/
WhyiscreditutilizationstablePrecautionpaymentsandcreditcardsoverthebus WhyiscreditutilizationstablePrecautionpaymentsandcreditcardsoverthebus

WhyiscreditutilizationstablePrecautionpaymentsandcreditcardsoverthebus - PDF document

felicity
felicity . @felicity
Follow
342 views
Uploaded On 2021-09-25

WhyiscreditutilizationstablePrecautionpaymentsandcreditcardsoverthebus - PPT Presentation

3ScottFulfordConsumerFinancialProtectionBurueauemailscottfulfordcfpbgovIconductedsomeofthisworkwhileIwasonthefacultyatBostonCollegeandavisitingscholarattheConsumerPaymentsResearchCenterattheFederalRes ID: 885771

148 147 cycle 150 147 148 150 cycle debt credit 2015 000 2002 card utilization notes 2013 fulford 2010

Share:

Link:

Embed:

Download Presentation from below link

Download Pdf The PPT/PDF document "WhyiscreditutilizationstablePrecautionpa..." is the property of its rightful owner. Permission is granted to download and print the materials on this web site for personal, non-commercial use only, and to display it on your personal computer provided you do not modify the materials and that you retain all copyright notices contained in the materials. By downloading content from our website, you accept the terms of this agreement.


Presentation Transcript

1 Whyiscreditutilizationstable?Precaution,
Whyiscreditutilizationstable?Precaution,payments,andcreditcardsoverthebusinesscycleandlifecycleScottL.FulfordandScottSchuhApril2017PreliminaryversionAbstractWeshowthatcreditutilization—thefractionoftheavailablecreditcardlimitused—isremarkablystableoverthebusinesscycle,thelife-cycle,andforindividualsintheshortterm.Tounderstandthisstableutilization,webuildandestimateamodeloflife-cyclecredituseinwhichcreditcardshavebothaprecautionaryandpaymentsvalue,unitingtheirmonetaryandrevolvingdebtuses.Bothusessuggestthatincreasesincreditaccompanyincreasesindebt.Weestimatethepreferencesnecessarytomatchtheobservedlife-cycledebtandconsumption.Themodelsuccessfullypredictsstableutilizationoverthelife-cycle,businesscycle,andforindividuals. ScottFulford:ConsumerFinancialProtectionBurueau;email:scott.fulford@cfpb.gov.IconductedsomeofthisworkwhileIwasonthefacultyatBostonCollegeandavisitingscholarattheConsumerPaymentsResearchCenterattheFederalReserveBankofBoston.IwouldliketothanktheBankandtheCenterfortheirknowledgeandhelp.ScottSchuh:ConsumerPaymentResearchCenter,FederalReserveBankofBoston;email:Scott.Schuh@bos.frb.org.WeboththankDavidZhangforhisexcellentresearchassistance.Thispaperhasbenetedfromthecommentsofpar-ticipantsatthe2015CanadianEconomicsAssociation,the2015BoulderSummerConferenceonConsumerFinancialDecisionMaking,theFDICConsumerResearchSymposium,the2016NBERSummerInstituteAggregateImplica-tionsofMicroBehaviorworkshop,andseminarsattheFederalReserveBankofBoston,theBankofCanada,andtheConsumerFinancialProtectionBureau.Toensureappropriateuseofthedata,Equifaxrequiredthatwepre-clearresultsthatusedEquifaxdatabeforemakingthempublic.Th

2 eviewsexpressedinthispaperaretheauthors'
eviewsexpressedinthispaperaretheauthors'anddonotnecessarilyreecttheofcialpositionoftheFederalReserveBankofBoston,theFederalReserveSystem,theConsumerFinancialProtectionBureau,ortheUnitedStates.1 1IntroductionAsbanksattemptedtorepairtheirbalancesheetsduringthenancialcrisisof2008-2009,theyreducedthecreditcardlimitsofmillionsofAmericans,wipingoutnearlyatrilliondollarsinavailablecredit,andreducingtheaveragelimitbyabout40%.Atthesametime,Americansreducedtheircreditcarddebtbyasimilaramountandsotheaveragecreditutilization—thefractionofavailablecreditused—wasnearlyconstantfrom2000to2015(seegure1).Inaggregate,thedebtreductionswereapproximatelydoublethetaxrebatesfromtheEconomicStimulusAct(Parkeretal.,2013)andtheaveragefallindebtwasmorethan$1,000dollars.WhydidsomanyAmericanspaybacksomuchdebtduringarecession?Whilethefallincreditduringthecrisisisthemostdramaticexample,weshowthatlargechangesincreditaccompaniedbysimilarlylargechangesindebtarecommonoverthelife-cycleandforindividualsintheshortterm.UsingalargepanelfromthecreditbureauEquifaxandcollectedbytheNewYorkFederalReserve,weshowthataveragecreditcardlimitsincreasebymorethan400percentbetweenage20and30,andcontinuetoincreaseafterage30,althoughatasomewhatslowerrate.Yetsincecreditcarddebtincreasesatnearlythesamepace,creditutilizationdeclinesonlyveryslowlyoverthelifecycle.Individualsalsofacesubstantialcreditlimitvolatility,severaltimeslargerthanincomevolatility(Fulford,2015),butindividualcreditutilizationisextremelypersistentaswell,withshocksdyingoutalmostcompletelyafterabouttwoyears.Creditcardscanbeusedbothforpaymentsandtoaccumulaterevolvingdebt,andwesuggestthatthereasonfo

3 rstableutilizationisthatbothusespushtowa
rstableutilizationisthatbothusespushtowardsstability,althoughindifferentways.Therstuseisprimarilymonetary:acreditcardmaybeaconvenientwaytopayforthings,especiallyifitofferssomekindofrewards.Inthisway,creditcardsaresimilartodebitcardsorcheckswhichmaytakeseveraldaystoclearandrequireanintermediarywhopromisestopaythemerchantrstandcollectfromtheconsumerlater.1Convenienceuseofcreditcardsthereforetakes 1Thisaspectofcreditcards,whichinvolvestheinter-relationshipbetweencreditandliquidity,hasbeenstudiedrecentlybyTelyukovaandWright(2008)andTelyukova(2013).2 onsomeoftheaspectsofconsumption.Anincreaseinincomethatincreasesbothconsumptionandthecreditcardlimitwillalsoincreaseconvenienceuse,suggestingthatutilizationshouldbestable.Theseconduseisthat,havingdecidedtopayforsomething,aconsumerhastheoptiontoroll-overherdebtfrommonthtomonth.Creditthereforeplaysaprecautionaryroletosmoothovershocksandalifetimeliquidityroletohelpbringforwardconsumption.Sincesuchprecautionaryorbuffer-stockwealth(Carroll,1997;Deaton,1991)isonlythereforinsurancepurposes,anincreaseincrediteffectivelymakespeoplemorewealthy,allowingthemtospendmore(Fulford,2013).Boththemonetaryandprecautionaryfunctionsofcreditcardspointtostableutilizationsincedebtrisesatthesametimeascredit.Tomakethecasethatthecombinedpaymentandprecautionaryaspectsofcreditareimportantandexplainthebroadfactsofcreditcarddebt,weadaptamodeloflife-cycleconsumptionandsavings(GourinchasandParker,2002;Cagetti,2003)toallowbothfortheuseofcreditcardsforpaymentsandthelargechangesincreditlimitsoverthelife-cyclethatwehavedocumented.Withinthemodel,weallowtheconsumertodecidehowmuchofcurrentconsumptiontopayforwithacreditca

4 rdcard.Somepaymentsareveryconvenienttous
rdcard.Somepaymentsareveryconvenienttouseacreditcardfor,otherslessso.Akeyfeatureofcreditcardcontractsallowsustoidentifytheconveniencevalueofcreditcards:cardholderswhohadrevolvedinthepreviousbillingcyclelosetheoatorgraceperiodtopayoffthenewpurchaseswithoutinterest.Oursimplepaymentsmodelisidentiedoffofthedifferenceinbehaviorbetweenthosewhoarerevolvingdebtandthosewhoarenot.UsingnewdatafromtheDiaryofConsumerPaymentChoice,weestimatethatnon-revolverswouldbewillingtopay0.319percentofallconsumptiontocontinueusingcreditcards.Sincethevaluetakesplaceononlythe17%ofconsumptionpayedforwithcreditcards,itsuggeststhatthisformofpaymentisveryconvenient,giventhecurrentpaymentsinfrastructure.Wethenembedthevalueofpaymentchoiceinthelife-cyclemodelwhichallowstheaccumu-lationofcreditcarddebtandsavingsandestimatethepreferencesnecessarytomatchthelife-cycleproleofconsumptionorcreditcarddebtusingtheMethodofSimulatedMoments(McFadden,1989).Allowingforsubstantialheterogeneityofpreferences,themodelmatchesboththelife-3 cyclemomentsofcreditcarddebtandconsumptionwell.Theestimatessuggestthatabouthalfthepopulationmustbeveryimpatientandcarelittleaboutrisktoholdtheamountofrevolvingdebtweobserve.Aroundhalfofcreditcardusersareprimarilyusingtheircardsforpayments,andsoallowingforbothconvenienceandrevolvinguseisnecessaryforunderstandingoverallcreditcarddebt.BuildingontheworkofGrossandSouleles(2002),recentworkestimatestheresponseofdebttochangesincreditandhasnotedthesubstantialheterogeneityinresponses(Agarwaletal.,2015;Aydin,2015).Theheterogeneitycomesbothfromthedifferencesbetweenrevolversandconve-nienceusersaswellasdifferentresponsesacrossthelifecycleandfraction

5 ofcreditused.Al-lowingforbothtypeofuses,
ofcreditused.Al-lowingforbothtypeofuses,thedynamicsofcreditutilizationfromthemodelcloselymatchthereducedformdynamicsweestimateinthecreditbureaudata,suggestingthatthiskindofhetero-geneityisnecessarytounderstandresponsestocreditandotherliquidityshocks.Addingheterogeneoususesforcredittothelife-cyclemodelalsosuggestsasubtlydifferentexplanationforthehumpshapeoflife-cycleconsumption(Attanasioetal.,1999;AttanasioandBrowning,1995)thanthecombinationofprecautionandlife-cyclesavingssuggestedbyGour-inchasandParker(2002),insteadhearkeningtotheolderheterogeneousapproachofCampbellandMankiw(1989)andCampbellandMankiw(1990).Whileprecautionexplainsthelevelofconsumption,itplaysonlyasmallroleinthelife-cycleshapeinourestimates.Instead,thosewhoholdrevolvingdebtconsumeclosetotheirincomeovertheentirelife-cycle,relyingentirelyoncreditforsmoothingpurposes,andsoalloftheir“savings”comefromcreditlimitincreases.ThepatientconvenienceuserslooksmuchlikeastandardLife-Cycle/PermanentIncomeHypothesisconsumerwhoconsumesnearlythesameamountovertheentirelife-cycle.Theaverageofthesetwopopulationsconsumelessthanincomeoverthelife-cyclebutwiththedistincthumpshapeofconsumptioncomingentirelyfromtheincomeproleoftheimpatienthand-to-mouthpopu-lation.Indeed,ourestimatethatrevolvinghand-to-mouthconsumerscomposeabouthalfofthepopulationisveryclosetotheestimatesinCampbellandMankiw(1990).Usingourmodelestimatedtomatchthelife-cycleofcreditandconsumption,wenallyask4 howwellitexplainsthebusinesscycleofcreditanditsindividualdynamics.Thisapproachfollowsthestandardhypothetico-deductivemethod(Deaton,2010),inthatthebestevidenceinfavorofamodelisifithelpsexplainnewphenomenaout

6 ofsample.Wesimulatealargepopulationthatm
ofsample.Wesimulatealargepopulationthatmatchestheagedistributionofthepopulationofcreditusersandgivethemalarge,unexpected,reductionincreditofthesamesizeasoccurredduringthenancialcrisis.Themodelpredictsthestableutilizationthatobtainedovertheperiodbothinaggregateandattheindividuallevel,despitethelargeriseincreditfrom2000to2008andtheabruptfallover2009.2LiteratureHowconsumersrespondtochangesintheavailabilityofcreditisrarelystudied,despitethecen-tralityofcreditanddebtinthenanciallivesofconsumersandhouseholds.Itisparticularlyhardtostudychangesincreditbecausecredit—unlikedebt,assets,orincome—isonlyoccasionallyre-portedinsurveys.Indeed,Zinman(2015)arguesthathouseholddebtisunderstudiedevenwithintheeldofhouseholdnance,itselfunderstudiedcomparedwithotherareasofnance.Otherthansomeworkonmortgages(IacovielloandPavan,2013),thispaperappearstobethersttostudythelifecycleofcreditlimits.Consequently,weviewoneofourmajorcontributionsasdocumentinghowU.S.consumers'creditanddebtvaryoverthelifecycle.Asmallliteraturehasexaminedchangesincreditcardlimits,buthasconsideredchangesinlimitsonlyforsinglecreditcardaccountsandhasnotconsideredthedifferencebetweenconve-nienceusersandrevolvers.ThepioneeringworkisGrossandSouleles(2002),whouseapanelfromasinglecreditprovidertolookathowhouseholdsrespondtochangesininterestratesandchangesinavailablecredit.Increasesincreditlimitswerefollowedbyincreasesindebt,partic-ularlyforconsumersalreadyclosetotheircreditlimit.GrossandSouleles(2002)alsonotedthe“creditcardpuzzle,”theobservationthatsomehouseholdspayhighinterestoncreditcarddebtswhileatthesametimeearninglowinterestonliquidsavings.Aga

7 rwaletal.(2015)usecreditlimitincreasesth
rwaletal.(2015)usecreditlimitincreasesthatarediscontinuouswithcreditscoretoexaminehowexogenouschangesincreditlim-5 itsmatter.Forconsumerswiththelowestscores,adollarincreaseinlimitsisfollowedby59centsmoredebtwithinayear,whilethosewithhighercreditscoresincuralmostnoincreaseindebt.UsingtheEquifax/CCP,Fulford(2015)demonstratesthatthereissubstantialcreditlimitvariabil-ity.Short-termcreditvolatilityislargerthanmostmeasuresofincomevolatility,andlong-termcreditvolatilityismuchgreaterthanlong-termmeasuresofincomevolatility.Thisvolatilitycanhelptoexplainthecreditcardpuzzle.Ludvigson(1999)examinestheresponseofconsumptiontocreditvolatilityattheaggregatelevel.Leth-Petersen(2010)studiesaDanishreformthatallowedhomeownerstousehousingequityascollateralforthersttime.Thereformincreasedavailablecredit,butitproducedrelativelymoderateconsumptionresponses.Theresponsewasstrongestfortheyoungesthouseholds.Sincelargerchangesincreditaremorelikelywhenthereislessnancialintermediationingeneral,muchoftherecentworkonchangesincredithavestudieddevelopingcountries.Fulford(2013)examinestheshort-andlong-termconsumptionresponsesofconsumersinabuffer-stockmodelfollowingchangesincreditandndsevidenceconsistentwiththemodelinIndiafollowingamassivebankingexpansion.Inanstructuralestimationapproachsimilartoourwork,KaboskiandTownsend(2011)estimateamodelofconsumption,savings,andcreditusinganexpansionofcreditinThailand.KarlanandZinman(2010)examinetheeffectsofexpandingcreditaccesstothemarginalborrowerinSouthAfrica.Whilechangesincreditoverthelifecyclehavebeenlargelyunstudied,muchworkexaminesthedecisiontosaveandconsumeoverthelifecycle.Inmuchofthiswork,creditisintention-

8 allypushedtothebackground.Inthestandardv
allypushedtothebackground.Inthestandardversionsofthelife-cycleorpermanentincomehypothesis,forexample,theassumptionthatyoungconsumerscansmoothreliesdirectlyontheassumptionthatcreditisreadilyavailable(Deaton,1992).Morerecentlife-cyclemodelstakese-riouslythatcreditconstraintsmaybind,butdonotallowcredittovaryoverthelifecycle.Thetypicalassumptionisthateitherthereisnocreditavailable,orthatthereisaxedlimit,sothatonlynetassetsneedtobestudied(see,forexample,GourinchasandParker(2002)).Somerecentworkhasattemptedtoendogenizeborrowingconstraints,andmuchofthiswork6 hasdirectlife-cycleimplications.Coccoetal.(2005)buildamodelofconsumptionandportfoliochoiceoverthelifecycle.TheirworkaddsportfoliochoicetotheapproachofGourinchasandParker(2002).Asanextension,theyintroduceendogenousborrowingconstraints.Thesecon-straintsarebasedontheminimumvaluethatincomecantake,sincewithlimitedenforcement,borrowershavetochoosetopaybackratherthanfacethepenaltyofdefault.Borrowinggreatlyaffectsportfoliochoice,asyoungconsumersborrowiftheendogenousconstraintpermits,andonlystartinvestinginequitylaterinlife.Lopes(2008)introducesasimilarlife-cyclemodelwithdefaultandbankruptcy.Lawrence(1995)appearstohavebeenthersttointroducedefaultinalife-cyclemodel.Athreya(2008)developsalife-cyclemodelwithcreditconstraints,default,andsocialinsurance.Relaxingdefaultpolicycreatesseverecreditconstraintsamongtheyoung.Eliminatingdefaultrelaxescreditconstraintsfortheyoungandreducesconsumptioninequality,butincreasesconsumptioninequalityfortheold,whonowcannolongerdefaultaftersufcientlyseverenegativeshocks.Thispaperalsooverlapswithalargerliteratureexaminingthewaysthatindividualsusethe

9 nancialproductsavailabletothem.Stangoand
nancialproductsavailabletothem.StangoandZinman(2009)examinehowmuchasampleofU.S.consumerspaysinfeesandinterestfornancialproducts.Creditcardinterestisthebiggestnancialexpense,althoughsomehouseholdsalsopaysignicantoverdraftfees.Morethanhalfofhouseholdscouldreducefeessubstantiallybymovingamongproducts.Agarwaletal.(2007)notethatmiddle-agedadultspaytheleastinthesekindsofavoidablefees,withtheminimumpaidatage53.Zinman(2013)examinesthequestionofwhethermarketsover-orunder-supplycreditandconcludesthat,whiletherearemodelsthatsuggestover-supplyandmodelsthatsuggestunder-supply,thereisnotstrongevidenceforeither.7 3Creditcarduseoverthebusinesscycle,life-cycle,andforindividualsBothcreditanddebtchangesubstantiallyoverthebusinesscycle,thelifecycleandforindividualsintheshortterm.ThissectionbrieydiscussesthecontextofconsumercreditintheUnitedStates,introducesourmaindatasources,andpresentssomenon-parametricandreducedformresults.Anearlierworkingpaperversionofthispaper(FulfordandSchuh,2015)providesadditionaldescriptivestatisticsincludingadditionalevidenceonthedistributionofcreditandoncreditcardholdingbyageusingtheSurveyofConsumerPaymentChoice(SchuhandStavins,2014).Wethenturntoamodelinthenextsectiontohelpmakesenseoftheseobservations.3.1ThedataTheEquifax/NYFedConsumerCreditPanel(CCP)containsa5percentsampleofallaccountsreportedtothecreditreportingagencyEquifaxquarterlyfrom1999to2014.Formuchoftheanalysisweuseonlya0.1percentsampleforanalyticaltractability.Onceanaccountisselected,itsentirehistoryisavailable.Thedatasetcontainsacompletepictureofthedebtofanyindividualthatisreportedtothecreditagency:creditcard,auto,mortgage,andstudentloandebts,asw

10 ellassomeother,smaller,categories.Leeand
ellassomeother,smaller,categories.LeeandvanderKlaauw(2010)provideadditionaldetailsonthesamplingmethodologyandhowcloselytheoverallsamplecorrespondstothedemographiccharacteristicsoftheoverallUnitedStatespopulation,andconcludethatthedemographicsmatchtheoverallpopulationveryclosely:thevastmajorityoftheU.S.populationovertheageof18hasacreditbureauaccount.TheCCPalsorecordswhetheranaccountisajointorco-signedaccount.Ratherthancapturingtoofewpeople,themainissueisthatasizablefractionofsampledaccountsrepresenteitherincorrectinformationreportedtoEquifaxorindividualswhoareonlylooselyattachedtothecreditsystem,eitherbychoiceorbecausetheylackthedocumentation.Forexample,theaccountsarebasedonSocialSecuritynumbers,soreportinganincorrectSocialSecuritynumbercancreateaccountsincorrectlyattributedtoanindividual.Forthisreason,we8 limitthesamplethroughouttoaccountsthanincludealistedageandshowanopencreditcardaccountatsomepointfrom1999to2014.Thispopulationhassomeaccesstocreditandthusexcludesthosewhocouldnotobtainacreditcardorchosenotapplyforone.Dependingontheanalysis,wealsolimitthesampletothosewithcurrentopenaccounts,debt,orlimits.Muchofthispaperfocusesoncreditcards,sincetheyhaveexplicitlimitsnotreadilyobservableinmostothermarkets.However,thecreditcardlimitsreportedtocreditreportingagenciesareattimesincomplete.TheEquifax/CCPreportsonlytheaggregatelimitforcardsthatareupdatedinagivenquarter.Cardswithcurrentdebtareupdated,butaccountswithnodebtandnonewchargesmaynotbe.Todealwiththisproblem,wefollowFulford(2015)andcreateanimpliedaggregatelimitbytakingtheaveragelimitofreportedcardstimesthetotalnumberofopencards.Thismethodisexactifcardsthathavenotbeenupdatedhaveth

11 esamelimitasupdatedcards.Estimatingthedi
esamelimitasupdatedcards.Estimatingthedifferencebasedonchangesasnewcardsarereportedandthelimitchanges,Fulford(2015)ndsthatnon-updatedcardstypicallyhavelargerlimits,andsotheoveralllimitisanunderestimateforsomeconsumers.Thisissueisaconcernmostlyforconsumerswhoareusingonlyasmallfractionoftheiravailablecredit,sinceitisonlycardsnotusedatallarenotupdated.Fortheconsumerswhousemoreoftheircreditandsomayactuallybeboundbythelimit,thelimitisaccurate,becausealltheircardsareupdated.3.2CreditanddebtoverthebusinesscycleSince2000overallcreditanddebthavevariedtremendously.Figure1showshowtheaverageU.S.consumer'screditcardlimitanddebthavevariedfrom2000through2014.AlthoughtheEquifaxdatasetstartsin1999,weexcludetherstthreequarters,sincethelimitsinitiallyarenotcomparable(seeAveryetal.(2004)foradiscussionoftheinitialreportingproblems).Thescaleontheleftisinlogarithms,soproportionalchangesindebthaveapproximatelythesameimportanceasproportionalchangesincredit.Between2000and2008theaveragecreditcardlimitincreasedbyapproximately40percentfromaround$10,000onaveragetoapeakof$14,000.Over2009,overalllimitscollapsedrapidlybeforerecoveringslightlyin2012.Creditcarddebtshowsasimilar9 variationovertime.From2000to2008,theaverageU.S.consumer'screditcarddebtincreasedfromjustover$4,000tojustunder$5,000,beforereturningtoaround$4,000over2009and2010.2Utilizationismuchlessvolatilethancreditordebt.Thethicklineinthemiddleofthegureshowscreditutilization,theaveragefractionofavailablecreditused.Creditutilizationfellslightlyfromover35percentin2000toaround30percentin2006beforegenerallyincreasingagainto2010anddecliningslightlysincethen.Althoughitisnotimmediatelyevident,the

12 scaleofgure1forcreditanddebtonthelef
scaleofgure1forcreditanddebtontheleftisverysimilartothescaleforutilizationontheright.A1percentagepointchangeinutilizationhasthesameverticaldistanceasa1percentchangeincreditordebt.Largerchangesarelessexactlycomparable,butthedistancebetween$4,000and$5,000,forexample,isstillalmostexactly20percentagepointsontherightaxis.Thesimilarscalesmeanthatwecandirectlycomparetherelativechangesovertimeinlimits,debt,andcreditutilization.Creditanddebtvarytogetherinwaysthatproduceextremelystableutilizationthathasnoobviousrelationshipwiththeoverallbusinesscycle.Sucharelationshipisnotjustmechanical:whencreditwascutin2009,familieshadthechoicewhethertomaintainorincreasetheirdebt,andthecutincreditcouldhavetranslateddirectlyintoanincreaseinutilizationratherthanadecreaseindebt.3.3CreditanddebtoverthelifecycleWenextexaminehowcredit,debt,andutilizationevolveoverthelife-cycle.Figure2showsthecreditcardlimitanddebtinthetoppanelandcreditutilizationinthebottompanel.Eachlineisforanagecohortthatwefollowovertheentiretimepossible.Thegurethereforemakesnoassumptionsaboutcohort,age,ortimeeffects.Creditlimitsincreaseveryrapidlyearlyinlife,increasingbyaround400percentbetweentheagesof20and30.Theycontinuetoincrease,althoughlessrapidly,afterage40.Life-cyclevariationdominateseverythingelseingure2;whilethereisclearlysomecommonvariationoverthebusinesscycle,cohortsmovenearlyinlinewith 2Thefallindebtisnotbecauseofchargeoffsinwhichthebankwritesoffthedebtfromitsbooksasunrecoverable.Theconsumerstillowesthechargedoffdebt.Banksmayeventuallysellcharge-offdebttoacollectionagency,inwhichcaseitmaynolongerappearascreditcarddebtwithincreditbureauaccounts.Chargeoffsarenotlargeen

13 oughtoexplainthefallindebt,althoughtheyd
oughtoexplainthefallindebt,althoughtheydidincreaseover2009.Seehttps://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/chargeoff/delallsa.htmforcharge-offratesforcreditcards.10 age.Estimatingasimplemodelthatdividesbetweencommontimeandageeffectsmakes,gureA-5intheappendixmakesthispointexplicit.3Despitetheverylargevariationoverthebusinesscycleevidentingure1,thebigchangesarehappeningoverthelife-cycle.Creditlimitsanddebtcombinetogivethefractionofcreditused,showninthebottompanelofgure2.Consumerswithzerodebthavezerocreditutilization,andsoareincludedinutilizationbutareexcludedfrommeancredit,whichincludesonlypositivevalues.4Creditutilizationfallsslowlyfromage20toage80.Onaverage,20-year-oldsareusingmorethan50percentoftheiravailablecredit,and50-year-oldsarestillusing40percentoftheircredit.Creditutilizationfallstobelow20percentonlyaroundage70.Theslowfallincreditutilizationcomesfromtwodifferentsourcesoverthelifecycle.Earlyinlife,creditutilizationishigh,asasubstantialportionofthepopulationusesmuchorallofitsavailablecredit.Creditincreasessomewhatmorerapidlythandebt,however,socreditutilizationfallsslowly.Inmid-life,debtstabilizes,butcreditlimitscontinuetoincreaseslowlyFinally,start-ingaroundage60,averagedebt,conditionalonhavingany,startstodecline,socreditutilizationdeclines.3.4TheindividualevolutionofutilizationTheprevioustwosectionsshowthatdespiteverylargechangesincreditanddebtoverthelifecycleandbusinesscycle,creditutilizationisremarkablystable.Theaggregatedatacouldbehidingsubstantialindividualvolatilityinutilization,however.Inthissectionweshowthatutilization 3Estimatingasimplemodelthatseparatesthevariationbetweenageandyearallowsustomaketheimportan

14 ceoflife-cyclevariationevenclearer.Figur
ceoflife-cyclevariationevenclearer.FigureA-5showstheageandyeareffectsfromestimatingasimpleregressionoftheform:lnDit=+t+a+it;(1)wherelnDitiseitherlogdebt,logcreditlimits,orutilization,andallowsthesetovarybetweenageeffectsaandyeareffectstbutimposescommoncohorteffects.Theexcludedgroupisage20andyear2000,soeachpanelingureA-5startsatzeroatage20andyear2000.Theestimatedeffectisinlogunits,andsothescaleoftheguresuggeststhatvariationoverthelife-cycleincreditisaround9(e2::5=e0:3)timeslargerthanovertime,evenwithamassivecreditcontraction.4Thecalculationingure2aretheaverageofloglimitsandlogdebtstomatchlateranalysisandsoexcludezerosexceptforutilization.FigureA-6intheappendixshowsthefractionineachcohortwhohavepositivecreditanddebt.Includingthezeroswouldlowertheaveragecreditlimitanddebt,butactuallymakesthelife-cyclevariationlarger.11 foranindividualisextremelystable;whiledifferentindividualshavedifferentcreditutilizationratiosthatrepresenttheirindividualsteadystateandtheseratiosmaychangeslowlyastheyage,individualsreturnrapidlytotheirowntypicalratio.Creditutilizationisbestcharacterizedbyxedheterogeneityacrossindividuals,andrelativelysmalldeviationsforanindividualovertime.Wepresentnon-parametricresultsinappendixAandappendixgureA-7andreachalmostidenticalconclusionstotheparametricestimates.Thenon-parametricresultssuggestthatthesimplelineardynamicreducedformmodelweemployissurprisinglyaccurate.Table1showshowutilizationthisperiodisrelatedtoutilizationinthepreviousperiod.Weestimateregressionsoftheform:it=t+a+ i+ it�1+it;(2)whereit=Dit=Bitisthecreditutilizationgiven

15 thecreditlimitBitandthecurrentdebtDit,co
thecreditlimitBitandthecurrentdebtDit,conditionalonthecreditlimitBit￿0,andage(a)andquarter(t)effectsthatallowutilizationtovarysystematicallybyageandyear.Column1doesnotincludexedeffectsandsoassumesacommonintercept,column2includesquarterandageeffects,whiletheothercolumnsincludeindividualxedeffects,quarter,andageeffects.5Withoutxedeffects,creditutilizationisverypersistentandreturnstoanon-zerosteadystateofapproximately40percentutilization( =(1� )=0:38).Notethatthisutilizationisclosetotheaverageingure1,asitshouldbesincetheyareestimatedfromthesamedataandthenon- 5Thecombinedage,year,andindividualxedeffectsinequation(2)arenotfullyidentied.Asintheage-cohort-periodproblem,itisimpossibletofullyidentifyalleffectssincetherecanbeatrendinanyoneofage,time,orcohort,orsplitamongallthree,andanydivisionisobservationallyequivalent,sincebirthcohortequalstheyearminusage.Putdifferently,ifweestimateallindividualeffects,itisnotpossibletofullyseparatebetweengettingolderandatimeshock.Thesizeofthedatasetmeansthatratherthanestimatingindividualcoefcients—sometimesreferredtoasnuisanceparameters—weinsteadperformthestandardwithintransformationbyremovingthemeanfromallvariablesinequation(2).Thewithintransformationmeansthatanyadditionalrestrictionforidenticationmustbeoneitherthetimeorageeffects.Ratherthanimposingthequestionableassumptionthattwooftheageoryeareffectsareexactlyequal—theimplicationofdroppingmorethanoneoftheageoryeardummies—weinsteadimposetherestrictionthatthereisnotrendintheageeffects.Thisrestrictionisinnocuousinthesensethattherecanstillbeatrendwithage,asindividualeffectsthatare

16 olderwhenweobservethemcanhavelarger
olderwhenweobservethemcanhavelargeri,butthattrendwillappearintheindividualeffectsratherthanintheageeffects.Moreover,theageeffectscanstillallowlife-cyclevariation,butthatvariationmustaverageouttozero.WeimplementthisrestrictionfollowingDeaton(1997,pp.123–126)byrecastingtheagedummiessuchthat^Ia=Ia�[(a�1)I21�(a�2)I20],whereIais1iftheageofpersoniisaandzerootherwise.12 parametricconditionalexpectationfunctionshowninappendixgureA-7isnearlylinear.Intheothercolumns,sincetheage,year,andxedeffectschangethesteadystate,wedonotreportit,butitisimportanttorealizethattheaveragesteady-statecreditutilizationisnotzero.Thenexttwocolumnsreporthowcreditutilizationvariesaroundanindividual-specic i,byestimatingusingthewithintransformation.Nearlyhalfoftheoverallvarianceinutilizationcomesfromthesexedeffects.Inotherwords,wecanthinkofthedistributionofutilizationascomingabouthalffromfactorsthatarexedforanindividual,allowingforcommonageandyeartrends,andhalffromrelativelyshort-termdeviationsfromthemean.Adeviationfromthemeanutilizationdiminishesatarateofabout0.353=1-0.647perquarter.Andso,aftera10percentagepointincreaseinutilization,6.47percentagepointsremaininonequarter,1.7percentagepointsinayear,andlessthan0.3ofapercentagepointaftertwoyears.Thelastcolumnsuggeststhatthespeedofreturntoindividualutilizationdependsonage.Fora20-year-old,onlyafraction0.58oftheshockisleftafteronequarter,fora60-year-old0.70ofashockremains.Itisnotobviouswhythespeedofreturnshouldincreasewithage.Onepossibilityisthatcreditrepresentsamuchmoreimportantfactorintheoverallportfolioofyoungpeople,whotypicallyhaveacquiredfewassets.A60-year-oldmayhaves

17 omeotherassetsandismorelikelytobeaconven
omeotherassetsandismorelikelytobeaconvenienceuser,andsomaynottargetcreditutilizationasclosely.TheestimatesinTable1emphasizethatcreditutilizationforanindividualisverystable.Whiletherearedeviationsfromthelong-termmean,thesedissipatequicklyandarelargelygonewithintwoyears.Boththeparametricandnon-parametricevidencesuggeststhatindividualshaveastrongtendencytoreturntotheirowncreditutilizationfollowingshocks.Sincecreditutilizationisnotzeroformostpeople,theresultssuggestastrongtendencytoholdcreditcarddebtforthelongterm.Sincetheparametricestimatesincludeageeffects,thesedeviationsarearoundalife-cycleaverage,whichtheprevioussectionshaveshownisdecliningslowly,butpersistently,withage.Boththeslowdeclineofutilizationwithageandthequickreturntoindividualcreditutilizationsuggestthatthepass-throughfromthecreditcardlimittocreditcarddebtislargeandoccursrelativelyrapidly.Intheworkingpaper(FulfordandSchuh,2015),weshowresultsonhowdebtandcredit13 co-evolve,ratherthanxingtheirrelationshipbycombiningthemintoutilization.Relativelylittleislostbysimplifyingonlytoutilization.Moreover,inaGrangerCausalitysense,thedirectionofcausalitymovesprimarilyfromchangesincredittochangeindebt.4Amodeloflife-cycleconsumptionandcreditcarddebtWehavedemonstratedthatthereisastrongtendencyforindividualstohavestableutilizationwhichfallsslowlyoverthelife-cycle.Tounderstandtheseobservations,thissectiondescribesalife-cycleconsumptionmodelsimilartoGourinchasandParker(2002)orCagetti(2003)towhichweaddapaymentchoiceandchangingcreditoverthelife-cycle.Thenextsectionestimatestheparametersofthemodelbasedontheobservedlife-cycleprolesofdebtandconsumptionandaskshowwellitexplainsthestableu

18 tilization.4.1ThedecisionproblemFromanya
tilization.4.1ThedecisionproblemFromanyagetaconsumerseekstomaximizehisorherutilityforremaininglifegivenhercurrentresourcesandexpectedfutureincome.Withadditivelyseparablepreferences,theconsumerofagetwithcash-at-handWtandcurrentcreditlimitBtmaximizesthediscountedvalueofexpectedfutureutility:maxfCs;sgTs=T(E"TXs=t s�tsu(sCs)+ T+1S(AT)#)subjecttoCsWsWs+1=R(As)As+Ys+1+Bs+1As=Ws�Bs�Css=(s;IRs)IRs=f1ifAs�10;0elseg14 whereshegetsperiodutilityu()fromconsumptionCtwhichismademorevaluablebysde-pendingonhowshepaysforthatconsumption.Wewilldescribehowshedecideswhatfractions2[0;1]ofherconsumptiontopayforwithacreditcardinmoredetailbelow,butconsiderstobethevalueinconsumptionunitsofherpaymentchoicewhichdependsonwhethershehasrevolvedtheperiodbefore(IRs).Shediscountsthefuturewithaxeddiscountedfactor .ShelivesforTperiodswhereTisarandomnumberthatwewillmatchtotheactuallifetables,butassumethatshedieswithcertaintyatage~T.Ondeath,shereceivesanalutilityS()fromleft-overpositiveresources.Inourbaseestimations,wesetthebequestmotivetoallowforanannuitytoheirs.AppendixBdiscussesthespecicfunction.Recentworkhasdisagreedovertheimportanceofabequestmotiveasopposedtootherpossiblemotivesforkeepingassetslateinlifesuchaslong-termcareandmedicalneeds(DeNardietal.,2010).Sincewefocusprimarilyondebts,ourmodelandestimatesarenotwellsituatedtodistinguishbetweenmotives.Removingthebequestmotivedoesnotaffecttheresultsmuch,butrequiresthepatientconsumertoexpectnon-assetincomeafterexpensestofallevenmoresubstantiallylateinlife.EndofperiodassetsAsdeterminetherateofreturnforthenextperiod:R(As)=8￿￿&

19 #x]TJ ;� -2;.51; Td;&#x [00;&
#x]TJ ;� -2;.51; Td;&#x [00;&#x]TJ ;� -2;.51; Td;&#x [00;:RifAs0RBifAs0;withaborrowerfacingahigherratethanasaverRBR.ThepaymentdecisionAccompanyingtheconsumptiondecisionisapaymentdecision.Ineveryperiodtheconsumermustdecidethefractionofherconsumptiontopayforwithacreditcards.Theoptimalfractionthenmakesconsumptionmorevaluablebyanamounts=(s;IRs�1)wheresistheoptimalfractionandIRs�1isanindicatorforwhethersheisrevolvingasofthepreviousperiodandsodoesnotgettheoatthatconvenienceusersget.Sincesappearsintheconsumer'sproblemonlyintheutilityfunction,notintheaccumulationequation,itisnotdirectlyaffecting15 thebudgetconstraint.Instead,wemodelthepaymentdecisionasoneofconvenience,inkeepingwithourdualapproachtocreditcards.Forexample,itisoftenmoreconvenienttobuysomethingonlinewithacreditcard.Itmightbepossibletosetupadirectbankwithdrawal,ormailacheck,orvisitabanktoturncashintoacashier'scheck,butthesemethodsrequireadditionalstepsortakelonger.Theprimaryvalueofcreditcardsaspaymentsisthattheyareawidelyacceptedpaymentmeans.Inaddition,somecreditcardsofferrewardsofvarioustypesthatmakepaymentsusingthemmorevaluableinmanyways.Whilesomeoftheserewards,suchas1%cashback,couldaffectthebudgetconstraintdirectly,others,suchasairlinemilesorpreferentialaccesstoeventtickets,areprimarilyintheformofincreasedvalueofconsumption.Giventhiscomplexity,ourapproachistomakeallpaymentchoicespurelyhedonic,whichsimpliestheproblemtremendouslybyallowingustomaketheconsumer'sproblemsequential.Theconsumerrstdecideshowtopayforwhatshewillconsume.Thengivens,whichmakesconsumptionthisperiodmoreorlessvalu

20 able,shedecideshowmuchtoconsume,takingin
able,shedecideshowmuchtoconsume,takingintoaccounthowherdecisionsthisperiodwillaffectherpaymentandconsumptiondecisionsnextperiod.Inparticular,theoptimalamounttopaywithacreditcardthisperioddirectlydependsonwhethersheleftrevolvingdebtfromlastperiod(IRs�1).Thereisnograceperiodoncreditcardpaymentsforrevolvers.Purchasesstartearninginterestassoonastheyaremadeifaconsumerhasunpaidcreditcarddebtfromthepreviousmonth.Theconsumermaychoosetopayanynewpurchasesoffverysoon,andsonotowemuchinterestonthem,ofcourse,butforrevolversthereisnofreecredit.Thedifferencebetweenthepaymentshabitsofconvenienceusersandrevolversiscrucialhere.Unlikeconvenienceuserswhogetaninterestfreeloanforallpayments,andsomayndcreditcarduseveryconvenient,revolversarepayinginterestontheirpurchasesandsondthemlessconvenient.Sincetheonlystatevariablethatmattersforthepaymentdecisioniswhetherornotsheisrevolving,thisapproachimpliesthatthepaymentdecisiontakesononlytwovaluesR=(R;IR=1)fortheoptimalsharebyarevolverRandC=(C;IR=0)forconvenienceuserswithoptimalshareC.Wewillusethisdistinctionandthedifferentpaymentchoicesofrevolversandconvenienceuserstoidentifyasimplefunctionalformfor(s;IRs�1).16 Tomodelthepaymentdecision,weassumethatallofthegoodsandservicesthataconsumerbuyscanberankedinorderofthevalueshegetsfrompurchasingwithacreditcard.Some,suchasgoodsonline,areveryconvenienttobuywithacreditcard.Others,suchastherentormortgagepayments,areinconvenientormaycomewithsomeadditionalcosts,andsoaconsumerwilltrytoavoidpayingforthemwithacreditcard.Orderedthisway,themarginalvalueofspendingalargerfractiononacreditcardisdeclining,andwillevent

21 uallyreachzerowhenitisinconvenienttospen
uallyreachzerowhenitisinconvenienttospendmoreonacreditcard.Weassumethatthedecreaseinthemarginalvalueofconvenienceislinearatrate1anddenotemarginalconvenienceoftherstconsumptiononacreditcardas0.Figure3showsthismarginalvalue.Themarginalconveniencevalueoftherstsmallshareofconsumptiononacreditcardisveryhigh,butasaconsumerchargesmoreandmore,thevaluedecreases.Theoptimumiswherethemarginalvalueofadditionalconsumptiononacreditcardiszero.Revolversmustpayinterest,inadditiontogettingtheconvenienceofthecard,andsothestart-ingmarginalconvenienceforthemislower.Ifconsumptionisspreadevenlyoverthemonth,thenarevolverwillpayadditionalinterestof(rB=12)=2onherconsumptionthatmonth.6Revolversstartoutatalowerinitialvalue,andsotheiroptimumpaymentshareislowerinFigure3,apredictionweseeinthedataandwilldiscussmoreforwhenweestimatethismodelinsection5.Finally,wendtheconsumptionvalueofthispaymentchoicebytakingtheareaunderthecurvesandnormalizingthevalueofothermeansofpaymentto1sothat(0;)=1.Exceptforthevalueofbequests,thenormalizationdoesnotaffecttheconsumptiondecisionsinceitaffectsthemarginalvalueofconsumptionthisperiodandinthefuture,leavingthetradeoffbetweenthemunchanged.Althoughitisnotrequiredforthesolutiontotheconsumer'sproblem,itisusefultoconsiderwhatthemodelsaysforconvenienceuseandrevolvingcredit.Aconsumerwithnegativeassetsis 6Thisformulacomesfromthewaythatannualcreditcardratesarereportedandinterestcharged.TheAnnualPercentageRateorAPRisnotacompoundrate,andsoitisappropriatetodivideitby12tondtherateofinterest.Thenancingchargeonacreditcardiscalculatedbasedontheaveragedailybalancewithinamonth,andsothenancingchargeonconsum

22 ptionspreadevenlythroughoutamonthishalft
ptionspreadevenlythroughoutamonthishalftheinterestrate.NotethatwhiletheAPRisnotacompoundrate,interestchargesnotpaidoffeachmonthwillcompoundbothinrealityandinourmodel.17 borrowingandhasdebtsthatrevolvefromperiodtoperiod.Sincethepaymentdecisionispurelyhedonic,itdependsonlyonwhetherornotsomeonewasrevolvinglastperiod,andsothereisanoptimalrevolverfractionofconsumptiononacreditcardRconvenienceuserfractiononacreditcardC:Theobservedcreditcarddebtataget,whichincludesbothnewchargesandpreviousdebtisthen:DRit=RCit�AitifAit0forarevolver(forwhomAi;t�10).Forconvenienceusersontheotherhand,assumingtheyarenottransitioningintobeingrevolvers,theobservedcreditcarddebtisjustafractionoftheirconsumption:DCit=CCitifAit&#x]TJ/;༕ ;.9;Ւ ;&#xTf 1;.21; 0 ;&#xTd [;0:ThecreditlimitThelimitingfactorforconsumptioninanygivenperiodiscash-at-handWswhichisdeterminedbyincomeYs,assetsordebtsfromthepreviousperiodAs,andthecurrentcreditlimitBs:ThecreditlimitBsevolveswithpermanentincome:Bs=bsPs;wherebs0isthepossiblystochasticfractionofthisamountthatcanbeborrowed.ThisapproachmeansthatacrossconsumersBswillbeinproportiontoincomePs;butmayfollowadifferentaveragepathoverthelife-cyclethanincome.7 7Theconsumer'sproblemaswritten,withWsasasufcientperiodbudgetconstraint,impliesthataconsumermustimmediatelyrepayalldebtoverherlimitifhercreditlimitfalls.Toseethis,considerwhathappensifBs�1￿0andtheconsumerborrowsleavingsnegativeassetsattheendofperiodAs�10.IfBs=0;thenassetsattheendofperiodsmustbeweaklypositive(As0),andsoalldebthasbeenrepaidwithinasingleperiod.Acutincreditlimitsimpliesanimmediaterepaymentofdebtinexcessof

23 thelimit.Thisdebtrepaymentwhencreditiscu
thelimit.Thisdebtrepaymentwhencreditiscutbelowdebtdoesnotmatchcreditcardcontracts,whichdonotrequireimmediateandcompletepaymentfollowingafallincredit(Fulford,2015)).Instead,creditcardborrowerscanpayofftheirdebtunderthesameterms,theyjustcannotaddtoit.However,allowingforsuchbehaviormeansthattheremustbeanadditionalcontinuousstatevariablesinceWsandBsnolongerfullydescribetheconsumer'sproblem,whichaddssubstantiallytothenumericalcomplexityofthesolutionthroughthecurseofdimensionality.18 TheincomeprocessIncomeordisposableincomefollowsarandomwalkplusdrift:Ys+1=Ps+1Us+1Ps+1=Gs+1PsNs+1whereGs+1istheknowgrowthratefromperiodtoperiod,the“permanent”orrandomwalkshocksNs+1areindependentlyandidenticallydistributedaslognormalwithmeanone:lnNs+1N(�2N=2;2N);andthetransitoryshocksaredistributedas:Us+18￿￿&#x]TJ ;� -2;.52;&#x Td ;&#x[000;&#x]TJ ;� -2;.52;&#x Td ;&#x[000;:ULwithprobabilitypL~Us(1�ULpL)=(1�pL)withprobability1�pL;where~Uisani.i.d.lognormalwithmeanone:ln~Us+1N(�2U=2;2U)andULisunemploymentincomeasafractionaspermanentincome.ThestructureoftheshocksensuresthattheexpectedincomenextperiodisalwaysGs+1Pssincethemeanofbothtransitoryandpermanentshocksisone.Recursiveformulationandiso-elasticpreferences.Weassumethatsub-utilitydisplaysCon-stantRelativeRiskAversion(CRRA):u(C)=C1� 1� :WithCRRApreferences,itispossibletonormalizetheproblemintermsofpermanentincomePtatanygivenage(seeCarroll(2012)foramorecompletediscussion).Usinglowercasetorepresentthenormalizedvalue:ct=Ct=Pt,wt=Wt=Pt,andat=At=Pt,andrewritinginrecursiveform,19 theproblemisequivalentto:vt(wt;bt)=maxctu(t

24 ct)+Et[ t+1(Gt+1Nt+1)1� vt+1(wt+1
ct)+Et[ t+1(Gt+1Nt+1)1� vt+1(wt+1;bt+1)] subjecttoctwtwt+1=Rt+1(IRt+1)at+Ut+1+bt+1at=wt�bt�ctt=(IRt)=maxt(t;IRt)IRt=f1ifat�10;0elsegwhereRt+1(IRt+1)=R=(Gt+1Nt+1)ifat0andRt+1(IRt+1)=RB=(Gt+1Nt+1)ifat0.TheexpectationattincludesthepossibilityofdeathbeforeTandthecertaintyofdeathat~Tleavingabequestworth t+1s(at)wheres()isthebequestfunctionnormalizedbyPt.Theinitialdistributionofincomeandwealth,andlatelifeincomeFinally,thereareseveralimportantdecisionparametersthataffectinitialdistributionsanddecisionslateinlife.Weassumethattheinitialdistributionofthewealth/permanentincomeratioislog-normalwithalocationparameter0andvarianceparameterthatmatchesthevarianceofpermanentincomeshocks.WeallowforafallindisposableincomeinretirementoroldagebyassumingthatafterRperiodspermanentincomefallsto1ofitsvalueatageR�1.Suchafallindisposableincomemayalsocomefromincreasedmedicalorcareneeds,andsoisaexiblewayofallowingforthepossibilitythatwealthneedsmaybehigherlateinlifebecauseincomeafternecessaryexpensesmaybelower.ModelfrequencyBecauseofdataandcomputationalconstraints,muchofthestructuralcon-sumptionliteraturehasbeenlimitedtoexaminingdecisionsmadeatayearlyfrequency.Yetcon-sumptiondecisionsmustbemademorefrequentlythenyearly.Ifsmoothingwithintheyearisperfect,thenthefrequencyshouldnotmatter.However,thelogicofthemodelandthedatasug-gestthatpeopledooccasionallyhittheirbudgetconstraint,whichdirectlyimpliesthatignoring20 decisionsmadewithintheyearmaymissimportantfacetsofconsumerbehavior.Inaddition,ifwewanttounderstandwhetherthemodelcanmatchthequarterlydynamicsofindividualandaggregatecreditutiliza

25 tion,itmustbehaveatleastaquarterlyfreque
tion,itmustbehaveatleastaquarterlyfrequency.4.2NumericalsolutionWiththeproblemwrittenrecursively,weproceedthroughbackwardrecursiontondanumericalapproximationoftheconsumer'sproblem.Foragivensentofparameters,oncevT+1(AT;0)isgiven,itispossibletondanapproximationofvT(w;b),andusetheapproximationofvT(w;b)tondvT�1(w;b).Thesolutiontoeachperiod'svaluefunctionisaconsumptionfunctionct(w;b).Wefollowseveralstandardsteps(seeCarroll(2012)foramoreindepthdiscussionofmanyoftheseapproaches).First,wediscretizethelog-normalshocksusingaGauss-Hermitequadraturewhichturnstheintegrationintheexpectationfunctionintoasummationoverdiscretestates.Sincetheincomeprocessissurelynotexactlylog-normalthereisnogainorlossinaccuracyfromdoingso;wearesimplyreplacingoneapproximationofshockswithanother.Second,wefollowthemethodofendogenousgridpoints(Carroll,2006)tondtheoptimalconsumptionthatleadstoendofperiodassetsatatanumberofgridpointsforatandbt.Veryelegantly,itisthenpossibletondoptimalconsumptionwhichleavesthisamountofassetsct(w;b)attheendogenousgridpointsforwsimplyusingtheaccountingidentityat=wt�bt�ct;andsoavoidacomputationallycostlynumericalroot-ndingapproximationentirely.Moreprecisely,iftheconsumerhasnotconsumedallavailablecash-at-handforthenextperiod,andsoisnotstrictlyconstrainedbythecreditlimit,thenthestandardrstorderconditionsandtheEulerequationimplythat:u0((IRt)ct)=Et[ tRt+1(at)(Gt+1Nt+1)1� u0(t+1ct+1(wt+1;bt+1))]wheredespiteitssubscriptt+t=(IRt+1)isdeterminedentirelybythechoiceofwhethertoleavepositiveornegativeassetsforthenextperiod.Giventhenextperiodconsumptionfunction,itis21 straightforwardton

26 dtheoptimalconsumptionthatleavesendofper
dtheoptimalconsumptionthatleavesendofperiodassetsatas:cat(a;b;IRt+1)=(1=t)Eth ^ t+1Rt+1(a)(Gt+1Nt+1)1� (t+1c(Rt+1(a)a+Ut+1+bt+1;bt+1))� i�1= :(3)Foravectorofendofperiodassets~a,itisnearlycostlesstondtheoptimalconsumptionatavectorofendogenouspointsforcash-at-hand~w=~a+b+cat(~a;b;IRt+1)istheamountatwhichconsumingcat(a;b;IRt+1)andleavingafornextperiodisoptimal.Welinearlyinterpolatebetweenthesepointstondanapproximationoftheconsumptionfunction.Notethatinadditiontothecurrentstateofassetsandthecreditlimit,theconsumptionfunctionisalsoafunctionofwhethertheconsumerisrevolvingbyhavingnegativeassetslastperiod.Whileitisnotacontinuousstate,theadditionofanotherstatevariablecomplicatesthesolutionsincewemustndtheoptimalconsumptionforbothrevolvers,whondconsuminglessvaluablesincetheycannotpayforitinquiteasconvenientway,andconvenienceusers.Forthemostpart,someonewhoisnotrevolvingthisperiodwillnotberevolvingnextperiodandsovt=t+1andthepaymentchoicedoesnotaffecttheconsumptiondecisiondirectly.Itdoes,however,makerevolvingsomewhatmorecostly.Sincetheconsumer'sproblemincludesbothanexternallyimposedcreditlimitaswellasinter-estratesthatdifferdependingonwhetherassetsarepositiveornegative,thereareseveraladditionalcomplications.TherstisthatthestandardEulerequationdoesnotholdwhentheconsumerisagainsthercreditlimitandsospendsallavailableresources,sinceshewouldliketospendmoretodaybutcannot(Deaton,1991).Thisproblemisrelativelyeasytodealwith,however,byinclud-ingtheinectionpoint,orthelastpointatwhichtheEulerequationholdsandsoassetsleftforthenextperiodare�bt.Foranycash-at-handlessthanw=cat(�b;b)

27 ,theconsumerconsumesallcash-at-hand,soct
,theconsumerconsumesallcash-at-hand,soct(w;b)=wifww.Thesecondproblemisthattheinterestratedifferen-tialintroducesastepintheconsumptionfunctionsincetherearetwosolutionstoequation(3)fora=0:One,thelimitwithassetsapproachingzerofrombelow,usestheborrowingrateRBandtheotherusesthesavingrateR.Theeconomicintuitionisthatleavingzeroassetsforthenextperiodisoptimalatahighborrowingratewellbeforeitisoptimalatlowsavingsrate.Forcash-at-handbe-22 tweenthesetwopoints,theconsumerhasamarginalpropensitytoconsumeofonesincethereturnonsavingsisnothighenoughtoinducehertosave,butthecostofborrowingissufcienttokeepherfromborrowingandsoadditionalresourcesgostraighttoconsumption.Todealwiththisissue,theendogenousgridpointsincludetwopointswherea=0:therstcBt=cat(0;b;RB)thesolutiontoequation(3)whena=0usingRBandwBt=0+b+cBt,andthesecondcFt=cat(0;b;R)andwFt.Betweenthepoints(wBt;cBt)and(wFt;cFt)theconsumerhasamarginalpropensitytoconsumeofone.FigureA-2showstheconsumptionfunctionatdifferentageswithaconstantabilitytoborrowoverthelifecycleofonefthofincome.8Severalpointsareworthdiscussing.First,thecon-sumptionfunctiongenerallyfallswithage.Thisoccursastheconsumerplansforretirementwhenhavingaccumulatedalargeamountofsavingsisvaluable.SincewesetbT+1=0,andtheremain-ingwealthisdividedamongthemanyyearsofretirement,consumptionoutofavailableresourcescT+1(wT+1)isquitelow.Planningforthishighdemandforsavingsmeansafterage45,consumersseektoaccumulatebyspendingmuchlessfromavailableresources.Earlyinthelife-cycle,retire-mentisfaraway,andshort-termshocksdominate,andsotheconsumptionfunctionat26isverysimilartotheoneat35and45.Second,forlowcash-at-handbelowwthemarginalp

28 ropensitytoconsumeisone.Betweenwandw
ropensitytoconsumeisone.BetweenwandwBtheconsumerisleavingdebtfornextperiod,andsoispayingahighinterestrateRB.BetweenwBandwFtheconsumerdoesnotwanttoborrow,butthereturnonsavingsisnothighenough,andsosheleaveszeroassetsandhasamarginalpropensitytoconsumeofone.Thiskinkintheconsumptionfunctionimpliesthattherecanbeapositivefractionofconsumerswhoholdexactlyzeroassets.ThedistancebetweenwBandwFdependsontheinterestratedifferential,withawiderdifferentialimplyingalargerdistance. 8TheotherrelevantparametersareasavingsrateR=1:03andborrowingrateRB=1:14,acoefcientofrelativeriskaversionof =2,adiscountparameter =0:9andotherparametersandretirementfunctionsmatchingGourinchasandParker(2002).23 5EstimationThissectiondescribesthedatausedtoestimatethemodel,theestimationprocedure,andthere-sults.Alongwithinformationontheincomeprocessdescribedbelowandthepaymentsparame-ters,thelife-cycleportionofthemodelisdescribedbyonlyfourparameters.Weallowforpref-erenceheterogeneitybyallowingfortwosub-populationswithdifferentpreferences.Ofcourse,additionalpreferenceheterogeneityispossible,butourresultsshowthatthisistheminimumhet-erogeneitynecessaryandwepreferthissimpleheterogeneitysinceitmakesobviousthecontribu-tionofdifferentpopulations.Therearethusthreeformsofheterogeneityintheestimatedmodel:ageaspeoplemakedifferentdecisionsatdifferentages;idiosyncraticheterogeneityaspeoplearehitwithdifferentshocksandsohavedifferentassetsandincomes;andpreferenceheterogeneityasdifferentsub-groupsreactdifferentlytoshocks.Foreachsub-groupweestimatethediscountrate ;coefcientofrelativeriskaversion ,andthefallinincomeattheendoflife1.Tocombinegroupsweestimatetheshareofg

29 roupA,fAinthepopulation.Incomeandinitial
roupA,fAinthepopulation.IncomeandinitialwealthmustbejointlydeterminedwithfAtokeepthesimulatedmeanincomeandinitialwealthequaltotheirobservedcounterparts.Toallowonegrouptohaveahigherincomethantheotheronaverage,weestimatethemultipleoftheaveragepermanentincomeearnedbygroupA,A,sothatifgroupAearnshalfofthepopulationaverageincomeA=0:5.TogetherfAandAdirectlydetermineB.Similarly,weestimatetheinitialliquidfundstoincomeratioofgroupAA0,andsofAdeterminesB0.9Finally,weestimatetheconveniencevalueofcreditcardsforpaymentsforrevolversRandconvenienceusersC.Weestimatealloftheotherparametersofthedecisioninaseparaterststage.Wethereforeestimate11parametersjointly=f A; A;A0;A1; B; B;B1;fA;A0;R;Cg.Weestimatetheparametersofthehighlynon-linearmodelthatbestmatchthelife-cycleevo-lutionofdebtandconsumptionusingtheMethodofSimulatedMoments(MSM)ofMcFadden(1989).Foragivensetofparameters2,andrststageparameterssuchastheinterest 9InorderfortheaverageincomeofthecombinedpopulationstoequaltheaverageobservedincomefAA+fBB=1which,sincefB=1�fA,impliesthatB=(1�fAA)=(1�fA).Similarly,sincefAA0+fBB0=InitialliquidfundstoincomethenB0=((Initialliquidfundstoincome)�fAA0)=(1�fA).24 rateandincomeprocessestimatedseparately,wenumericallyndconsumptionfunctionsateachage.Thenwithaninitialdistributionofinitialassets,income,andcreditlimits,wedrawastartingvaluefromthisdistributionforeachi=1toNconsumers.Eachconsumermakesaconsumptiondecision,leavingassetsfornextperiod.Foreachconsumer,wedrawthenextperiodincomeandcreditlimitsfromthe

30 irdistributionsandndhisorherconsumpt
irdistributionsandndhisorherconsumptionandthenassetsforthenextperiod.Thisprocessproceedsuntilthelastperiod,generatingforeveryagetheconsumptionandassetsforallNconsumers.Agivensetofmodelparameterscanthusgeneratealife-cycledistributionofconsumption,debt,andsavings.Withthesedistributions,itispossibletocalculatemomentsthatdescribethedistributionandattempttondtheparametersthatminimizethedifferencebetweenthesemomentsandtheirobservablecounterparts.GourinchasandParker(2002),forexample,calculatetheriskaversionanddiscountparametersthatmakethecalculatedmeanconsumptionoverthelife-cyclematchthehumpshapeobservedintheConsumerExpenditureSurvey.Cagetti(2003)insteadmatchestheaccumulationofwealthoverthelife-cycleasobservedintheSurveyofConsumerFinances.Moreformally,foragiven2,andrststageparametersestimatedbelow,wecandenethedifferencebetweenanempiricalmomentandasimulatedmomentasgj(;)foreachofJtotalmoments.Forexample,oneoftheempiricalmomentsweuseisthemeancreditcarddebtatage30estimatedfromtheEquifax/NYFED,andsoonemomentis:gj(;)=(1=I)IXi=1Di30�(1=N)NXk=1^D(;)k30where^D(;)i30isthesimulateddebtofpersoniatage30givenparameters;andDk30isthedebtofpersonkinEquifax/NYFedCCPatage30.TheseareaveragedovertheIpeopleintheCCPsample,andtheNpeoplewesimulate.TheMSMthenseekstominimizetheweightedsquareofthesedifferences:min2g(;)0Wg(;)(4)25 whereg(;)=(g1(;);:::;gJ(;))andWisaJJweightingmatrix.Wegenerallyusetheoptimalweightingmatrixproportionaltotheinversevarianceoftheempiricalmoments,whichgivesmoreweighttobetterestimatedmoments.5.1Theem

31 piricalmomentsandrststageestimatesWe
piricalmomentsandrststageestimatesWeestimatethemodeltoprovidethebestttotwolife-cyclemoments:(1)theobservedcreditcarddebtoverthelife-cyclefromtheNYFed/EquifaxConsumerCreditPaneldescribedinsection3andthe(2)householdconsumptionoverthelife-cyclefromtheConsumerExpenditureSurveyfrom2000-2014.Sinceourobservedcreditdataisfortheindividualaccountholder,ratherthanthehousehold,weadjusthouseholdconsumptionbydividingbythenumberofadultsinthehousehold.Weallowforsomeunobservedtastechangesoverthelife-cyclebyadjustingconsumptionforthenumberofchildreninthehousehold.10Tobeidentied,themodelrequiresanumberofotherancillaryparametersestimatedelse-where.WeadjustthestandarderrorsoftheMSMfortheserststageestimatesusingtheirvariance-covariancematricesfollowingLaibsonetal.(2007)whoalsoupdateGourinchasandParker(2002)byallowingfortheempiricalmomentstohavedifferentnumbersofobservations.WeusedatafromtheDiaryofConsumerPaymentChoicetondthefractionofconsumptiononacreditcardbyrevolversandconvenienceusers,anddiscusstheidenticationofthepaymentsproblembelow.Weestimatetheaveragelife-cyclegrowth(Gt)ofincomebasedafthorderpoly-nomialbesttofaftertaxincomeperadulthouseholdmemberfromtheConsumerExpenditureSurvey.TherawdataandthettedlinesareinappendixgureA-8.Similarly,wetakeafthdegreepolynomialestimateoftheaveragecreditlimitperaccountfromEquifax/NYFedCCPtoformBs.Notsmoothingthesetwobudgetconstraintsmakeslittledifferencetotheoverallesti- 10Formally,weestimateln(Ci;t=Adultsi;t)=a+t+ Childreni;t+i;tandthencalculateaveragehouseholdconsumptionperadultateachafterremovingtheeffectofchildrenatthein-dividuallevel.Theremovingt

32 heimpliedconsumptioneffectofchildrenhasa
heimpliedconsumptioneffectofchildrenhasasurprisinglysmalleffect.FigureA-8showstheunadjustedandadjustedconsumption.Childrenraiseexpendituresperadulthouseholdmemberslightlyfromages35-45,buttheadjustmentissmall.26 mates,butintroducesdistractingjumpsinlife-cycleconsumptionanddebtasconsumersrespondtoshort-termbudgetchanges.WeestimatetheinitialliquidfundstoincomeratioofthepopulationfromtheSCFforhouse-holdsage20-27.Liquidfundsareliquidnancialassets(savings,checking,moneymarket,stocks,bonds)plusavailablecredit(creditlimitminusdebt).Dividedbyonequarternormalincome,wecalculatethatthesehouseholdshaveanaverageof1.28quartersofnormalincomeinavailableliquidfunds.Whilethepopulationaverageincomefollowstheobservedlife-cyclepath,individualincomesvarybasedontheiridiosyncraticshocks.WeusetheestimatesoftheannualincomeprocessfromGourinchasandParker(2002),whichareupdatesofCarrollandSamwick(1997),calculatedfromthePanelStudyofIncomeDynamics.Weadjustthesevolatilitiesforquarterlydynamicssothatfourquarterlyshockscombinetoproducethesamevarianceasoneyearlyshock.Acloseapproximationisthatthequarterlytransitoryvariancemustbefourtimestheannualvariancesincequarterlyshocksaverageout,whilethequarterlypermanentvariancemustbeonefourththeyearlyvariancesincepermanentshocksstack.Weobservetwopricesdirectly,althoughthereislikelygreaterheterogeneityinthepricesactuallypaidthanweincorporateinthemodel.WesettheinterestrateondebtRb=14:11basedontheaveragerevolvinginterestrateovertheperiod,adjustedslightlyforthelackofexplicitdefaultriskinthemodel.11Sincethereisonlyonerisklessliquidassetotherthantheabilitytoborrow,theappropriaterateonsavingsisnotobvioussincewewouldliketocapture

33 thereturnsthatpeopleexpecttoreceiveonthe
thereturnsthatpeopleexpecttoreceiveontheirsavings.Wethereforesetthereturnonsavingsastheaveragereturnonanallbondportfoliofrom1926to2015ascalculatedbythemutualfundcompanyVanguardof5.4percent.Weadjustbothborrowingandsavingpricesforthegeometricaverageinationratefrom2000-2015of2.15percent.Intheexpectedgrowthoverthelife-cyclewealso 11WefollowFulford(2015)inusingtheEdelberg(2006)adjustmentfordefault.TheFederalReserveseriesG19(CommercialBankInterestRateonCreditCardPlansNSA)averageovertheperiodis14.73percent(theaveragecreditcardinterestratereportedintheSCFis14.22percent).BasedoncalculatingtheriskofdefaultfromthePSID,Edelberg(2006)calculatesthezerobankruptcyriskratewouldbe0.62percentagepointslower,asmalleradjustmentthaninAngeletosetal.(2001),whoadjustfordefaultby2percentagepoints.27 includeexpectedrealaggregategrowthof1.5%,theaveragecompoundedratefrom1947to2015fromtheBEA(2009chaineddollarsGDPpercapita).125.2IdenticationandestimationofthepaymentsproblemThestructureoftheconsumer'sproblemmeansthatthepaymentdecisionisonlyinuencedbytheconsumptiondecisionthroughwhetherornottheconsumerwasrevolvingasoftheperiodbefore.Wecanthusndthesolutiontothepaymentsproblemrst,andthenallowthesolutiontothepaymentproblemtoinuencetheconsumptionproblem.ThetwoparametersofthepaymentproblemareexactlyidentiedbytwomomentsweobserveintheDiaryofConsumerPaymentChoice:thefractionofconsumptionthatrevolversandconvenienceuserspayforwithacreditcard,alongwiththeobservablemarketrateonborrowingonacreditcard.Table2showsthefractionofallexpendituresoverathreedayperiodthatthenationallyrepre-sentativesampleofconsumersfromtheDairyofConsumerPaymentChoiceputonac

34 reditcard.Theaverageconsumerpaysfor17.2p
reditcard.Theaverageconsumerpaysfor17.2percentofconsumptionwithacreditcard.Revolverspayforslightlylessat15.6percentandconvenienceuserspayforslightlymoreat18.2percent.Dividingthepopulationbyagesuggeststhattheremaybemoresignicantdifferencesintheusagepatternsfortheyoung,butthoseinmiddleagehaveafairlystablepatternofcreditcarduse,withconve-nienceusersspendingslightlymorethanrevolversatmostages.Interestingly,bothrevolversandconvenienceusersover65tendtospendmoreonacreditcard.Perhapsthischangecomesfromashiftinthetypeofexpenditureafterretirement.Thedifferencebetweenrevolversandconvenienceusersthenexactlyidentiesthepayment 12Whileeachoftheseparametersisvolatileanddifferentagentsmayexperiencedifferentprices,thereisnoesti-mationuncertaintyaboutthemandsowedonotadjusttheMSMvariance-covariancematrixforthem.Putadifferentway:the“population”averageinterestrateisnotanestimateandsodoesnothaveastandarderror(itmaybeadrawfroma“super-population”process,butoureconomicagentsliveinthispopulation,andsotheonlyrelevantpriceistheonetheyface).Instead,theseparametersmaybemiss-specied,whichisamodelingproblem,notanestimationone.Economicagentsmayfaceuncertaintyabouttheirrateofreturn,ination,andeconomicgrowthwhichcanbemodeled,althoughwithinourmodelallagentstaketheseasgiven.Similarly,therearemultiplewaysofsavingwithdifferentratesofreturn,andasinglerateofreturnonlyimperfectlycapturesthisheterogeneity.WethankChrisCarrollforpointingoutthatevenifweremovetrendsfromlife-cycleproles,theeconomicdecisionoftheagentincludesexpectedaggregategrowth.28 modelasgure3illustrates.Sincerevolverslosetheoatonpurchases,theirpaymentsuseofacr

35 editcardisshifteddownbyanamountequaltoth
editcardisshifteddownbyanamountequaltothelossofoat.ThedifferenceintheoptimalfractiononacreditcardRandCidentiestheslopeandinterceptofthetwolines.WeuseasimpleDeltamethodexpansiontocalculatethestandarderrorsforthepaymentparameters0and1.AppendixCshowsthesecalculationsandTable2showstheestimatedcoefcientswithaninterestrateonborrowingof14.11percentadjustedforinationof2.15percent(seediscussioninsection5.1).Themodelthendirectlygivestheconveniencevalueofcreditcreditcards.Atcloseto12percentrealborrowingrate,theconveniencevalueofusingacreditcardforpaymentsoverothermethodsisworth0.319percentofconsumptiontoconvenienceusersand0.235percenttore-volvers.Thiscalculationistheconsumersurplusofcreditcardsasapaymentmechanismandsodoesnotdirectlycalculatewelfare.Theaverageconveniencedependsonthefractionofrevolversandconvenienceusers.Inaddition,thecalculationdoesnottakeintoaccountthecostsofoperatingthepaymentssystemortheproducersurplusfromadditionalsalesmadebecausesomepurchasesaremoreconvenient,orthegainstotheprocessors,networkoperators,andbanks.Nonetheless,a0.319percentmultipleofallconsumptionisasubstantialnumber,andsinceitisproducedfromonlythe18.2percentofconsumptionpaidforwithacreditcard,suggeststhatthevaluethatcon-sumersgetfromusingcreditcardsforthepurchasestheydousethemforisverylarge.Thevalueoftheintercept0,forexample,suggeststhatforthemostvaluablepurchases,usingacreditcardhasaconveniencevalueof4.1percentofallconsumptionforthesepurchases.Forcomparison,ifallconvenienceconsumersreceivedtheequivalentofonepercentcashbackontheirpurchaseswithcreditcards,theimpliedconsumersurplusis0.182percentofconsumption.Thiscalcu

36 lationlikelyoverstatesthedirectvalueofre
lationlikelyoverstatesthedirectvalueofrewardssincenotallcardsofferrewards,butsuggeststhatintheneighborhoodofhalfoftheconveniencevaluefromcreditcardscomesfromdirectrewardsandtheotherhalffromtheirvalueasaconvenientpaymentmechanism.29 5.3Identicationandestimationofthelife-cyclemodelUsingtherststageestimatesofthepaymentsproblemandtheotherparameters,wenextestimatethefulllife-cycleproblemandthendiscussthevariationthathelpsidentifythedifferentparam-eters.13Table3showsthemodelestimateswhilegure4showsthehowdebtandconsumptionvaryoverthelife-cycle.Sincethescaleofthetwopanelsofgure4isinlogs,theMSMises-sentiallyndingtheparameterssothatthesumofthesquareddifferencesbetweenthepredictedconsumptionanddebtlinesisassmallaspossible.Itisclearthatgiventheconstraintsoftheop-timizationmodel,themodelestimatescansuccessfullycapturethelife-cycleprolesofdebtandconsumption.Todoso,themodelsuggeststhatabouthalfthepopulation(fA)mustbeimpatientandalmostriskneutral.Thishalfofthepopulation,whichthegureandtablescallpopulationA,startslifewithasubstantialamountofdebt(A0)andhassubstantialrevolvingdebtthroughoutthelife-cycle.Inordertomatchtheamountofdebtandconsumption,theestimatessuggestthatthispopulationhasaslightlyhigherincomethantheaverage(A)andsoititisconsumingalmostallofitsincomeinanygivenquarter.Thispopulationthuslivesessentiallyhand-to-mouthovertheentirelife-cycle.Itreliesoncreditforallofitssmoothing,althoughitsaverageutilizationishighthroughmuchofthelife-cycle(thethirdpanelingure4),andsoitisnotkeepingmuchcreditforprecautionaryreasonseither.Theestimatessuggestthattheotherhalfofthepopulationisrelativelypatientandriskavers

37 e.Itsriskaversionislowerthanmanyestimate
e.Itsriskaversionislowerthanmanyestimateswhichareoftenaround2,butarehigherthantheestimatesinGourinchasandParker(2002).PopulationBistoopatienttoeverwanttoholdmuchdebtandquicklyrepaystheinitialdebtwhichtheestimatessuggestitholds(A0).Afteraboutage30,thispopulationonlyusescreditcardsforpayments.14Sincetheestimatessuggestthatthispopulationexpectstoreceivelittleincomeafterexpenses(B1)inlatelifeanditisrelatively 13Inrobustnesschecks,itappearsthatthequadraticfunctioninequation(4)hasmultiplelocalminima.Wediscusswhatappearstobethebestlocalminimumhere,butexpectthatinfutureversionswewillprovidegreaterevidencethatitisindeedthebestminimumbasedonstartingtheestimationatagridofstartingpoints.Wealsoplantocharacterizeotherminimaandhowtheyhelpunderstandidentication.14Theaddeddebtfromconvenienceuseofcreditcardsisonemonthworthofconsumption(1/3ofquarterlycon-sumption)timestheestimatedrateofconsumptiononacreditcardforaconvenienceuserfromtable2.30 patient,almosttheentirelife-cycleisspentacquiringassetsforoldage.Consumptionisthereforerelativelyatovertheentirelife-cyclesinceitisattemptingtosmoothoverthisfallinincomeafterexpenses.Sincethisisahighlynon-linearmodel,allmomentsaretypicallyusedtoidentifyallparame-ters,butitisusefultounderstandhowdifferentsourcesofvariationidentifytheparameters.Boththeconsumptionanddebtthatweobserveoverthelife-cycleareaveragesovertheentirepopula-tion,andsothemodelisidentiedoffoftheaverageofthetwopopulations.Theestimatesshowthatforthemodeltoproduceasmuchdebtasinthedata,approximatelyhalfofthepopulationmustberelativelyimpatientandnotmuchconcernedaboutdebt.Sincethispopulationlivesnearlyhand-to-mouth,itsconsumpt

38 ioncloselyfollowsincomeoverthelife-cycle
ioncloselyfollowsincomeoverthelife-cycle.Togetanaverageconsumptionproleinwhichconsumptionisbelowincomeformuchofthelife-cyclethereforerequirestheotherhalfofthepopulationtoberelativelypatientandriskaverse.Thispopulationistoopatienttokeepmuchdebtathighinterestrates,andpaysoffalmostallofcreditcarddebtithasearlyinlifebyitsmid20s.Mostofthelife-cycledynamicsofdebtthereforecomefromtheimpatientpopulation.Whilethelevelofconsumptionanddebtcomesfromtheaverage,thelife-cycleprolesarelargelydeterminedbyonlyoneofthepopulations.Sincethepatientpopulationcarriesalmostnodebt,theproleofcreditcarddebtlargelyidentiesthepreferencesoftheimpatientpopulation,theirinitialwealth,andtheirexpectedresidualincomelateinlife.Thediscountrateofthispopu-lationislargelyidentiedbytherealinterestoncreditcarddebt;ifthepopulationistoopatient,thenitwillnotaccumulateenoughdebt,tooimpatientanditwillacquiretolittledebt.Forthisimpatientpopulation,thehumpshapeofdebtcomesfromincreasesincreditlimitsearlyinlifewhichallowsittoincreasesitsdebts,andthefallinincomelateinlifewhichmakescarryingdebtmorepainful.Theriskaversionisidentiedbyhowmuchcreditthispopulationkeepsasabuffer.Themorepatientandriskaversepopulationcarrieslittledebtpastits20s,soitspreferencesarelargelyidentiedbytheconsumptionprole.TheimpatientpopulationAhasastronghumpinconsumptionasitfollowsincome.Fortheaverageconsumptionproletobebelowaverage31 income,thepatientpopulationBmusthavearelativelyatconsumptionprole.Itspreferencesforrisk( B),discountrate( B),andexpectedlatelifeincomeafterexpensesB)aredeterminedbythisshape.Thediscountrateisalsocloselyidentiedbytherateofret

39 urnonsavings.Theestimatedmodelmatchesoth
urnonsavings.Theestimatedmodelmatchesotherlife-cycleprolessuchastheutilizationandthewealthpathwellasshownintheremainingpanelsofgure4.Creditutilizationstartshighandslowlyfallsoverthelife-cycle.Theestimatessuggestthatutilizationisonaverageslightlylowerthanweobserveinthedata.Toexaminetheevolutionofwealth,whichmaybenegative,wetakethelogofwealthaftergivingeveryone$10,000,whichallowsustoconsiderthefulldistributioninasinglegraph.Themodelestimatespredictslightlylesswealthaccumulationoverthelife-cyclethantheSCF,butpredictsthesametrendincreaseandatteningafterage55.Themodelwasnotestimatedtomatchthesetwoproles,andsobeingabletosuccessfullypredicttheirevolutionsuggeststhatthemodeliscapturingimportantfacetsoflife-cycledecisionmaking.Theheterogeneityinpreferencesiskeyhere.GourinchasandParker(2002)estimateparameterstomatchtheconsumptionproleandvastlyunder-predictwealthaccumulation,whileCagetti(2003)estimatesparameterstomatchthewealthprole,butneedsahighdegreeofrisk-aversethathecannotcapturetheconsumptionprole.Themodelpredictsthatthefractionrevolvingwillbeapproximatelyconstantoverthelife-cycle,whiletheSCFsuggestsitshoulddeclinenearlycontinuously.15Thepopulationaveragefractionrevolvinginthemodelisapproximatelycorrect,butsincetheimpatientpopulationAisalwaysindebt,andthepatientpopulationBalmostneverrevolves,thefractionrevolvingdoesnotchangemuchoverthelife-cycle.Itispossiblethatadditionalheterogeneityacrossthepopulationcouldreplicatethisbehaviorbyallowingpartofthepopulationtobeontheedgebetweenrevolvingandnot,withthebalanceshiftingoverthelife-cycle.Theproblemwiththisapproachisthatthedifferencebetweenthesavingsinterestrateand

40 theborrowingrateissolargethatitisonlyfor
theborrowingrateissolargethatitisonlyfor 15SincetheSCFsometimeshastroublewithdebts(Zinman,2009),andisatahouseholdratherthanindividuallevel,thereisreasontoquestionwhethertheSCFfractionrevolvingisthebestbenchmark.OurestimatesfromtheDairyofConsumerPaymentsChoiceinappendixgureA-1suggestthatthethefractionrevolvingisapproximatelyconstantuntilage50,butthendeclinessteadily.Whilethisproleisclosertothemodelprediction,themodelisstillnotpredictingamovementoutofrevolvinglateinlife.32 veryparticularpreferencesthatsomeonewhoisnotwillingtoborrowlateinlifewouldbewillingtoborrowearlyinlife.Suchparticularpreferencesareverysensitivetochangesininterestrates,whichsuggeststhatcredituseissensitivetointerestrates.Thestabilityofutilizationin1despitelargechangesininterestratesovertheperiodsuggeststhattheanswermustlieelsewhere.Instead,itseemslikelythatthereissomesortofpreferenceheterogeneityoverthelife-cycle.Youngpeoplewhothinkthemselvesinvinciblemayhavelowriskaversion,sincetheyhavenotseenthebadconsequencesofpoorplanning,butbecomeincreasinglypatientandriskaverseastheyageandexperiencebadshocks.Thelasttwocolumnsoftable3showestimatesthatuseadifferentweightingmatrixandturnofftheendogenouspaymentchoicebymakingallconsumersgettherevolvingvaluefromcredituse.Optimalweightsgiveeachmomentaweightproportionaltohowwellitisestimated.Sincethedebtmomentsareestimatedfromlargesampleofadministrativedata,theestimationtendstoputmoreweightonminimizingthedebtresiduals.Analternativeweightingschemeistoallowoptimalweightingwithineachofthecreditanddebtmoments,butrenormalizesothattheaveragemomentfordebtandconsumptiongetsthesameweight.Thisweightmatrixproducesnearlyidenticalesti

41 mates.Similarly,theendogenouspaymentscho
mates.Similarly,theendogenouspaymentschoicedoesnotmuchaffecttheestimates.Thereasonisthatsincesofewpeopleswitchfromrevolvingtoconvenienceuse,thevalueanindividualgetsfromcreditcardconsumptionthisperiodisalmostalwaysthesameasnextperiod.Inmarginalutilitythevalueofconsumptiononacreditcarddoesnotaffectthetradeoffbetweentodayandthefuture.Itmakesnotrevolvingslightlymorevaluable,butsincehardlyanyoneisontheedge,thisvaluedoesnotmatter.Includingcreditcardsasapaymentmechanismisimportant,however.Thedebtsweobserveinthecreditbureaudataincludebothrevolvingandconvenienceuseandnotaccountingfortheconvenienceusewouldmaketheaveragedebttoohigh.5.4ModelpredictionsforthebusinesscycleandindividualsInthissection,wetakethemodelandestimatedparametersandaskhowwellitpredictsphenom-enaoutsidethelife-cyclethatitwasnotestimatedtomatch.Agoodwaytothinkoftheseresults33 isthattheyprovidebothanout-of-sampleexaminationofhowgoodthemodelestimatesareandwhetherthemodelcansuccessfullyexplainotherphenomena.Wetakethisexaminationasdistinctfromourdiscussionintheprevioussectionofwhetherthemodelcanreplicateotherlife-cyclemomentssuchasutilizationandwealthwhichhelpvalidatethemodel.Showingthatthemodelcanhelpunderstandindividualandbusinesscycledynamics,ontheotherhand,providesatestofthemodelpredictions.ToperformthistestwesimulatealargepopulationwiththesameageproleasinEquifaxfromage24to74.Weallowfortheconstantrealgrowthof1.5percenttheconsumersinthemodelassume,andadjustthedollarvaluesfortheaverageinationrate.Finally,tomimicthefallincreditlimitsthatstartedinthelastquarterin2008andwentthrough2009,weintroduceafallincreditof40percenttoonesixthofthepopulationforsixquarters.Thisparti

42 cularexperimentisthesimplestwaytogetthea
cularexperimentisthesimplestwaytogettheapproximately40percentdropincreditlimitsspreadovermorethanayearevidentingure1.Itisnotafullreplicationofthechangingenvironment.Inparticular,itdoesnotincludeafallinincomeoradeclineinthecondenceaboutfutureincomegrowth.Theindividualdynamicsofcreditutilizationfromthesimulationscloselymatchthedynamicsfromthecreditbureaudata.Intable1weshowedthat,oncewecontrolforxedunobservedhet-erogeneitywithxedeffects,shockstoutilizationdisappearquickly,with64.7percentofashocksurvivingeachquarter(thethirdcolumn).Thelastcolumnperformsexactlythesameregressiononthesimulateddata.Thesimulatedconsumersexperiencethelargeunexpectedfallincreditinover2009,andtheexpectedincreaseoverthelife-cycle,buttheonlyunexpectedcreditvolatilitythattheyfacecomesbecausecreditisproportionaltovolatilepermanentincome.Sincevolatilityinincomeismuchlessthanvolatilityincredit(Fulford,2015),theconsumersinthemodelfacelesscreditvolatilitythanactualconsumersoverthetimeperiod.Nonetheless,theirresponsetochangesincreditlimtsareveryclosetoactualconsumers;theestimatedmodelcapturesthedynamicsofcreditutilizationnearlyexactlywith68.3percentofashockpersistingtothenextquarter.Wenallyexaminethebusinesscycledynamicswithwhichwestartedthepaper.Thebot-tompanelofgure1showstheaggregateresponseofthesimulatedconsumerstothe40percent34 fallincreditintroducedoversixquarters.Creditincreasesatthesame1.5percentrealrateasincome,plus2.1percentforaverageination.Modelcreditgrowthisslightlyslowerthantheac-tualcreditgrowthovertheperiodsuggestingthatpeggingcredittoincomedoesnotfullycapturetheaggregategrowth.Sincewealreadycapturethemuchlargerlife-cyclech

43 anges,theremainingunexplainedaggregategr
anges,theremainingunexplainedaggregategrowthduringtheperiodisunimportantforindividualdecisions.Sinceconsumersexpectcreditgrowth,theirdebtsgrowatthesametime,andcreditutilizationisstabledespitethegrowthbeforeandafterthecrisisjustasinthedata.Thesimulatedpopulationhasaslightlylowercreditutilizationoverthelife-cycle(seegure4),andsoalowercreditutilizationinaggregate.Duringthecrisis,debtquicklyadjuststothefallincredit,andsoutilizationismuchsmootherthaneithercreditordebt.Astheindividualdynamicsshow,whileshocksattheindividualleveldisappearquicklyinboththemodelanddata,itstilltakesseveralquartersforconsumerstofullyadjusttheirdebtandsavingstoa40percentfallincredit.Theexcessivesmoothnessofutilizationinthecreditbureaudatasuggeststhattheremaybeadditionalfeaturesoftheperiodnotcapturedbythesimplesimulatedshock,sincethesimulateddatacloselymatchestheindividualresponsestoafallincredit.Thesimulationdoesnotincludeanydeclineinincomewhich,ifexpectedtobepermanent,wouldalsodecreasedebt.Thefallincreditwasalsomoreconcentratedamongsomeconsumers.Whileinitiallythedeclinewasconcentratedamongthosewithhighcreditscores,laterdeclinesweretothosewithlowercreditscores(Fulford,2015),whoseresponsestoafallinlimitsareevenfasterthanaverage(seeourworkingpaper(FulfordandSchuh,2015)formoreevidenceonheterogeneityofresponses).6ConclusionCreditismorevolatilethanincomeoverboththebusinesscycleandlife-cycle.Creditincreasesveryquicklyearlyinlife,yetsincedebtfollowstheseincreases,creditutilizationdecreasesonlyslowlyoverthelife-cycle.Creditutilizationisalsoremarkablystableacrossthebusinesscycle35 despiteanearly40percentdropfollowingthenancialcrisisin2008.Weshowthatthisstabili

44 tycomesfromindividualdecisionsasshocksto
tycomesfromindividualdecisionsasshockstocreditutilizationquicklydisappear.Weintroduceandestimateamodeloflife-cycleconsumption,saving,anddebtthatexplainsthisstability.Creditplaysaprecautionaryroleinthemodel,andsoconsumersmanageitjustastheywouldanybufferofsavings.Creditcardsarealsousedforpaymentsandthisformofdebtissmoothedlikeconsumption.Bothaspectspointstostablecredituse.Weestimatethepaymentsaspectusingthedifferingcreditcarduseforpaymentsofrevolversandconvenienceusersandndthatthepaymentsvalueofcreditcardsisworth0.319percentofconsumptionforconvenienceusers.Estimatingtherestofourmodeloffofthelife-cycleofdebtandconsumption,weshowthatitcanproducethelife-cycleprolesofconsumptionanddebt.Italsopredictsthestableutilizationoverthebusinesscycleandforindividuals.Whiletheestimatedmodeldoescapturetheslowfallinutilizationoverthelifecycle,itpredictsaconstantfractionofthepopulationrevolving,ratherthanasteadydeclineoverthelifecycle.Withfullyforwardlookingbutveryimpatientconsumers,life-cycleconcernsarenotsufcienttogetthosewillingtoborrowinearlylifetostopborrowingatalllateinlife.Instead,thedeclinesuggeststhatsomeadditionalformoflearningorpreferencechangesisneeded.Oneofthestartlingfactsofconsumernanceishowlittlethemedianhouseholdsaves,par-ticularlyinliquidform.Theincreasesincreditoverthelife-cyclehelptoexplainwhyconsumerssavesolittleearlyinlife.Inexpectation,thecreditlimitfortheaveragepersoninher20swillbemuchhighernextyear.Sincecreditisaformofwealthforprecautionarypurposes(Fulford,2013),theyoungareeffectivelybecomingwealthierthroughcreditincreases,reducingtheirneedtosave.Inmiddleage,ontheotherhand,manyhouseholdshavesubstantialdebt.Fo

45 rthesehouse-holds,savingshouldbemostlyab
rthesehouse-holds,savingshouldbemostlyaboutpayingdownpreviousdebt.Payingoffcreditcarddebthasarisklessreturnthataverages14percent,whichnootherassetclasscanmatch.Thelargelife-cyclevariationincreditanddebtsuggestswhytheaveragehouseholdhaslittleinpositiveassetsbeyondasmallemergencyfundandilliquidhousinguntilverylateinlife:itgenerallyhassubstantialandincreasingcredit,andcansavebypayingdowndebt.Nottakingthisvariationintoaccountleads36 toamisunderstandingofthenancialstatusofU.S.households.37 ReferencesAgarwal,Sumit,SouphalaChomsisengphet,NealeMahoney,andJohannesStroebel.2015.“DoBanksPassThroughCreditExpansions?TheMarginalProtabilityofConsumerLendingDur-ingtheGreatRecession.”Technicalreport,SSRN.Agarwal,Sumit,JohnC.Driscoll,XavierGabaix,andDavidLaibson.2007.“TheAgeofReason:FinancialDecisionsOvertheLifecycle.”WorkingPaper13191,NationalBureauofEconomicResearch.Angeletos,George-Marios,DavidLaibson,AndreaRepetto,JeremyTobacman,andStephenWeinberg.2001.“TheHyperbolicConsumptionModel:Calibration,Simulation,andEmpiri-calEvaluation.”TheJournalofEconomicPerspectives,15(3):pp.47–68.Athreya,KartikB.2008.“Default,insurance,anddebtoverthelife-cycle.”JournalofMonetaryEconomics,55(4):752–774.Attanasio,OrazioP.,JamesBanks,CostasMeghir,andGuglielmoWeber.1999.“HumpsandBumpsinLifetimeConsumption.”JournalofBusiness&EconomicStatistics,17(1):pp.22–35.Attanasio,OrazioP.,andMartinBrowning.1995.“ConsumptionovertheLifeCycleandovertheBusinessCycle.”TheAmericanEconomicReview,85(5):pp.1118–1137.Avery,RobertB.,PaulS.Calem,andGlennB.Canner.2004.“CreditReportAccuracyandAccessto

46 Credit.”FederalReserveBulletin,Summ
Credit.”FederalReserveBulletin,Summer:297–322.Aydin,Deniz.2015.“Themarginalpropensitytoconsumeoutofliquidity:Evidencefromaran-domizedcontrolledtrial.”2015MeetingPapers270,SocietyforEconomicDynamics.Cagetti,Marco.2003.“WealthAccumulationOvertheLifeCycleandPrecautionarySavings.”JournalofBusinessandEconomicStatistics,21(3):339–353.Campbell,JohnY.,andN.GregoryMankiw.1989.“Consumption,Income,andInterestRates:ReinterpretingtheTimeSeriesEvidence.”NBERMacroeconomicsAnnual,4:185–216.Campbell,JohnY,andNGregoryMankiw.1990.“PermanentIncome,CurrentIncome,andCon-sumption.”JournalofBusiness&EconomicStatistics,8(3):265–79.Carroll,ChristopherD.1997.“BufferStockSavingandtheLifeCycle/PermanentIncomeHy-pothesis.”QuarterlyJournalofEconomics,112(1):1–55.Carroll,ChristopherD.2006.“Themethodofendogenousgridpointsforsolvingdynamicstochas-ticoptimizationproblems.”EconomicsLetters,91(3):312–320.Carroll,ChristopherD.2012.“SolutionMethodsforMicroeconomicDynamicStochasticOp-timizationProblems.”Available:http://www.econ2.jhu.edu/people/ccarroll/SolvingMicroDSOPs/,accessed3June2015.38 Carroll,ChristopherD.,andAndrewA.Samwick.1997.“Thenatureofprecautionarywealth.”JournalofMonetaryEconomics,40(1):41–71.Cocco,JoãoF.,FranciscoJ.Gomes,andPascalJ.Maenhout.2005.“ConsumptionandPortfolioChoiceovertheLifeCycle.”ReviewofFinancialStudies,18(2):491–533.DeNardi,Mariacristina,EricFrench,andJohnB.Jones.2010.“WhyDotheElderlySave?TheRoleofMedicalExpenses.”JournalofPoliticalEconomy,118(1):pp.39–75.Deaton,Angus.1991.“Savingand

47 LiquidityConstraints.”Econometrica,
LiquidityConstraints.”Econometrica,59(5):1221–1248.Deaton,Angus.1992.UnderstandingConsumption.Oxford:ClarendonPress.Deaton,Angus.1997.TheAnalysisofHouseholdSurveys:AMicroeconometricApproachtoDe-velopmentPolicy.Baltimore:JohnsHopkinsUniversityPress.Deaton,Angus.2010.“UnderstandingtheMechanismsofEconomicDevelopment.”TheJournalofEconomicPerspectives,24(3):pp.3–16.Edelberg,Wendy.2006.“Risk-basedpricingofinterestratesforconsumerloans.”JournalofMon-etaryEconomics,53(8):2283–2298.Fulford,Scott.2013.“Theeffectsofnancialdevelopmentintheshortandlongrun:TheoryandevidencefromIndia.”JournalofDevelopmentEconomics,104:56–72.Fulford,ScottL.2015.“Howimportantisvariabilityinconsumercreditlimits?”JournalofMon-etaryEconomics,72:42–63.Fulford,ScottL.,andScottSchuh.2015.“Consumerrevolvingcreditanddebtoverthelife-cycleandbusinesscycle.”April,Inpreparation.Gourinchas,Pierre-Olivier,andJonathanA.Parker.2002.“ConsumptionOvertheLifeCycle.”Econometrica,70(1):47–89.Gross,DavidB.,andNicholasS.Souleles.2002.“DoLiquidityConstraintsandInterestRatesMatterforConsumerBehavior?EvidencefromCreditCardData.”QuarterlyJournalofEco-nomics,117(1):149–185.Iacoviello,Matteo,andMarinaPavan.2013.“Housinganddebtoverthelifecycleandoverthebusinesscycle.”JournalofMonetaryEconomics,60(2):221–238.Kaboski,JosephP.,andRobertM.Townsend.2011.“AStructuralEvaluationofaLarge-ScaleQuasi-ExperimentalMicronanceInitiative.”Econometrica,79:1357–1406.Karlan,Dean,andJonathanZinman.2010.“ExpandingCreditAccess:UsingRandomizedSupplyDecisionstoEstim

48 atetheImpacts.”TheReviewofFinancial
atetheImpacts.”TheReviewofFinancialStudies,23(1):433.Laibson,David,AndreaRepetto,andJeremyTobacman.2007.“EstimatingDiscountFunctionswithConsumptionChoicesovertheLifecycle.”WorkingPaper13314,NationalBureauofEco-nomicResearch.39 Lawrence,EmilyC.1995.“ConsumerDefaultandtheLifeCycleModel.”JournalofMoney,CreditandBanking,27(4):939–954.Lee,Donghoon,andWilbertvanderKlaauw.2010.“AnIntroductiontotheFRBNYConsumerCreditPanel.”StaffReport479,FederalReserveBankofNewYork,Available:http://newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr479.pdf,accessed6April2015.Leth-Petersen,Søren.2010.“IntertemporalConsumptionandCreditConstraints:DoesTotalEx-penditureRespondtoanExogenousShocktoCredit?”TheAmericanEconomicReview,100(3):1080–1103.Lopes,Paula.2008.“CreditCardDebtandDefaultovertheLifeCycle.”JournalofMoney,CreditandBanking,40(4):769–790.Ludvigson,Sydney.1999.“ConsumptionandCredit:AModelofTime-VaryingLiquidityCon-straints.”ReviewofEconomicsandStatistics,81(3):434–447.McFadden,Daniel.1989.“AMethodofSimulatedMomentsforEstimationofDiscreteResponseModelsWithoutNumericalIntegration.”Econometrica,57(5):995–1026.Parker,JonathanA.,NicholasS.Souleles,DavidS.Johnson,andRobertMcClelland.2013.“Con-sumerSpendingandtheEconomicStimulusPaymentsof2008.”AmericanEconomicReview,103(6):2530–53.Schuh,Scott,andJoannaStavins.2014.“The2011and2012SurveysofConsumerPaymentChoice.”ResearchDataReports14-1,FederalReserveBankofBoston.Stango,Victor,andJonathanZinman.2009.“WhatDoConsumersReallyPayonTheirCheckingandCreditCardAccounts?Explicit,Implicit,andAvoidab

49 leCosts.”TheAmericanEconomicReviewP
leCosts.”TheAmericanEconomicReviewPapersandProceedings,99(2):424–429.Stepner,Michael.2013.“BINSCATTER:Statamoduletogeneratebinnedscatterplots.”StatisticalSoftwareComponents,BostonCollegeDepartmentofEconomics,October.Telyukova,IrinaA.2013.“HouseholdNeedforLiquidityandtheCreditCardDebtPuzzle.”Re-viewofEconomicStudies,80(3):1148–1177.Telyukova,IrinaA.,andRandallWright.2008.“AModelofMoneyandCredit,withApplicationtotheCreditCardDebtPuzzle.”ReviewofEconomicStudies,75:629–647.Zinman,Jonathan.2009.“Whereisthemissingcreditcarddebt?Cluesandimplications.”ReviewofIncomeandWealth,55(2):249–265.Zinman,Jonathan.2013.“ConsumerCredit:TooMuchorTooLittle(orJustRight)?”WorkingPaper19682,NationalBureauofEconomicResearch.Zinman,Jonathan.2015.“HouseholdDebt:Facts,Puzzles,Theories,andPolicies.”AnnualReviewofEconomics,7:251–276.40 Figure1:Creditcardlimits,debt,andutilization:2000–2014Observedlimits,debts,andutilization Modelpredictiongivenfallincreditlimits Notes:Theleftaxisshowstheaveragecreditcardlimits(topline)anddebt(bottomline).Notethelogscale.Therightaxisshowsmeancreditutilization(middleline)denedasthecreditcarddebt/creditcardlimitifthelimitisgreaterthanzero.Source:Authors'calculationsfromEquifax/NYFedCCP.41 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9 1Credit utilization 4000 5000 6000 8000 10000 14000Credit and debt ($ log scale) 2000q1 2005q1 2010q1 2015q1Date Mean credit card limitMean credit card debt Figure2:Creditcardlimits,debt,andcreditutilization Notes:Eachlinerepresentstheaveragecreditcardlimit,debt,andutilizationofonebirthcohort,1999–2014.Source:Aut

50 hors'calculationsfromEquifax/NYFedCCP.42
hors'calculationsfromEquifax/NYFedCCP.42 Credit Limit Credit Debt 1 5 10 20 50 100 redit card limit or debt, thousands (if positive) Credit Utilization 0 .2 .4 .6 .8Credit card debt / Credit Card limit 20 40 60 80Age Figure1:creditlimit,creditdebt,andcreditutilization Figure3:Marginalvalueofadditionalconsumptiononacreditcard Notes:Thisgureillustrateshowthemarginalvalueofadditionalconsumptiononacreditcardchangeswiththesharespentonacreditcard.Thetoplineisforconvenienceuserswhoputasharecofconsumptiononacreditcard.Thebottomlineforrevolversisshifteddownbytheamount�rb=24sincerevolverslosetheoatonpaymentsmadeusingcreditcards.TheythereforeputasmallershareontheircreditcardsR.43 Share of consumption on credit card π 0 1 Marginal value of additional consumption on a credit card ν 0 Slope - ν 1 π C ν 0 - r B /24 π R 0 Figure4:Consumptionanddebtoverthelife-cycle:modelestimatesEstimationmoments:DebtEstimationmoments:Consumption Estimationpredictions:UtilizationEstimationpredictions:Fractionrevolving Estimationpredictions:WealthpathEstimationpredictions:Varianceofdebt Notes:44 Age 30 40 50 60 70 Variance 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 Model variance log debt Equifax variance credit card debt Age 30 40 50 60 70 Credit card debt and limit ($, log scale) 200 500 1,000 2,000 5,000 10,000 20,000 Model debt Equifax credit card debt Equifax credit card limit Population A debt Population B debt Age 30 40 50 60 70 Consumption and income ($ quarterly, log scale) 3000 5000 8000 10000 Model consumption CEX consumption CEX income and model income Population A consumption Population B consumption Age 30 40 50 60 70 0 0.2 0.4 0.6

51 0.8 1 Model utilization Equifax utiliza
0.8 1 Model utilization Equifax utilization Population A Population B Age 30 40 50 60 70 Fraction 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Model fraction revolving SCF fraction revolving Population A Population B Age 30 40 50 60 70 log wealth ($, log scale) 5,000 10,000 20,000 50,000 100,000 Model mean log wealth+10,0000 SCF per person mean log wealth+10,000 Table1:Creditutilization Equifax/NYFedCCPModel Creditutilizationt Creditutilizationt�10.874***0.868***0.647***0.647***0.514***0.683***(0.000876)(0.000892)(0.00131)(0.00139)(0.00441)(0.000329)Creditutilizationt�20.0156***(0.000643)Creditutilt�1Age0.00314***(9.93e-05)Constant0.0479***(0.000461)Observations347,642347,642347,642332,696347,6424,752,000R-squared0.7410.7430.4290.4440.4310.489FixedeffectsNoNoYesYesYesYesAgeandyeareffectsNoYesYesYesYesYesNumberofaccounts10,45110,10310,451102,564Frac.VariancefromFE0.4770.4670.4980.292 Notes:Thesampleincludes0creditutilizationbutexcludesindividualquarterswheretheutilizationisundenedsincethelimitiszeroandwhenutilizationisgreaterthan5(averysmallfraction,seedistributionsofutilizationingure).Allcolumnsincludeageandyeareffects,withageeffectsnormalizedtohavezerotrendwhenxedeffectsareincluded.Source:Authors'calculationsfromEquifax/NYFedCCP. 45 Table2:Fractionofconsumptiononacreditcardandvalueforpayments FractiononStd.Std.Creditcarderrordev. Allconsumers0.1720.00820.310Allrevolvers0.1560.01300.283Allconvenienceusers0.1820.01050.324Revolvers Age250.2340.07600.30125Age350.1570.02870.29935Age450.1340.03440.28245Age550.1420.02130.14255Age650.1440.02070.144Age&#x-250;=650.2020.03990.312ConvenienceUsers Age250.0650.02330.20925Age350.1690.02550.

52 16935Age450.1550.02280.29145Age550.1730.
16935Age450.1550.02280.29145Age550.1730.02150.32755Age650.2160.02420.345Age&#x-250;=650.2430.02710.350 ModelEstimates Level00.0350.0216Slope10.1940.1259 ImpliedvalueofCreditCarduse(inpercentofconsumption) Revolvers0.235%0.1512Convenienceusers0.319%0.0962 Notes:Author'scalculationsfromtheDiaryofConsumerPaymentChoice.Thestandarderrorsarecalculatedbybootstrapping.46 Table3:Modelestimates PopulationACRRA A0.1540.1640.176(0.015)(0.018)(0.019)Discount A0.8890.8890.889(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)InitialwealthA0-5.320-2.725-2.734(1.031)(0.091)(0.094)Latelifeinc.A10.5150.5220.545(0.009)(0.009)(0.008)PopulationBCRRA A0.9360.8680.958(0.202)(0.217)(0.249)Discount B0.9610.9630.962(0.003)(0.003)(0.004)InitialwealthB0-0.072-0.090-0.120(0.142)(0.138)(0.155)Latelifeinc.B10.0700.0790.080(0.074)(0.068)(0.072)ShareAfA0.5570.5570.557(0.001)(0.002)(0.002)Inc.mult.AA1.1611.1931.206(0.025)(0.027)(0.027)WeightsOptimalEqualOptimalEndogenouspaymentsYesYesNo Notes:Standarderrorsinparentheses.Equalweightsareoptimalwithineachofthelife-cycledebtandconsumptionmoments,butequalweightforeachsetofmoments.Optimalweightsaretheinverseofthevarianceofeachindividualmoment.Forabriefdescriptionofeachmomentandtheestimationmethodseethebeginningofsection5.47 AppendixForOnlinePublicationAChangesincreditutilization:non-parametricevidenceFigureA-7showsconditionalmeanscatterplotsofcreditutilizationinonequarteragainstcreditutilizationinthenextquarter,inthenextyear,andintwoyears.Thetoprowshowsthemeaninthefuture,conditionalonlyonhavingtheutilizationshownonthex-axisinthatquarter.Thebottomrowinsteadtakesthewithintransformationandallowsforageandyear

53 effects.Itthereforeshowshowfarfromtheind
effects.Itthereforeshowshowfarfromtheindividual'saveragecreditutilizationsheisinthenextquarter,conditionalondifferingfromheraverageutilizationbytheamountonthex-axisthisquarter.Inotherwords,ifanindividualis10percentagepointsabovehertypicalutilizationinonequarter,howfarwillshebeonaverageinthenextquarter,nextyear,andintwoyears?Eachdotcontainsanequalportionofthesample.FigureA-7thuscapturestherelationshipbetweenutilizationtodayandinthefuturewithoutimposinganyparametricassumptions.Eachpanelalsoshowsthebesttlinefortheconditionalmeansandtheestimatedcoefcients.Thetoppanelsshowthatcreditutilizationishighlypersistentanddoesnottendtozeroonaverage.Creditutilizationthisquarteristypicallyveryclosetocreditutilizationnextquarter,sincetheconditionalmeansaretypicallyveryclosetothe45-degreeline.Forexample,onaverageifapersonisusing40percentofhercreditthisquarter,shewillbeusingabout40percentofhercreditnextquarter.Lookingclosely,however,averagecreditutilizationishighernextquarterforthoseusinglessthan20percentoftheircredit,andlowerforthoseusingmorethan80percentoftheircredit.Thebesttlinethroughtheconditionalmeanssuggeststhatcreditutilizationisnottrendingtozero.Instead,thelong-termsteady-stateutilizationis0.39.16Thesameconclusionisevidentfromtheconditionalchangescomparingutilizationthisquartertoayearfromnowandto 16Sincetheconditionalexpectationofutilizationnextquartergiventhisquarterisut+1=0:041+0:896utthesteady-stateutilizationis0.39=0.041/(1-0.896).A-1 twoyearsfromnow.Thoseconsumersusinglessthanapproximately40percentoftheiravailablecreditthisquarterareusingmoreoftheircreditinoneyearandintwoyears,thoseusingmorethan40percentoftheircreditareus

54 inglessoftheircreditonaveragewithinoneye
inglessoftheircreditonaveragewithinoneyearandtwoyears.Thesteady-statecreditutilizationisaround40percent(evidentbyndingwheretheconditionalexpectationfunctioncrossesthe45degreeline),althoughthemovementtowardthesteadystateisfairlyslow.Onaverageindividualsdonottrendtozeroutilization,nortousingalloftheircredit.Con-ditionalonusingzerocreditthisquarter,creditutilizationisnearly5percentwithinonequarterandnearly8percentinayear.Ontheotherhand,theaveragepersonusingallofhercreditinonequarterisusinglessthan90percentofitinayear.ThesecondrowofgureA-7allowsindividualstoreturntotheirownmeanandaddssub-stantialnuance.Thereasoncreditutilizationissopersistentinthetoprowisthatitappearsthatindividualshavetheirownmeantowhichtheyactuallyreturnquiterapidly.Thespeedofthereturnisevidentfromtheslopesofthelines.Onlytwo-thirdsofashocktoutilizationremainsafteronequarterand13percentremainsaftertwoyears.Evenifindividualsreturnveryrapidlytotheirownmeans,itisimportanttonotethatthosemeansarenotzero.CreditutilizationispersistentinthetoprowofgureA-7becauseindividualsaretypicallyquiteclosetotheirownmeancreditutilization.Sincecreditutilizationistheratioofdebtandcredit,thestabilityofcreditutilizationimpliesthatanindividualwithanincreaseincredithasincreasedherdebtsby33percentoftheincreaseincreditwithinonequarter,and87percentoftheincreaseincreditintwoyears.BBequestsInourbaseestimation,wegiveconsumerswhodiewithpositiveresourcessomeextrautilityfrombequests.Wehavealsoexaminedtheconsequencesofallowingconsumerstoplacenovalueonbequests.Sinceourestimationusesdebtandconsumptionmoments,bequestsarenotanimportantA-2 factorintheestimationsincethemedianpersonisleavingveryl

55 ittleinbequests.Wehavefoundthatanyreason
ittleinbequests.Wehavefoundthatanyreasonableapproachtointroducebequestsmakesonlyaveryminordifferenceinourestimates.Thisappendixoutlinesoneexibleapproach,anddiscusseshowtheparameterestimateschangewhennotincludingbequests.Thedifcultywithintroducingbequestsinamodelwithbothdebtandsavingsisthatwhilepositiveassetslefttoheirsmayprovideutility,unsecureddebtsarenotpassedon.Sinceitispossibletodiewithnegativeassets,zerobequestsarepossible.Simplyincludingbequestsinthesub-utilityfunctionwillthereforeproducenegativeinnitevaluefromleavingnobequest,whichconsumerswillcounterfactuallyacttoavoidbyneverbeingindebt.Instead,wemodelthebequestmotiveastheconsumerconsideringthemarginalutilityabequesttoherheirswillbringthemontopoftheirownincomes.TheconsumerdieswithcertaintyatageT,andwithsomeprobabilitybeforethat.Tovaluebequestsreasonably,wetakepositiveassetsasprovidinganannuityvalueontopofsomebaseincomethatheirsalreadygetthatisafunctionoftheconsumer'spermanentincome,andthebequestvalueasthepresentvalueoveralifetimeoftheseadditionalassets.Thevalueofbequestsisthen:S(At)=0@~TXs=0 s(Pt+rB(1�IRt+1)At)1� 1� 1A;wheretheconsumeronlyleavesabequestifshehaspositiveassetsattheendoftheperiod(IRt+1is0ifAt0).Theparameterdeterminesthemarginalutilityofbequestsandcanbethoughtofashowmuchmoreorlessincomechildrenhavethanparents.Thisstructureisimportantsincepeoplecandecidetodieindebt,andsoleavenothing.Ifchildrenaremuchbetteroffthenparents,thenthemarginalutilityofleavingabequestislow,andparentswillgenerallyonlyleavealargebequestaccidentally.Inourbaselineestimationwithbequests,weset=2whichimpliesthatattheaverageageofdeathchildren

56 areearningtwiceasmuchastheirelderlyparen
areearningtwiceasmuchastheirelderlyparents,butwehavealsoestimated,andfoundthatwhilevaluesaround2arereasonable,isverypoorlyidentiedgiventhemomentsweuse.Evenverylateinlife,A-3 thelikelihoodofdeathinthenextyearisfairlylow,andsotheexactformofthebequestmotive,includingremovingit,doesnotaffectdecisionsmeaningfullyformostofthedistribution.Thereasontousenitechildren'slifetimeistoallowforpossiblyverypatientparentswith closetoorgreaterthan1.CIdenticationofthepaymentsmodelThissectionshowshowtoidentifythepaymentmodelparametersandstandarderrorsfromob-servablemoments.Itthencalculatestheconsumersurplusanditsstandarderrors.Weobserve:R=1 NNXi=1i;tjIRi;t�1=1theaverageexpendituresbyrevolversonacreditcard,andsimilarlyCtheaverageforconve-nienceusers.DenoteourestimatesofthestandarderrorsofthesemeansasRandC.ThentheinterceptfortheaverageconvenienceuserisjustC=0=1andforarevolveritisR=(0�rB=24)=1whererBistheAPRinterestchargedonpayments,whichhaveanaveragedailybalanceofhalfofthemonthsconsumption.Solvingfor0and1gives:1=rB=24 C�Rand0=C1=(rB=24)C C�RA-4 .Thepresenceofadifferenceoftworandomvariableswhosesupportsmayoverlapinthede-nominatorofthetransformedvariablesmakescalculatingtheirvariancespotentiallytricky.SinceC�Rismaybecloseto0,then1and0maybeverylarge,whichisadifferentwayofsayingthatthemodelisnotidentiedifthereisnotadifferenceintheaveragebehaviorofconvenienceusersandrevolvers.Wecalculatethestandarderrorsofthetransformedvariablesusingthedeltamethod,whichavoidsthisissuebyexaminingo

57 nlysmallchangesaroundtheoptimum,andsodoe
nlysmallchangesaroundtheoptimum,andsodoesnotconsiderthehighlynon-linearincreasearoundC�R=0.ForsmallchangesCandRaroundCandR:1(rB=24)1 C�R�C�R (C�R)2:SinceRandCareindependent,thevarianceof1isapproximately:Var[1]rB=24 (C�R)22(2C+2R):Takingthesameexpansionfor0includingthecovarianceofthenumeratoranddenominator:Var[0]CrB=24 (C�R)22 2C+R C22R!:Finally,thetotaladditionalconveniencevalueofusingacreditcardoverthealternativesforaconvenienceuserisjusttheareaunderthecurve:C=(C;IRi;t�1=0)=(C0)=2=(rB=48)(C)2 C�Randforarevolversis:R=(R;IRi;t�1=1)=R 2(rB=24)C C�R�rB 24:A-5 TakinganexpansionaroundCandRyields:Var[C]rB 482 2C C�R�C C�R2!22C+C C�R22RandVar[R]rB 482C C�R�CR (C�R)222C+C C�R�CR (C�R)2�122R:A-6 FigureA-1:Fractionofconvenienceusersofcreditcards,conditionalonuse Notes:Eachdotshowsthefractioninthatveyearagegroup(labeledbytheyoungestmember)whodidnotrevolvecreditcarddebtfrommonthtomonth,`conditionalonusingtheircreditcard.95percentcondenceintervalsinbars.Source:Authors'calculationsfromthe2008–2014SurveysofConsumerPaymentChoice.FigureA-2:Consumptionfunctions

58 overthelife-cyclewithborrowing Notes:Sho
overthelife-cyclewithborrowing Notes:Showstheconsumptionfunctionforaconsumeratdifferentpointsofthelife-cycle.Atwtheconsumernolongerconsumesallcash-at-hand(whichincludesallavailablecredit).AtwBtheconsumernolongerborrows,butdoesnotsaveanythingbetweenwBandwFsincetheinterestrateforborrowingishigherthantherateforsaving.AfterwF;theconsumersaves(atthelowerrateofreturn).TheparameterstoproducethesefunctionsareasavingsrateofreturnR=1:03andborrowingrateRB=1:14,acoefcientofrelativeriskaversionof =2,adiscountparameter =0:9andotherparametersandretirementfunctionsmatchingGourinchasandParker(2002).A-7 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7Fraction Non-Revolving 20 30 40 50 60 70Age Group Cash-at-hand w t 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 Consumption c t 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 A g ! 6 A g 3 $ A g 4 $ A g $ $ A g 6 $ (w * , c * ) (w B , c B ) (w F , c F ) FigureA-3:Creditcardadoptionanduseforpaymentsbyageandyear(A)Creditcardadoptionrate (B)Shareofpaymentsusingcreditcards Source:Authors'calculationsfromthe2013SurveyofConsumerPaymentChoice.A-8 FigureA-4:Creditcardlimit,debt,andcreditutilizationdistributionsbyage(A)CreditCardLimits (B)CreditCardDebt (C)Creditutilization Notes:Eachlineisthepercentileofcreditlimitatthatage,conditionalonhavingapositivecreditlimitonalogscale.Forexample,the90thpercentilelineshowsthat10percentofthepopulation(withapositivecreditlimit)havealimitlargerthanthatline.Source:Authors'calculationsfromEquifax/NYFedCCP.A-9 .1 .2 .5 1 5 10 20 50 100credit limit by pctiles '000s (1, 10, 25, 50, 75, 90, 99) 20 40 60 80Age .2 .5 1 5 10 20 50 100 redit limit ptiles 000s 20 40 60 80Age Figure8:Percentilesoflogcreditcardlimitbycohort(1920,1930,1940,1950,

59 1960,1970,1980). Figure9:Percentilesoflo
1960,1970,1980). Figure9:Percentilesoflogcreditlimitbyage .8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6standard deviation of log credit card limit (if positive) 20 40 60 80Age .1 .2 .5 1 5 10 20 50 100 redit debt ptiles, 000s 20 40 60 80Age Figure10:Percentilesoflogcreditdebtbyage 1 1.5 2 2.5standard deviation of log credit card debt (if positive) 20 40 60 80Age 0 .5 1 1.5 redit utilization percentiles 20 40 60 80Age .1 .2 .3 .4 .5standard deviation of credit card utilization 20 40 60 80Age FigureA-5:Creditcardlimits,debt,andutilization:ageandyeareffectsCreditcardlimits` Creditcarddebt Creditcardutilization Notes:Eachlineshowstheestimatedageoryeareffectsfromequation(1).Notethedifferentscales.Source:Authors'calculationsfromEquifax/NYFedCCP.A-10 0 .5 1 1.5 2 2.5Estimated effect 20 40 60 80Age -.1 0 .1 .2 .3Estimated effect 2000 2005 2010 2015Year 0 .5 1 1.5 2Estimated effect 20 40 60 80Age -.05 0 .05 .1 .15 .2Estimated effect 2000 2005 2010 2015Year -.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0Estimated effect 20 40 60 80Age -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2Estimated effect 2000 2005 2010 2015Year FigureA-6:FractionwithpositivecreditcardlimitanddebtbycohortandageFractionwithpositivelimitFractionwithpositivedebt Notes:Eachlinerepresentsthefractionwithpositivecreditcardlimitsordebtofonebirthcohort,1999–2014.Source:Authors'calculationsfromEquifax/NYFedCCP. A-11 .2 .4 .6 .8 1Have positive credit card limit 20 40 60 80Age .2 .4 .6 .8Have positive credit card debt 20 40 60 80Age FigureA-7:Changesincreditutilizationinonequarter,oneyear,andtwoyears Notes:Eachpointinthetoprowshowsthemeancreditutilizationinthefutureconditionalonbeinginthebinwithameancreditutilizationonx-axistoday.Thebottomrowshowstheconditi

60 onalrelationshipbetweendeviationsfromthe
onalrelationshipbetweendeviationsfromtheindividualmeanutilizationovertheentiresample,adjustingforageandyear.Source:Authors'calculationsfromEquifax/NYFedCCPusingtheprogrambinscatter(Stepner,2013). A-12 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9 1 1.1Credit utilization inone quarter 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9 1 1.1Credit utilization today E[y|x] = 0.041 + 0.896x 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9 1 1.1Credit utilization inone year 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9 1 1.1Credit utilization today E[y|x] = 0.077 + 0.786x 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9 1 1.1Credit utilization intwo years 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9 1 1.1Credit utilization today E[y|x] = 0.100 + 0.698x -.5 -.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5Difference in credit utilization inone quarter -.5 -.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5Difference in credit utilizationfrom own meanE[y|x] = 0.666x -.5 -.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5Difference in credit utilization inone year -.5 -.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5Difference in credit utilizationfrom own meanE[y|x] = 0.339x -.5 -.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5Difference in credit utilization intwo years -.5 -.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5Difference in credit utilizationfrom own meanE[y|x] = 0.128x FigureA-8:Consumptionandincomeoverthelife-cyclefromtheConsumerExpenditureSurvey Notes:ShowstheaverageconsumptionandincomeateachagefromtheConsumerExpenditureSurvey,poolingallsurveysfrom2000-2014.Consumptionisthetotalhouseholdexpendituresdividedbythenumberofadults.Adjustedconsumptionremovestheestimatedeffectofchildren.Incomeisafter-taxincome,anditssmoothedversionisbasedonaquinticfromage24to81.SincetheCEXpoolsincomeandconsumptionafterage81(or83inlateryears),ages81onth

Related Contents


Next Show more