/
Working Paper/Document de travail2013Which Parametric Model for Condit Working Paper/Document de travail2013Which Parametric Model for Condit

Working Paper/Document de travail2013Which Parametric Model for Condit - PDF document

giovanna-bartolotta
giovanna-bartolotta . @giovanna-bartolotta
Follow
411 views
Uploaded On 2016-08-02

Working Paper/Document de travail2013Which Parametric Model for Condit - PPT Presentation

2 Bank of Canada WorkingPaperSeptemberWhich Parametric Model for ConditionalSkewnessBruno FeunouMohammad R JahanParvarand Rom ID: 430216

2 Bank Canada WorkingPaperSeptemberWhich Parametric

Share:

Link:

Embed:

Download Presentation from below link

Download Pdf The PPT/PDF document "Working Paper/Document de travail2013Whi..." is the property of its rightful owner. Permission is granted to download and print the materials on this web site for personal, non-commercial use only, and to display it on your personal computer provided you do not modify the materials and that you retain all copyright notices contained in the materials. By downloading content from our website, you accept the terms of this agreement.


Presentation Transcript

Working Paper/Document de travail2013Which Parametric Model for ConditionalSkewness?by Bruno Feunou, Mohammad R. JahanParvar and Roméo Tédongap 2 Bank of Canada WorkingPaperSeptemberWhich Parametric Model for ConditionalSkewnessBruno Feunou,Mohammad R. JahanParvarand Roméo TédongapFinancial Markets DepartmentBank of CanadaOttawa, Ontario, Canada K1A 0G9feun@bankofcanada.caOffice of Financial Stability Policy and ResearchFederal Reserve Board of Governorsshington, DC 20551Corresponding author: Mohammad.JahanParvar@frb.govDepartment of FinanceStockholm School of EconomicsStockholm, SwedenRomeo.Tedongap@hhs.se Bank of Canada wor king papers are theoretical or empirical works - in - progress on subjects in economics and finance. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors.No responsibility for them should be attributed to the Federal Reserve Board of Governors or the ank of Canada. ISSN © 2013Bank of Canada ii AcknowledgementsWe thank two anonymous referees, Chris Adcock (the editor), Torben Andersen, Bruce Hansen, Stanislav Khrapov, Nicola Loperfido, Dilip K. Patro, Akhtar Siddique, Scott Hendry, Glen Keenleyside, seminar participants at Joint Statistical Meetings 2011, Midwest Econometric Group meeting 2011, the Bank of Canada, Wayne State University (mathematics department), OCC, and the MAF 2012 conference for many useful comments. The remaining errors are ours. An earlier version of this paper has been circulated and presented at various seminars and conferences under the title “Regime Switchingin the Conditional Skewness of S&P500 Returns.” iii AbstractThis paper addresses an existing gap in the developing literature on conditional skewness. We develop a simple procedure to evaluate parametric conditional skewness models. This procedure is based on regressing the realized skewness measures on modelimplied conditional skewness values. We find that an asymmetric GARCHtype specification on shape parameters with a skewed generalized error distribution provides the best insample fit for the data, aswell as reasonable predictions of the realized skewness measure. Our empirical findings imply significant asymmetry with respect to positive and negative news in both conditional asymmetry and kurtosis processes.JEL classification: C22, C51, G12, G15Bank classification: Econometric and statistical methodsRésuméLes auteurs élaborent une procédure d’évaluation simple des modèles paramétriques d’asymétrie conditionnelle en vue de combler une lacune de la littérature sur le sujetCette procdure est baséesur la régression de l’asymétrie réalisée sur l’asymétrie conditionnelle. Les auteurs constatent qu’une spécification de type GARCHasymétrique pour les paramètres de forme, couplée à une distribution d’erreurs généralisée asymétrique, offre le meilleur ajustement statistique en échantillonainsi qu’une prévisibilité satisfaisante de la mesure de l’asymétrie réaliséeIls notent une importante asymétrie dans l’effet des bonnes et des mauvaises nouvelles sur le plan tant de la dynamique de l’asymétrie conditionnelle que de celle de l’aplatissement conditionnelClassification JEL : C22, C51, G12, G15Classification de la Banque :Méthodes économétriques et statistiques 1IntroductionTraditionalmodellingof nancialtimeseriescriticallyreliesontheassumptionofconditionalnormalityofreturns.Thisassumptionimpliesthatconditionalskewnessandexcesskurtosisshouldbeequaltozero.However,empiricalevidenceisinsharpcontrasttothisassertion.Unconditionally,thesemomentsprovenottobezero.Moreover,similartothe rsttwoconditionalmoments,highermomentsdemonstrateconsiderabletimevariationasnotedbyBekaertetal.(1998)andGhyselsetal.(2011).Thus,explicitmodellingofconditionalhighermomentsthatallowsfortimevariation,isnecessarytoavoidmodelmisspeci cation.SincethepioneeringworkofHansen(1994),anumberofresearchershaveproposedparametricmodelsforconditionalskewness.Examplesofstudiesontheeconomicimportanceofconditionalskew-nessin nancialassetreturns,itseconometricmodellinganditsempiricalapplicationsincludeHarveyandSiddique(1999,2000),Chenetal.(2001),BrannasandNordman(2003),JondeauandRockinger(2003),Patton(2004),Leonetal.(2005),LanneandSaikkonen(2007),GrigolettoandLisi(2009),Wilhelmsson(2009),Ghyselsetal.(2011),DurhamandPark(2013),Conradetal.(2013),andFeunouetal.(2013).Thereexistanumberofstudiesthatfocusonconditionalkurtosis,amongthemBrooksetal.(2005)andGuidolinandTimmermann(2008).Inthispaperwefocusonconditionalskewness,orconditionalasymmetry.Theexistingresearchdoesnottelluswhichparametricconditionalskewnessmodelprovidesabetter tforthedata.AsnotedbyKimandWhite(2004),thisispartiallyduetotheextremesensitivityoftraditionalskewnessandkurtosismeasurestooutliers.1Theyproposeseveralrobustmeasuresforskewnessandkurtosis.Inpreviouswork(Feunouetal.2013),wefoundthatconditionalasymmetryinreturnsisrelatedtothe\relativesemi-variance,"de nedastheupsidevarianceminusthedownsidevariance.2Weshowedthatmodellingdownsideriskispossiblewhenameasureofskewnessisexplicitlyincorporatedinthemodel.WeusedPearson's(1895)\modeskewness"asthemeasureofchoice.Pearson'smodeskewnessismorerobusttooutliersthantraditionalskewnessmeasures.BuildinguponandexpandingonsuggestionsinKimandWhite(2004)andFeunouetal.(2013),thispaper llstheexistinggapintheliteratureregardingmodeladequacyforparametricconditionalskewnessmodels.Ourobjectiveisthreefold.First,weestablishthroughapropositionthattherelativesemi-variance, 1Bytraditional,wemeanstandardizedthirdandfourthmomentsofarandomvariable.2Wede nethe\upsidevariance"asthevarianceofthereturnsconditionalupontheirrealizationaboveacertainthreshold.Theirvarianceconditionalupontheirrealizationbelowthesamethresholdiscalled\downsidevariance."Basedonthesetwode nitions,wede nethedi erencebetweenupsidevarianceanddownsidevarianceasthe\relativesemi-variance."1 dividedbythetotalvariance,isameasureofskewnessthatsatis esthepropertiesproposedbyGroen-eveldandMeeden(1984)foranyreasonableskewnessmeasure.Second,wedevelopanintuitiveandeasy-to-implementmethodfornon-parametricmeasurementofrealizedasymmetry.Third,basedonthismeasureofrealizedasymmetry,wecantestanyparametricmodelforconditionalskewnessandprovideamethodofhowtomodeltheconditionalskewness.Wetestanumberofparametricmodelsofconditionalasymmetrywithvariousfunctionalanddistributionalassumptions.ThetestingprocedureisbasedonMincerandZarnowitz(1969)regressionsandissimilarinspirittothemethodologydevel-opedbyChernov(2007)toclosetherealized-impliedvolatilitypredictiveregressiongap.We ndthatinadditiontoallowingtimevariationintheconditionalasymmetry,weneedtoallowfora\leveragee ect,"butalsoforasymmetry-in-asymmetrytoobtainthebestcharacterizationoftheconditionalskewnessdynamics.3ThemostsuccessfulcharacterizationoftheconditionalasymmetrysharesseveralfunctionalfeatureswiththecelebratedexponentialGARCH(EGARCH)modelofNelson(1991).Ghyselsetal.(2011)proposeamethodologyformodellingandestimatingtheconditionalskewnessbasedonamixeddatasampling(MIDAS)methodofvolatilityestimationintroducedandextensivelystudiedbyGhyselsetal.(2005,2006,2007),andBowley's(1920)measureofskewness.Ourworkdi ersfromGhyselsetal.intwoimportantdimensions.First,weareinterestedinassessingtheadequacyofdi erentmodelsofconditionalasymmetry,whileGhyselsetal.focusonasinglemodel.Second,Ghyselsetal.buildtheirmodelofconditionalasymmetrybasedonBowley's(1920)robustcoecientofskewness.Thismeasureisconstructedusingtheinter-quantilerangesoftheseriesinvestigated,whileourmeasureisbasedonthedi erencebetweenupsideanddownsidesemi-variances.DurhamandPark(2013)studythecontributionofconditionalskewnessinacontinuous-timeframe-work.Fortractability,theyassumesimpledynamicsbasedonasingleLevyprocessfortheconditionalskewnessintheirestimatedmodels.Wemodeltheconditionalasymmetryindiscretetimeandassumemuchricherdynamics.DurhamandParkestablishthecostofignoringconditionalhighermomentsinmodellingreturnsdynamics.Thus,theirsimplemodelisadequatetomotivatetheirwork.Theeconomicrelevanceofconditionalasymmetryhasbeenestablishedinseveralassetpricingstudies.AspointedoutbyChristo ersenetal.(2006),conditionallynon-symmetricreturninnovationsarecriticallyimportant,sinceinoptionpricing,forexample,heteroskedasticityandtheleveragee ectalonedonotsucetoexplaintheoptionsmirk.Inthisstudy,wetryto ndthemodelthatbestcharacterizesthedynamicsoftheconditionalasymmetryinS&P500returnsinarichsetofmodels.JondeauandRockinger(2003)characterizethemaximalrangeofskewnessandkurtosisforwhich 3We ndthattheevidenceforasymmetry-in-asymmetryitselfisrelativelyweak.Butthe exibilityo eredbyseparatingthecontributionsofpositiveandnegativeshocksimprovesthemodel'sperformancesigni cantly.2 adensityexists.TheyclaimthatthegeneralizedStudent-tdistributionspansalargedomaininthismaximalset,andusethisdistributiontomodelinnovationsofaGARCH-typemodelwithconditionalparameters.They ndtimedependencyoftheasymmetryparameter,butaconstantdegree-of-freedomparameterintheseriestheystudy.Theyprovideevidencethatskewnessisstronglypersistent,butkurtosisismuchlessso.Whilein uencedbyJondeauandRockinger(2003),ourstudydi ersfromtheirworkintwoimportantdimensions.First,westudyalargernumberofmodelsanddistributionsthanJondeauandRockinger(2003),andwethereforeconsiderourstudytobemorecomprehensive.Second,sincewecomparenon-nestedmodels,werelyonMincerandZarnowitz's(1969)methodologytoinvestigatetheadequacyofmodels.Therestofthepaperproceedsasfollows.Insection2,weprovidethetheoreticalbackgroundforourstudy.Wediscusstheimplicationsofvariousdistributionalassumptionsinsection3.Section4describesthedi erentparametricmodelspeci cationsfortheconditionalskewnessthatwetestinourempiricalanalysis.Wereportourempirical ndingsinsection5.Section6concludes.2TheoreticalBackgroundConventionalasymptotictheoryineconometricstypicallyleadstolimitingdistributionsforeconomicvariablesthatareconditionallyGaussianassamplesizeincreases.ExamplesofsuchworkincludeBollerslevetal.(1994)andDavidson(1994).Thus,conditionalskewnessshouldconvergetozeroassamplesizeincreases.However,asGhyselsetal.(2011),Brooksetal.(2005),andJondeauandRockinger(2003)show,conditionalskewnessformany nancialtimeseriesdoesnotvanishinlargesamplesorthroughsamplingathigherfrequencies.Inwhatfollows,weextendtheir ndingsanddevelopatestingframeworktocomparedi erentparametricmodelsofconditionalskewness.Ingeneral,commonparametricdistributionsconsideredinempiricalworktocharacterizethedis-tributionoflogarithmicreturnsareunimodalandsatisfythefollowingconditions:Var[rjrm]�Var[rjrm],Skew[r]&#x-278;0Var[rjrm]=Var[rjrm],Skew[r]=0Var[rjrm]Var[rjrm],Skew[r]0;(1)wheremisasuitablychosenthreshold.Afewstudiesintheliteratureusedistributionsthatexplicitlyallowforskewnessinreturns;inparticular,theskewedgeneralizedStudent-tdistributionpopularizedbyHansen(1994),theskewedgeneralizederrordistributionofNelson(1991),andthebinormaldistributionappliedto nancialdatainourpreviouswork(Feunouetal.2013)allsatisfyequation(1).Weintroduceanewmeasureofasymmetry,calledtherelativesemi-variance(RSV),de nedbythedi erencebetween3 theupsidevarianceandthedownsidevariance,whereupsideanddownsidearerelativetoacut-o pointequaltothemode.Proposition2.1Lettherandomvariablexfollowaunimodaldistributionwithmodem.Denotetheupsidevarianceas2u=Var[xjxm]andthedownsidevarianceas2d=Var[xjxm].Westandardizetherelativesemi-varianceRSV2u�2dbydividingitbythetotalvariancetoobtainascale-invariantanddimensionlessmeasureforskewnessde nedas (x)=2u�2d 2;(2)where2=Var[x]isthetotalvariance.Thedistributionisright-skewedif2u�2d,andleft-skewedif2u2d.Theproposedskewnessmeasureiscoherent;thatis,itsatis esthethreepropertiesproposedbyGroeneveldandMeeden(1984)thatanyreasonableskewnessmeasureshouldsatisfy.4Thesepropertiesare:(P1)foranya&#x-278;0andb, (x)= (ax+b);(P2)ifxissymmetricallydistributed,then (x)=0;(P3) (�x)=� (x).Proof:Notethat,foranya&#x-278;0andb,themodeofax+bisequaltoam+b.Besidesthetotalvariance,theupsidevarianceandthedownsidevarianceofax+baregivenbyVar[ax+b]=Var[ax]=a2Var[x]=a22;Var[ax+bjax+bam+b]=Var[ax+bjxm]=Var[axjxm]=a2Var[xjxm]=a22uVar[ax+bjax+bam+b]=Var[ax+bjxm]=Var[axjzm]=a2Var[xjxm]=a22d:Thus,theskewnessofax+bisgivenby (ax+b)=Var[ax+bjax+bam+b]�Var[ax+bjax+bam+b] Var[ax+b]=a22u�a22d a22=2u�2d 2= (x):The (x)skewnessmeasurethussatis es(P1).5Todemonstratethat (x)satis esthesecondproperty,supposethatxissymmetricandunimodal;thenweknowthatthemodeisequaltothemean.Asaresult,x�missymmetricandunimodalwithmeanzero.Consequently,x�manditsopposite,m�x,havethesamedistribution.Theupsidevarianceofx�misequalto2uandthedownsidevarianceofx�misequalto2d.However,2d=Var[x�mjx�m0]=Var[m�xjx�m0]=Var[m�xjm�x&#x]TJ/;ø 9;&#x.962; Tf;&#x 22.;1 ;� Td;&#x [00;0]: 4Suitabilityof (x)asaskewnessmeasurecriticallydependsonthemeasureofvolatilityusedinmodellingthereturnsprocess.Laterinthepaper,weshowthatourresultsarebasedontheEngleandNg(1993)NGARCHvolatilitymodel.Basedonempiricalresults,wearguethatNGARCHisaperfectlyadequatevolatilitymeasureand,thus,ourconditionalskewnessmeasuresarewellspeci ed.5Thisresultmeansthatrelativesemi-variance,2u�2d,satis es(P1)uptoamultiplicativeconstant.4 So,2disalsotheupsidevarianceofm�x.Sincex�mandm�xhavethesamedistribution,then2u=2dandinconsequence (x)=0.Thisshowsthatourmeasureofskewnesssatis es(P2).Todemonstratethat (x)satis es(P3),notethatthemodeof�xissimply�m.Theupsidevarianceof�xisthusthedownsidevarianceofx:Var[�xj�x�m]=Var[xj�x�m]=Var[xjxm]=2d:Similarly,wecanshowthatthedownsidevarianceof�xisequalto2u,theupsidevarianceofx.Ontheotherhand,�xandxhavethesametotalvariance2.Consequently,wehave (�x)=Var[�xj�x�m]�Var[�xj�x�m] Var[�x]=2d�2u 2=�2u�2d 2=� (x):Ourskewnessmeasurethussatis es(P3).2.1BuildingarealizedskewnessmeasureBasedonourdiscussioninsection2,wepositthatmodellingconditionalskewnessorasymmetryisequivalenttomodellingrelativesemi-variance,RSVt.Theliteratureonmodellingandmeasuringvolatilityin nanceandeconomicsisvast.Itsucestosaythat,foryearsnow,usingrealizedvari-ancefollowingthemethodologyofAndersenetal.(2001,2003)isthestandardmethodformeasuringvolatilityin nancialtimeseries.Asanexample,Chernov's(2007)studyontheadequacyofoption-impliedvolatilityinforecastingfuturevolatilitycruciallydependsonthismethodology.Wemodifythisstandardmethodologyintheliteraturetobuildanon-parametricanddistribution-freemeasureforconditionalasymmetryinreturns.Inarecentpaper,Neuberger(2012)discussesasomewhatsimilarmeasureofrealizedskewness.Weconstructourmeasuresfollowingthecommonpracticeintherealizedvarianceliteraturebysummingup nelysampledsquared-returnrealizationsovera xedtimeinterval,RVt=ntPj=1r2j;t;wheretherearenthigh-frequencyreturnsinperiodt,rj;tisthejthhigh-frequencyreturninperiodt.WethenconstructtherealizeddownsideandupsidevarianceseriesasRVdt=nt 2ndtntXj=1r2j;tI(rj;tmt)andRVut=nt 2nutntXj=1r2j;tI(rj;tmt);(3)wherendtandnutare,respectively,thenumberofhigh-frequencyreturnsbelowandabovetheconditionalmodeofreturnmtinperiodt,andwhereI()denotesanindicatorfunction.Thus,themeasureforrealizedrelativesemi-varianceissimplyde nedasRRSVt=RVut�RVdt;(4)5 which,dividedbyrealizedvariance,willde nerealizedskewnessaccordingtoourproposedmeasureforskewnessintroducedinProposition2.1.Realizedvolatilitywillrefertothesquarerootofrealizedvariance.Itisawell-knownfactthatEt[RVt+1]=2t,where2t=Vart[rt+1]istheconditionalvariance,andwherert=ntPj=1rj;tisthereturnofperiodt.Thisisawell-establishedresultbasedonCorollary1inAndersenetal.(2003).WeestablishthatEt[RRSVt+1]=2u;t�2d;t,andthefollowingpropositionanditsproofshowtheveracityofourassertion.Proposition2.2Lettheunidimensionalcontinuous-priceprocessfPtgTt=0,whereT�0,bede nedonacompleteprobabilityspace( ;F;P).LetfFgt2[0;T]Fbeaninformation ltration,de nedasafamilyofincreasingP-completeandright-continuous- elds.InformationsetFtincludesassetpricesandrelevantstatevariablesthroughtimet.LetRVut+1andRVdt+1bede nedasaboveforthispriceprocess.ThenEtRVut+1�RVdt+12u;t�2d;t:Proof:Seetheappendix.Thus,asimpletestingprocedureconsistsofregressingRVut+1�RVdt+1on2u;t�2d;t,orRVut+1�RVdt+1= 0+ 1�2u;t�2d;t+"t+1:(5)FollowingthestandardMincerandZarnowitz(1969)methodology,weviewthemodelwiththe 0closesttozero,the 1closesttooneandthehighestregressionR2asthebettermodelforconditionalskewness.6WehavefollowedBarndor -Nielsenetal.(2010)closelyinourtreatmentofsourcesofconditionalskewness.Thisimpliesthatintheproofoftheaboveproposition,andfollowingBarndor -Nielsenetal.(2010),wehaveshutdownthe\instantaneous"or\high-frequencyleveragee ect"toderivethedesiredresults.Inpractice,wehaveshownthatourrealizedrelativesemi-variancesharesmanyfeatureswiththerealizedsemi-variancesstudiedbyBarndor -Nielsenetal.(2010).Wehaveobserved,buthavenotstudiedthisissueindepth,thatindatasampledathighenoughfrequency,conditionalskewnessisdrivenpurelybyjumps.Thisisareasonableassumptionatfrequen-ciessuchas5-minute,15-minute,half-hour,hourly,orevendailysampleddata,sincetheinstantaneousleveragee ectisclearlyweakatsuchhighfrequencies.However,asthesamplingfrequencyisloweredto,forexample,monthlyorquarterlyperiods,thisassertionlosespower.Theleveragee ectisanimportantcontributortoconditionalskewnessinlowersamplingfrequencies. 6Inpractice,weputlessweightonthe rstcondition,with 0statisticallyindistinguishablefrom0.AsChernov(2007)documentsthisissueinaparallelliterature,pinningdownthecorrectfunctionalformofthestatisticalrelationshipbetweenlatentvariablesisdicult.Thus,wefocusonthemorerobustandtheoreticallymoreimportantrelationshipbetweenourskewnessmeasuresthroughslopeparameters.Thatsaid,wereportresultsforjointtestsfor 0=0; 1=1inourdiscussionofempirical ndings.6 Figure1showsthepathsfordailyrealizedrelativesemi-varianceandrealizedvarianceforS&P500returnsinthe1980{2010period.Bothseriesareconstructedusing15-minutereturns.Inordertoprovideamoretractablepictureofthebehaviorofrealizedrelativesemi-variance,wethinouttheplotanduseevery22nddatapointinthe gure.Westudythecorrelationbetweenrealizedrelativesemi-varianceandrealizedvarianceandvolatility.We ndthatthecorrelationbetweenrealizedvarianceandrelativesemi-varianceis-0.5076,thecorrelationbetweenrealizedvarianceandskewnessis-0.0206,thecorrelationbetweenrealizedvolatilityandrelativesemi-varianceis-0.4475,and nally,thecorrelationbetweenrealizedvolatilityandskewnessis-0.0538.Thus,RRSVandRVarenegativelycorrelated.Itisimmediatelyclearthatspikesinrealizedrelativesemi-variancetypicallyleadtosigni cantjumpsinrealizedvariance.Itisalsoclearthatthereisevidenceofclusteringvisibleinrelativesemi-variance,particularlyinthe rsthalfofthesamplingperiod.Therangeofrealizedrelativesemi-varianceiscomparabletothatreportedinourpreviouswork(Feunouetal.2013).3ModelSpeci cationfortheConditionalSkewnessInmodellingthe rsttwoconditionalmoments,itisnotnecessarytotakeastanceontheparametricdistributionofthereturns.Unlikethe rsttwoconditionalmomentswherenoassumptionontheparametricdistributionisrequired,modellinghighermomentsrequiresaspeci cationofaparametricdistribution.Two exiblefamiliesofdistributionsattractalotofattentionintheliterature.TheyaretheskewedgeneralizedStudent-t(GST)andtheskewedgeneralizederrordistribution(SGED).Wealsostudythebinormaldistribution,whichwerecentlyintroducedtothe nanceliterature(Feunouetal.2013).Withoutlossofgenerality,westandardizethesedistributionsby xingtheirmeantobeequaltozero,andtheirvariancetobeequaltoone.Standardizedreturnsaredenotedbyz.3.1TheskewedgeneralizedStudent-tdistributionHansen(1994)popularizedtheskewedGSTdistribution.Itsdensityisde nedbyfGST(z)=8���&#x]TJ ;� -1;.93; Td;&#x [00;&#x]TJ ;� -1;.93; Td;&#x [00;&#x]TJ ;� -1;.93; Td;&#x [00;:bc1+1 �2bz+a 1�2�(+1)=2ifz�a=bbc1+1 �2bz+a 1+2�(+1)=2ifz�a=bwhereistheskewnessparameter,representsdegreesoffreedomanda4c�2 �1;b21+32�a2;c�((+1)=2) p (�2)�(=2):Thisdensityisde nedfor21and�11:GSTdensitynestsalargesetofconventionaldensities.Forexample,if=0,Hansen'sGSTdistributionreducestothetraditionalStudent-t7 distribution.WerecallthatthetraditionalStudent-tdistributionisnotskewed.Inaddition,if=1,theStudent-tdistributioncollapsestoanormaldensity.Sincecontrolsskewness,ifispositive,theprobabilitymassconcentratesintherighttail.Ifitisnegative,theprobabilitymassisinthelefttail.ItiswellknownthatthetraditionalStudent-tdistributionwithdegreesoffreedomadmitsallmomentsuptotheth.Therefore,giventherestriction�2,Hansen'sdistributioniswellde nedanditssecondmomentexists.Thethirdandfourthmomentsofthisdistributionarede nedasEz3=�m3�3am2+2a3=b3;Ez4=�m4�4am3+6a2m2�3a4=b4;withm2=1+32;m3=16c�1+2(�2)2 (�1)(�3)if�3;andm4=3�2 �4(1+102+54)if�4:Themodeofthedistributionis�a=b.Thus,therelativesemi-varianceisVar[zjz��a=b]�Var[zjz�a=b]=4 b2"1�4c2(�2)2 (�1)2#:(6)We ndthatusingrelativesemi-varianceasameasureofskewnessinthecontextofgeneralizedStudent-tdistributionadds exibilitytotheanalysis.NotethatforthethirdmomenttoexistforarandomvariablewithskewedGSTdistribution,mustbegreaterthan3.However,weneedonly�2forrelativesemi-variancetoexist,whichisthesameconditionfortheexistenceofthesecondmoment.Thus,itispossibletostudyasymmetryevenwhenthethirdmomentdoesnotexist.3.2TheskewedgeneralizederrordistributionTheprobabilitydensityfunctionfortheSGEDisfSGED(z)=Cexp�jz+j [1+sign(z+)]:Wede neC= 2�1 �1;=�1 1 2�3 �1 2S()�1;=2AS()�1;S()=p 1+32�4A22;andA=�2 �1 �1 2�3 �1 2,where�()isthegammafunction.Scalingparametersandaresubjectto�0and�11.Thisdensityfunctionnestsalargesetofconventionaldensities.Forexample,when=0;wehavethegeneralizederrordistribution,asinNelson(1991).When=0and=2;wehavethestandardnormaldistribution;when=0and=1;wehavethedoubleexponentialdistribution;andwhen=0and=1,wehavetheuniformdistributionontheinterval�p 3;p 3:Theparametercontrolstheheightandthetailsofthedensityfunction,andtheskewnessparametercontrolstherateofdescentofthedensityaroundthemode(�).Thethirdandthefourthmoment8 arede nedasEz3=A3�3�3;Ez4=A4�4A3+62+34;whereA3=4�1+2�(4=)�(1=)�13andA4=�1+102+54�(5=)�(1=)�14:Themodeofthisdistributionis�.Asaresult,we ndthattherelativesemi-varianceisVar[zjz��]�Var[zjz�]=4�1�A2 S()2:(7)3.3ThebinormaldistributionThebinormaldistributionwasintroducedbyGibbonsandMylroie(1973).Itisananalyticallytractabledistributionthataccommodatesempiricallyplausiblevaluesofskewnessandkurtosis,andneststhefa-miliarnormaldistribution.7Inourpreviouswork(Feunouetal.2013),weshowedthataGARCHmodelbasedonthebinormaldistribution,whichwecallBiN-GARCH,isquitesuccessfulincharac-terizingtheelusiverisk-returntrade-o intheU.S.andinternationalindexreturns.OurBiN-GARCHmodelexplicitlylinksthemarketpriceofrisktoconditionalskewness.Theconditionaldensityfunctionofastandardizedbinormaldistribution(SBin),orbinormaldis-tributionwithzeromeanunitvariance,andPearsonmodeskewness,isgivenbyfSBin(z)=Aexp �1 2z+ d2!I(z�)+Aexp �1 2z+ u2!I(z�);whered=�p /8+p 1�(3/8�1)2andu=p /8+p 1�(3/8�1)2,andwhereA=p 2//(d+u).If=0,thend=u=1,andthisdistributioncollapsestothefamiliarstandardnormaldistribution.We ndthat�istheconditionalmode,anduptoamultiplicativeconstant,2dand2uareinterpretedasdownsidevarianceandupsidevariancewithrespecttothemode,respectively.Speci cally,Var[zjz�]=1�2 2dandVar[zjz�]=1�2 2u:(8)Weconsiderthispropertytobethemostimportantcharacteristicofthebinormaldistribution,givenourobjectives.Theexistenceandpositivityofthequantitiesdanduimposeaboundontheparameter,givenbyjj1.p /2�11:3236.Finally,itistrivialtoshowthattherelativesemi-variance 7SeeBangertetal.(1986),KimberandJeynes(1987),andTothandSzentimrey(1990),amongothers,forexamplesofusingthebinormaldistributionindatamodelling,statisticalanalysisandrobustnessstudies.9 forthestandardizedbinormaldistributionisVar[zjz�]�Var[zjz�]=p 21�2 p 1�(3/8�1)2:(9)3.4Theskewness-kurtosisboundaryLet3=E(z3t)and4=E(z4t)denotethenon-centeredthirdandfourthmomentsofarandomvariablefztg1t=0.Foranydistributiononztwith(�1;1)support,wehave234�1with4&#x-278;0(seeWidder1946,p.134,Theorem12.a;JondeauandRockinger2003).Thisrelationcon rmsthat,foragivenlevelofkurtosis,onlya niterangeofskewnessmaybespanned.Thisisknownastheskewness-kurtosisboundary,anditensurestheexistenceofadensity.Thus,therealchallengewhilemodellingthedistributionofztistogetcloseenoughtothisskewness-kurtosisboundary.Figure2showstheskewness-kurtosisboundaryforHansen'sskewedgeneralizedStudent-t,SGED,andbinormaldistributionsagainstthetheoreticalboundarydiscussedinWidder(1946)andJondeauandRockinger(2003).Itisclearfromthis gurethattheSGEDspansalargerareaofthetheoreticalskewness-kurtosisboundarythandoestheskewedgeneralizedStudent-tdistribution.Thus,weexpectmodelsbasedontheSGEDtooutperformmodelsbasedontheGSTdistribution.Thesharplimitonpermissibleskewnesslevelsinthebinormaldistributionseriouslylimitsitsabilitytospanthetheoreticalskewness-kurtosisboundary.Figures3and4demonstratethecontributionofskewnessandpeakednessparameters,and,re-spectively,togeneratingskewnessandkurtosisinskewedgeneralizedStudent-tdistributionandSGED,respectively.Notethatthepatternsfortheskewnesssurfaceinbothdistributionsareverysimilar.Thedi erenceliesinthepermissiblevaluesforandthelevelofskewnessgeneratedbycomparablecombinationsofskewnessandpeakednessparameters.Thatis,theskewedgeneralizedStudent-tseemstogeneratelargervaluesforskewnessincomparisonwithSGED.Thepatternofthekurtosissurface,however,isdi erentforthesedistributions.TheskewedgeneralizedStudent-tdistributionsdemonstrateamoreexplosivepatternaswemovetowardthecornersoftheadmissiblesetfor.ThebehaviorofthekurtosissurfaceforalladmissiblevaluesofismoresubduedforSGED.Bothdistributionsshowmildevidenceofasymmetryinkurtosisforlowervaluesof.4ModelSpeci cationInthissection,weintroducethefunctionalformsofthemodelsthatwe ttothedatafortestingpurposes.We rstdiscusshowwemakeourmodelscomparable.Wewanttoestimatetheparameters10 ofinterestwithoutimposingrestrictionsonourestimationprocedure;however,wealsowanttopreservethetheoreticalboundsimposedontheshapeparameters.Weusesign-preservingtransformations.Inparticular,followingHansen(1994)andNelson(1991),becauseofthedi erentrestrictionsontheshapeparameters,wemapthetransformedparameterstobeestimatedintothetrueparameters,usingalogisticmappingfortheskewnessandanexponentialmappingforthepeakedness.Thisstepallowsustoestimatethetransformedparameters~and~asfreevalues,andthenrecovertheoriginalparameters.ForthegeneralizedStudent-tdistribution,weusethemappings=�1+2 1+exp�~and=2+exp(~):(10)Thesetransformationsareintuitive.RecallthatskewedgeneralizedStudent-tdistributionrequiresthatjj1.Transformingfollowingequation(10)ensuresthattheseboundsarepreserved,regardlessoftheestimatedvalueof~.Similarly,GSTrequiresthat21.Equation(10)preservestheselimitsfor,regardlessoftheestimatedvalueof~.Fortheskewedgeneralizederrordistribution,wehave=�1+2 1+exp�~and=exp(~);(11)soastomaintaintherestrictionsjj1and&#x]TJ/;ø 9;&#x.962; Tf;&#x 10.;Ԗ ;� Td;&#x [00;0.Finally,forthestandardizedbinormaldistribution,wehave=1 p  2�124�1+2 1+exp�~35:(12)Notethatthebinormaldistributiondoesnothaveadistinctpeakednessparameter.Thetransformationinequation(12)istomaintaintheboundonPearsonmodeskewness,jj1.p /2�11:3236,forthebinormaldistributiondiscussedimmediatelyafterequation(8).Weestimateandcompareresultsfromuptoninespeci cationsforskewnessandpeakednessfactors,acrossthethreedistributionsdiscussedinsection3.Atotalof24models ttothedata.Inthemostbasicmodel,bothofthesefactorsareconstantparameterstobeestimated.Werelaxthisspeci cationandallowfortimevariationandfunctionalcomplexityintheseprocesses.Weassumethatthecondi-tionalvarianceprocessforreturnsfollowsanEngleandNg(1993)NGARCHspeci cation.Thus,theconditionalvarianceprocessfollows2t+1= 0+ 12t(zt+1�)2+ 22t:(13)Thischoiceoffunctionalformfortheconditionalvarianceallowsfora\leveragee ect"inreturns.Weassumethatreturnsfollowrt+1=+tzt+1,wherezt+1jItGST(t;t),zt+1jItSGED(t;t),11 orzt+1jItBiN(t),andwhereItdenotestheinformationsetuptotimet.8Themostbasicmodelthatwestudyassumesconstant~and~.WecallthismodelM0.WerelaxtheassumptionoftimeinvariancefortheskewnessprocessinModel1,butmaintainthatthepeakednessprocessisstillaparametertobeestimated.InmodelM1,weassumethattheskewnessprocessfollowsasymmetricARCH(1)process,~t+1=0+1zt+1:(14)Theassumptionofsymmetryheremeansthatthearrivalofgoodorbadnewsimpactstheskewnessprocesswiththesamemagnitude.Asymmetryinvolatilityisawell-documentedfeatureof nancialdata.Severalstudiesinthe(G)ARCHliteratureaddressthisissue,whichleadstotheleveragee ectin nancialdata.Amongthesestudies,wenoteNelson(1991),Glostenetal.(1993),andEngleandNg(1993).JondeauandRockinger(2003)arguethatasymmetryinARCHforskewnessandkurtosisrequiresinvestigation.Hence,westudythisissueinmodelM2,whereweassumeanAsym-ARCHstructureintheskewnessprocess,~,butassumeconstant~.Inthismodel,~follows~t+1=0+1;+zt+1I(zt+1�0)+1;�zt+1I(zt+10);(15)whereI()denotesanindicatorfunction.WeallowforthericherGARCH(1,1)dynamicsintheskewnessprocessinmodelM3.Inthismodel,westillassumeconstant~.~follows~t+1=0+1zt+1+2~t:(16)Thismodel,exceptfordistributionalassumptionsandnormalization,isthesamemodelstudiedbyHarveyandSiddique(1999).Tostudythepotentialexistenceofanasymmetry-in-asymmetryorleveragee ectintheconditionalskewness,weassumethattheskewnessprocessfollowsanasymmetricGARCHforminmodelM4.Inthismodel,~isstillassumedtobeconstant.Asym-GARCHin~impliesthefollowingfunctionalform:~t+1=0+1;+zt+1I(zt+1&#x]TJ/;ø 9;&#x.962; Tf;&#x 10.;Ԗ ;� Td;&#x [00;0)+1;�zt+1I(zt+10)+2~t:(17)Intheremainingfourmodels,werelaxtheassumptionofconstant~.InmodelM5,weassumea 8Tokeepournotationconsistentwiththerealizedvolatilityliterature,ourtimingconventiondi ersslightlyfromthefamiliarGARCHnotation.Throughoutthepaper,thesubscripttonanyvariablemeansthatitisobservedexactlyattimet.InthetraditionalGARCHnotation,thesubscripttintheconditionalvariancemeansthatitisthevarianceofthetimetreturns.Hence,thevarianceisobservedattimet�1.12 symmetricARCHstructureforboth~and~:~t+1=0+1zt+1;(18)~t+1= 0+ 1zt+1:InmodelM6,westudytheimpactofgoodandbadnewsonbothskewnessandpeakednessprocessesbyassuminganasymmetricARCHinboth~and~:~t+1=0+1;+zt+1I(zt+1�0)+1;�zt+1I(zt+10);(19)~t+1= 0+ 1;+zt+1I(zt+1&#x]TJ/;ø 9;&#x.962; Tf;&#x 10.;Ԗ ;� Td;&#x [00;0)+ 1;�zt+1I(zt+10):ModelM7investigatestheimplicationsofassumingaGARCHspeci cationforbothskewness,~,andpeakedness,~,processes:~t+1=0+1zt+1+2~t;(20)~t+1= 0+ 1zt+1+ 2~t:AswithM3,thisformulationisverysimilartothemodelinHarveyandSiddique(1999).Finally,westudytheimplicationsofassuminganasymmetricGARCHfunctionalformforboth~and~inmodelM8:~t+1=0+1;+zt+1I(zt+1&#x]TJ/;ø 9;&#x.962; Tf;&#x 10.;Ԗ ;� Td;&#x [00;0)+1;�zt+1I(zt+10)+2~t(21)~t+1= 0+ 1;+zt+1I(zt+1&#x]TJ/;ø 9;&#x.962; Tf;&#x 10.;Ԗ ;� Td;&#x [00;0)+ 1;�zt+1I(zt+10)+ 2~t:5EstimationResults5.1DataWeusedailyStandardandPoor's500(S&P500)indexexcessreturnsfromThomsonReutersDatas-tream.ThedataseriesstartsinJanuary1980andendsinSeptember2010.Table1reportssummarystatisticsofthedata.InPanelA,wereportannualizedreturnmeansandstandarddeviations,inpercentages,incolumnstwoandthree.Wereportunconditionalskewnessincol-umnfour.Weobservenegativeunconditionalskewnessformarketreturns.Thevalueofunconditionalskewnessisnotsmallrelativetotheaveragedailyreturns.Ourdataseemtobehighlyleptokurtotic,sincetheseriesdemonstratessigni cantunconditionalexcesskurtosis,asseenincolumn ve.There-portedp-valuesofJarqueandBera's(1980)normalitytestimplyasigni cantdeparturefromnormalityinthedata.Ourproxyfortherisk-freerateistheyieldofthe3-monthconstant-maturityU.S.Treasurybill,whichweobtainedfromtheFederalReserveBankofSt.LouisFREDIIdatabank.Thecrashof13 October1987,theAsiancrisisof1997,theRussiandefaultof1998andthe2007{09GreatRecessionarerepresentedinthedata.OurintradaydataseriescomesfromOlsenFinancialTechnologiesandistheirlongestavailableone-minutecloselevelS&P500indexpriceseries.ThedataspantheperiodfromFebruary1986toSeptember2010.Toreducethemarketmicrostructuree ectinourempiricalresults,weconstructintradayreturnsata15-minutefrequency.TheseresultsappearinPanelBofTable1.5.2DiscussionoftheresultsWereporttwosetsofresultsforeachdistribution.First,wereportestimationresultsforallmodelsstudiedforeachdistribution.WethenreporttheresultsfromrunningtheMincerandZarnowitz(1969)regressionsofrealizedskewnessmeasureonparametricskewnessresults.Wereportestimationresultsforthefullsample(1980{2009)andthreesubsamples,spanning1980{89,1990{99,and2000-09.Formodelselection,wemainlyrelyonempirical ndingsbasedonourfull-sampleestimates.Estimatedresultsbasedonsubsamplesaregenerallyfordemonstrationoftimevariationorrobustnessandplayasecondaryrole.Ineachcase,foreachdistributionandforeachsampleperiod,we rstidentifythemodelthatbestcharacterizesthereturns.Ourstrategytoidentifysuchamodelistocomputelikelihoodratio(LR)teststatistics.Amodelisconsideredviablewhen(i)theLRtestrejectsequalgoodnessof tbetweenabaselinenormallydistributedmodelandthemodelwithconditionalskewness,and(ii)theLRtestrejectsequalgoodnessof tbetweeneachmodelandthemodelprecedingit.9Thatis,wecontrolforoverparameterizationofmodelsbycomparingmodelssequentially.TheLRtestisnotapplicablefornon-nestedmodels.Insuchcases,wedonotcomputeLRteststatistics.IftheLRtestdoesnotdi erentiatebetweentwomodels' toritisinapplicable,thenwe rstlookattheBayesianinformationcriteria(BIC)ofmodels.Ifthisisstillnothelpful,wepreferthelessparameterizedmodeloverthemoreparameterizedmodelwiththesamegoodnessof tandsimilarBIC.Basedontheestimatedparametersofthepreferredparametricmodel,we lteroutthemodel-impliedrelativesemi-varianceprocess.Notethat,inourstudy,modelM8nestsallothermodels.Wethenregressrealizedrelativesemi-varianceontomodel-impliedrelativesemi-variance.Next,weturntomodelevaluation.Ourcriteriaforthesuccessofaparametricmodelofskewness(relativesemi-variance)here{indescendingorderofimportance{are:(i)aslopeparameterthatisstatistically 9Thismeansthat,inourtables,thereportedLRteststatisticsarecomputedbyusinglog-likelihoodvaluesfrommodelMxandmodelMx�1.Thatis,theLRstatisticformodelM2isbasedonlog-likelihoodvaluesformodelsM1andM2.Whennecessary,weindicatethatwehaveusedlog-likelihoodvaluesfromnon-sequentialbutnestedmodelstoconstructateststatistic.14 indistinguishablefromunityatreasonablecon dencelevels,(ii)thehighestpossibleR2giventhatthepreviousconditionismet,and nally(iii)whethertheslopeandinterceptcoecientsoftheMincer-Zarnowitzregressioninquestionarejointlyequaltooneandzero,respectively,giventhattheprevioustwoconditionsaremet.Thelastcriterionre ectsthedicultyofpinningdownthecorrectfunctionalformofalatentvariable,inourcaseconditionalskewness.Thus,weputlessweightoninterceptestimatesthatarestatisticallynotdi erentfromzero.Chernov(2007)documentsthisissueforrealizedandimpliedvolatilityliterature.Tables2and3reporttheestimationresultsformodelsinsection4fortheGSTdistribution.Notethatthebaselinemodel(representedasNinbothtables)isrejectedinfavorofallalternativemodelsentertainedinourstudy,basedonlikelihoodratioteststhatarenotreportedtosavespace.ModelsM0{M8deliverabetter tforthedata.Thus,the rstcriterionismet.FormodelM0,we ndthatestimatedpeakednessparametersarestatisticallydi erentfromzeroatthe5percentlevelacrossallsamplesstudied.However,theskewnessparameterisstatisticallysigni cantinthefullsampleandthe2000{09subsample.Weconcludethatthereisverystrongevidenceinfavoroftheexistenceofexcesskurtosisandconvincingevidencesupportingskewness,whichgetsstrongerasweusethe21st-centurydata.10ModelsM1{M4showasomewhatsimilarpattern.Whilethesizeoftheestimatedparametersmaydi eracrossthesemodelsandacrosssamples,theyareallsigni cantlydi erentfromzeroatthe5percentlevel.Estimatedautoregressiveparameters,whethersymmetricorasymmetric(1+or1�),andtheGARCH-likeparameter2aregenerallystatisticallydi erentfromzero.Inaddition,weobserveevidenceofasymmetry-in-asymmetryinourresults.Thatis,positivereturnsincreasetheskewness{or,inotherwords,pushtheskewnesstowardpositivevalues,andnegativereturnsdecreasetheskewness{orpushskewnesstowardnegativevalues.Thus,positiveandnegativenewshavedi erentandoppositeimpactsonskewness.Basedonthesizeoftheestimatedparameters,theimpactofpositivenewsislargerthanthatofnegativenews.ModelsM5toM8inTables2and3reporttheimpactoftimevariationontheconditionalkurtosis.Ingeneral,theGARCH-typeparameter 2andtheARCH-typeparameter 1;+arestatisticallysignif-icantatthe5percentlevel.Weobserveevidenceofanasymmetricimpactingoodandbadnewsforconditionalkurtosismodels.Theestimated 1;�parameterisstatisticallydi erentfromzerointhefullsample,butthisisnottrueingeneralforsubsampleresults.Inaddition,themagnitudeofestimated 1;+isgenerallylargerthanthatof 1;�parameters.Thus,itseemsthat,inthiscase,goodnewsis 10PleasenotethatinTables2,3,5,6,and8,weabusethenotationtosavespace.Thatis,1+and 1+representboththecoecientsfortheARCH-liketermsandthecoecientsforpositiveinnovationshocks.15 moreimportantthanbadnewsforconditionalkurtosisdynamics.Thelikelihoodteststatistics(henceforthLRstatistics)showthatthemodelsstudieddi eronhowwellthey tthedata.Overall,modelM8,whichallowsforasymmetricGARCH-typedynamicsforboth~tand~t,performsthebestbasedonLRtests.Thatis,basedonLRtestscarriedout,M8providesabetter tthanmodelsM0toM7inthefullsampleandthe1990{99and2000{09subsamplesforreturns.Table4reportstheresultsfromrunningtheMincer-Zarnowitzpredictiveregressionsintroducedinequation(5),wheretheright-hand-sidevariablesareimpliedskewnessmeasuresfromoneofthemodelsinequations(14)-(21)andtheleft-hand-sidevariableistherealizedskewnessmeasureintroducedinequation(4).TheRRSVmeasureisbasedonhigh-frequencyinformation,whileimpliedskewnessmea-suresarebasedondailydata.NotethatmodelM1providesthehighestR2infull-sampleestimation,buttheestimated 1issigni cantlydi erentfromunity.However,thebestmodelshouldbetheonewiththehighestR2amongallspeci cationswith 1notsigni cantlydi erentfromunity.OurresultssuggestthatmodelsM4andM8bothhave 1notstatisticallydi erentfromone,andthehighestR2of19percentinfull-sampleestimation.Boththesespeci cationshavetime-varyingconditionalskew-nessdynamicsfeaturingasymmetry-in-asymmetry,butM8nestsM4throughtheconditionalkurtosisdynamics.Forallmodels,thehypothesis 1=1isnotrejectedinthesecondsubsampleexceptforspeci cationsM0andM7,whilethejointhypothesis 0=0and 1=1isnotrejectedinthethirdsubsampleexceptforspeci cationsM0,M4andM6.OurpreferredmodelwouldthenbeM8basedonfull-sampleandsubsampleMincer-Zarnowitzpredictiveregressionresults,addedtothefactthatM8issigni cantlyfavoredoverM4giventheLRtestsreportedinTables2and3.Tables5and6reporttheestimationresultsformodelsM0{M8whenerrorsareSGED.SimilartowhatisseenintheresultsfortheGSTcase,modelsM0{M8performbetterthanthebaselinemodelNacrosstheboard.ModelsM0{M4demonstratestatisticallysigni cantpeakednessparameterestimatesacrossmodelsandsamples.Thestatisticalevidenceinfavorofasymmetry-in-asymmetryisquitestronginthefullsample.Statisticalevidencesupportingasymmetry-in-asymmetryismoremixedinthesubsamples.OurestimationresultsformodelsM5{M8implythat,again,evidenceinsupportofasymmetry-in-asymmetryintheconditionalskewnessisquitestrongforthefullsampleandinthesubsamples.Inaddition,thereissigni cantsupportforasymmetryintheconditionalkurtosis,wheregoodnewsreducesfat-tailedness.Thisisnotsurprising.Arrivalof\goodnews"shouldreducemarketuncertainty,andhenceconditionalkurtosis.BasedontheLRstatistics,againmodelM8isthepreferredmodelinthe16 fullsampleandacrossthesubsamples.Itappearsasifallowingforarich,asymmetricparameterizationaddstomodel exibilityandhenceitsperformance.ItisworthnotingthatmodelM8sharesmanyfeatureswiththecelebratedNelson(1991)EGARCHmodel.We ndthatinthe1990{99and2000{09subsamples,modelsM6andM8areindistinguishableusingLRtests.BasedonBIC,modelM6ispreferredtoM8inthesesubsamples.However,asmentionedearlier,webaseourjudgmentmainlyonfull-sampleresults,wheretheLRtestclearlypicksM8overM6andM7.Table7reportstheresultsforMincer-Zarnowitzpredictiveregressionswhereimpliedrelativesemi-varianceestimatesarebasedonmodelswithSGEDerrors.Inthefullsample,modelsM0{M2,M5andM8allhaveslopeparametersthatarestatisticallyindistinguishablefromone.Jointtestsofbothslopeandinterceptparametersbeingdi erentfromoneandzero,respectively,cannotberejectedfortheabovemodelsatthe5percentcon dencelevelforthefullsample,andmodelsM1andM5providethehighestR2of24percent.Thesespeci cationshaveARCH-typetime-varyingconditionalskewnessdynamicsincommon,butM5nestsM1throughtheconditionalkurtosisdynamics.However,neitherofthesetwomodelsispreferredinanyofthesubsamples,sincethehypothesis 1=1isrejectedatconventionallevelsofcon dence.Again,asmentionedearlier,webaseourjudgmentmainlyonfull-sampleresults,andmodelM1wouldbethepreferredspeci cation,sinceitismoreparsimoniousandslightlyfavoredoverM5basedonLRtestsandBICvaluesinTables5and6.However,notethatthejointhypothesis 0=0and 1=1isnotrejectedformodelM8,neitherinthefullsamplewithanR2of14percentnorinthesecondandthirdsubsampleswithR2sof7percentand16percent,respectively.Inthe rstsubsample,M8isalsothepreferredmodel,withanR2of22percentamongallspeci cationswherethehypothesis 1=1isnotrejected.ThenM8wouldbethebestmodel,shouldweextendourmodel-selectioncriteriatosubsampleregressionresultsandtheneedfor ttingtheexcess-returnsdataaswell.WereporttheestimationresultsforthebinormaldistributionmodelinTable8.Sincethestandard-izedbinormaldistributionisaone-parameterdistribution,itdoesnotallowforindependentestimationofconditionalkurtosis.Thus,weestimateonlymodelsM0{M4forthecaseofstandardizedbinormaldistributederrors.Similartothepreviouscases,we ndsigni cantsupportingevidenceforasymmetry-in-asymmetry.Almostallestimatedparametersarestatisticallydi erentfromzero.BasedontheLRstatistics,M3isthepreferredmodelforthefullsample.ItallowsforsymmetricGARCH-typedynamicsintheconditionalskewnessmeasure.Inthe1980{89subsample,M3remainsthemodelofchoice.Inthe1990{99subsample,M4istiedwithM2basedontheLRtest,butM2ispreferredtoM4basedonBIC.Inthe2000{09subsample,nomodelperformsbetterthanM0,whichallowsforconstantand.17 Table9reportsmodelevaluationresultsthroughMincer-Zarnowitzpredictiveregressions,formodelsM0{M4withstandardizedbinormallydistributederrors.Acrossthefullsample,modelsM1,M2andM4haveestimated 1parametersthatarestatisticallyindistinguishablefromunity.M1andM2havethehighestR2of25percentforthefullsample.Onceweconsidersubsamples,modelsM1andM4demonstratesimilarperformance;bothmodelsdonotrejectthehypothesis 1=1inallsubsamplesexcept1980{89.However,basedonourresultsreportedinTable8,weknowthatmodelM1ispreferredovermodelM4in ttingtheexcess-returnsdata.Thus,basedonMincer-Zarnowitzpredictiveregressionconsiderations,wechooseM1,whichallowsforasymmetricARCH-typedynamicsintheconditionalskewness.Note,however,thatalthoughmodelM3hasanestimated 1parameterof0.9262thatisstatisticallydi erentfromunityinthefullsample,thisvalueremainsquiteclosetoone.Furthermore, 1parameterestimatesarenotstatisticallydi erentfromoneformodelM3inallsubsamples.Giventheseobservations,onceweaccommodatetheneedfor ttingtheexcess-returnsdataaswell,wemaybetemptedtochooseM3overM1basedonLRtestingandsimilarpredictiveresults.11Comparingourresultsforthefullsampleacrossthethreedistributionalassumptions,weobservethefollowing:(i)GST-basedestimationresultsimplythatModel8,whichallowsforasymmetryinbothconditionalskewnessandkurtosis,performsbetterthanalternativemodelsstudiedincharac-terizingexcess-returnsdynamicsandinMincer-Zarnowitzpredictiveregressionsofparametricontonon-parametricmeasuresofrelativedownsidesemi-variances.(ii)SGED-basedestimationresultsim-plythatifwewantbothreasonablecharacterizationofexcess-returnsdynamicsandstrongpredictiveresultsformeasuringRRSV,thenourchoiceisM8,whichallowsforasymmetryinbothconditionalskewnessandkurtosis.However,ifweareinterestedonlyinpredictivepowerfortheRRSV,thenM1isthebetterchoice.(iii)Binormaldistribution-basedestimationresults,similartotheSGEDcase,leadustochoosetheparsimoniousM1forpredictivepurposesonly.Oncewedecidetocharacterizeexcess-returnsdynamicsaswell,thenwechoosethemore exibleM3,whichallowsforsymmetricGARCH(1,1)-typedynamicsintheskewnessprocess.Wederiveourtheoreticalframeworkfromtheliteratureonrealizedvolatility.Thus,inourtestingprocedures,wefollowthatliteraturecloselyinthatweareconcernedwithin-samplepredictabilityandnotout-of-sampleforecastability.Thus,itappearsthat,strictlyspeaking,modelM8withSGEDerrorsprovidesestimated 1sthatarestatisticallyclosetounity,deliversreasonableR2sandprovidesverygoodin-samplecharacterizationofexcess-returnsdynamics.WeconcludethatamodelthatallowsforasymmetricGARCH(1,1)-typedynamicsandaSGEDistheoverallpreferredmodel.Inaddition,this 1122criticalvaluesat5percentand1percentcon dencelevelsare5.99and9.21,respectively,whilethecomputedLRteststatisticisover11.18 modelprovidesstrongstatisticalsupportforasymmetry-in-asymmetryandasymmetryinconditionalkurtosis.Inquiteafewcases,wecouldnotrejectastatisticallysigni cantpositivedi erencebetweeninterceptparameters 0and0.Whiletheupwardbiasobservedacrossmodelsanddistributionsmayseemundesirableat rstglance,wekeepinmindthatthevastliteratureontheinformationcontentofimpliedvolatilityfacesthesametypeofproblem.Chernov(2007)addressesthebiasissuebyaddingasuitablepredictortotheright-handsideofthepredictiveregression.Itispossiblethat,byaddressingthepossibilityofamissingvariable,predictiveregressionsmayimprove.However,sinceM8coupledwithanSGEDworkswellandislargelyfreeofthisbias,itisquitepossiblethatthisbiasisduetodistributionalassumptions.Wewilladdressthisinterestingissueinfutureresearch.6ConclusionsInthispaper,weaddressanimportantgapintherecentandgrowingliteratureonconditionalskew-ness.Inrecentyears,anincreasingnumberofstudieshaveaddressedtheimportanceofmodellinghighermomentsandhowtheirdynamicsa ect nancialrisk-managementprocedures.Weproposeamethodologytoassessthemodeladequacyofthegrowingnumberofproposedparametricmeasuresoftheconditionalskewness.Weshowthat,theoretically,conditionalskewnessmatterswhenaseriesdemonstratessigni cantrelativesemi-variance.Wethenproposeasimpleandintuitivenon-parametricmeasureofrelativesemi-variance,whichwecallrealizedrelativesemi-variance,inthespiritofthesuccessfulliteratureonrealizedvariance.Weshowthat,undermildregularityconditions,parametricmodelsofconditionalasymmetryapproximatetherealizedrelativesemi-variance.Wealsoshowthatourproposedmeasureandmethodologyhaveclosetiestotheliteratureonrealizedvariance,ontheonehand,andtotherecentdevelopmentsonrealizedsemi-varianceontheother.Wethenstudyseveralparametricmodelsofconditionalskewness.Sincetheperformanceoftheparametricmodelsofskewnesscruciallydependsonthedistributionalassumptions,westudyarangeofrelevantdistributionalmodels,includingtheskewedgeneralizedStudent-tofHansen(1994)andJondeauandRockinger(2003),skewedGED,andbinormaldistributioninourpreviouswork(Feunouetal.2013).We ndstatisticallysigni cantevidenceinsupportofasymmetry-in-asymmetry,ortheso-calledleveragee ectintheconditionalskewness,andstrongsupportforasymmetric(G)ARCH-typedynamicsforbothskewnessandpeakednessprocessesintheconditionaldistribution.Weconcludethat,basedonourresults,thebestmodelforconditionalskewnessisonethatallowsforasymmetric19 GARCH(1,1)dynamicsandadmitsskewedGEDerrors,appliedtobothskewnessandpeakednessprocessesintheconditionaldistributionofreturns.Thismodelsharesmanyfeatureswiththewell-knownEGARCHmodelofNelson(1991).20 ReferencesAndersen,T.G.,Bollerslev,T.,Diebold,F.X.,Labys,P.,2001.Thedistributionofrealizedexchangeratevolatility.JournaloftheAmericanStatisticalAssociation96,42{55.Andersen,T.G.,Bollerslev,T.,Diebold,F.X.,Labys,P.,2003.Modelingandforecastingrealizedvolatility.Econometrica71,579{625.Bangert,U.,Goodhew,P.J.,Jeynes,C.,Wilson,I.H.,1986.LowEnergy(2-5keV)ArgonDamageinSilicon.JournalofPhysicsD:AppliedPhysics19,589{603.Barndor -Nielsen,O.E.,Kinnebrock,S.,Shephard,N.,2010.VolatilityandTimeSeriesEconometrics:EssaysinHonorofRobertF.Engle.OxfordUniversityPress,Ch.Measuringdownsiderisk:realisedsemivariance,pp.117{136.Bekaert,G.,Erb,C.,Harvey,C.R.,Viskanta,T.,1998.DistributionalCharacteristicsofEmergingMarketReturnsandAssetAllocation.JournalofPortfolioManagement,102{116.Bollerslev,T.,Engle,R.F.,Nelson,D.B.,1994.ARCHModels.Vol.4ofTheHandbookofEconomet-rics.North-Holland,Amsterdam,pp.2959{3038.Bowley,A.,1920.ElementsofStatistics.CharlesScribnersSons,NewYork,NY.Brannas,K.,Nordman,N.,2003.Conditionalskewnessmodellingforstockreturns.AppliedEconomicsLetters10(11),725{728.Brooks,C.,Burke,S.P.,Heravi,S.,Persand,G.,2005.AutoregressiveConditionalKurtosis.JournalofFinancialEconometrics3(3),399{421.Chen,J.,Hong,H.,Stein,J.,2001.Forecastingcrashes:tradingvolume,pastreturns,andconditionalskewnessinstockprices.JournalofFinancialEconomics61,345{381.Chernov,M.,2007.OntheRoleofRiskPremiainVolatilityForecasting.JournalofBusiness&Eco-nomicStatistics25(4),381{411.Christo ersen,P.,Heston,S.,Jacobs,K.,2006.Optionvaluationwithconditionalskewness.JournalofEconometrics131(12),253{284.Conrad,J.,Dittmar,R.,Ghysels,E.,2013.Ex-AnteSkewnessandExpectedStockReturns.JournalofFinance68(1),85{124.21 Davidson,J.,1994.StochasticLimitTheory,AnIntroductionforEconometricians,1stEdition.Ad-vancedTextsinEconometrics.OxfordUniversityPress,Oxford,U.K.Durham,G.B.,Park,Y.-H.,2013.BeyondStochasticVolatilityandJumpsinReturnsandVolatility.JournalofBusinessandEconomicStatistics31(1),107{121.Engle,R.F.,Ng,V.K.,1993.MeasuringandTestingtheImpactofNewsonVolatility.JournalofFinance48(5),1749{1778.Feunou,B.,Jahan-Parvar,M.R.,Tedongap,R.,2013.ModelingMarketDownsideVolatility.ReviewofFinance17(1),443{481.Ghysels,E.,Plazzi,A.,Valkanov,R.,2011.ConditionalSkewnessofStockMarketReturnsinDevelopedandEmergingMarketsanditsEconomicFundamentals.WorkingPaper,Kenan-FlaglerBusinessSchool-UNC,andRadySchoolofBusiness-UCSD.Ghysels,E.,Santa-Clara,P.,Valkanov,R.,2005.ThereisaRisk-ReturnTrade-O AfterAll.JournalofFinancialEconomics76,509{548.Ghysels,E.,Santa-Clara,P.,Valkanov,R.,2006.Predictingvolatility:gettingthemostoutofreturndatasampledatdi erentfrequencies.JournalofEconometrics131,59{95.Ghysels,E.,Sinko,A.,Valkanov,R.,2007.MIDASregressions:furtherresultsandnewdirections.EconometricReviews26(1),53{90.Gibbons,J.F.,Mylroie,S.,1973.EstimationofImpurityPro lesinIon-ImplantedAmorphousTargetsUsingJoinedHalf-GaussianDistributions.AppliedPhysicsLetters22,568{569.Glosten,L.R.,Jagannathan,R.,Runkle,D.E.,1993.OntheRelationBetweenExpectedValueandtheVolatilityoftheNominalExcessReturnonStocks.JournalofFinance48(5),1779{1801.Grigoletto,M.,Lisi,F.,2009.Lookingforskewnessin nancialtimeseries.EconometricsJournal12(2),310{323.Groeneveld,R.,Meeden,G.,1984.Measuringskewnessandkurtosis.TheStatistician33,391{399.Guidolin,M.,Timmermann,A.,2008.InternationalAssetAllocationunderRegimeSwitching,SkewandKurtosisPreferences.ReviewofFinancialStudies21,889{935.22 Hansen,B.E.,1994.AutoregressiveConditionalDensityEstimation.InternationalEconomicReview35(3),705{730.Harvey,C.R.,Siddique,A.,1999.AutoregressiveConditionalSkewness.JournalofFinancialandQuantitativeAnalysis34,465{488.Harvey,C.R.,Siddique,A.,2000.ConditionalSkewnessinAssetPricingTests.JournalofFinance55,1263{1295.Jarque,C.M.,Bera,A.K.,1980.EcientTestsforNormality,HomoscedasticityandSerialIndepen-denceofRegressionResiduals.EconomicsLetters6(3),255{259.Jondeau,E.,Rockinger,M.,2003.ConditionalVolatility,Skewness,andKurtosis:Existence,Persis-tence,andComovements.JournalofEconomicDynamicsandControl27,1699{1737.Kim,T.-H.,White,H.,2004.OnMoreRobustEstimationofSkewnessandKurtosis.FinanceResearchLetters1(1),56{73.Kimber,A.C.,Jeynes,C.,1987.AnApplicationoftheTruncatedTwo-PieceNormalDistributiontotheMeasurementofDepthsofArsenicImplantsinSilicon.JournaloftheRoyalStatisticalSociety:SeriesB36,352{357.Lanne,M.,Saikkonen,P.,2007.Modelingconditionalskewnessinstockreturns.EuropeanJournalofFinance13(8),691{704.Leon,A.,Rubio,G.,Serna,G.,2005.Autoregressiveconditionalvolatility,skewnessandkurtosis.TheQuarterlyReviewofEconomicsandFinance45,599{618.Mincer,J.,Zarnowitz,V.,1969.JacobMincer(editor),EconomicForecastsandExpectations.NationalBureauofEconomicResearch,NewYork,NY,Ch.TheEvaluationofEconomicForecasts.Nelson,D.B.,1991.ConditionalHeteroskedasticityinAssetReturns:ANewApproach.Econometrica59,347{370.Neuberger,A.,2012.Realizedskewness.ReviewofFinancialStudies25(11),3423{3455.Patton,A.J.,2004.Ontheout-of-sampleimportanceofskewnessandasymmetricdependenceforassetallocation.JournalofFinancialEconometrics2(1),130{168.23 Pearson,K.,1895.Contributionstothemathematicaltheoryofevolution.II.Skewvariationinhomo-geneousmaterial.PhilosophicalTransactionsoftheRoyalSocietyofLondon.A186,343{414.Protter,P.,1992.StochasticIntegrationandDi erentialEquations.Springer-Verlag,Berlin.Toth,Z.,Szentimrey,T.,1990.TheBinormalDistribution:ADistributionforRepresentingAsymmet-ricalbutNormal-LikeWeatherElements.JournalofClimate3(1),128{137.Widder,D.,1946.TheLaplaceTransform.PrincetonUniversityPress,Princeton,NJ.Wilhelmsson,A.,2009.Valueatriskwithtimevaryingvariance,skewnessandkurtosis{theNIG-ACDmodel.EconometricsJournal12(1),82{104.24 Appendix:ProofofProposition(2.2)Theset-upissimilartothatofAndersenetal.(2003)(henceforth,ABDL(2003)).Proposition1ofABDL(2003)permitsauniquecanonicaldecompositionofthelogarithmicassetpriceprocessp=(p(t))t2[0;T],p(t)=p(0)+A(t)+M(t);whereAisa nitevariationandpredictablemeancomponent,andMisalocalmartingale.Letr(t;h)=p(t)�p(t�h)denotethecontinuouslycompoundedreturnover[t�h;t].Thecumulativereturnsprocessfromt=0onward,r=(r(t))t2[0;T],isthenr(t)r(t;t)=p(t)�p(0)=A(t)+M(t):Furtherassumethatthemeanprocess,fA(s)�A(t)gs2[t;t+h],conditionaloninformationattimetisapredeterminedfunctionover[t;t+h]:AnimmediateresultofthisassumptionistheCorollary1,andhenceequation(6)ofABDL(2003),whichestablishesthatVar(r(t+h;h)jFt)=E�[r;r]t+h�[r;r]tjFt:Inotherwords,theconditionalvarianceequalstheconditionalexpectationofthequadraticvariationofthereturnsprocess.Denotethemodeofthedistributionofr(t+h;h)conditionalonFtbym(t;h).Leti(t+h;h)=1[r(t+h;h)m(t;h)]denoteanindicatorrandomprocessthattakes1ifthereturnsbetween[t;t+h]aregreaterthanorequaltotheconditionalmodem(t;h):Sincethemeanprocess,fA(s)�A(t)gs2[t;t+h],conditionaloninformationattimet,isapredeter-minedfunctionover[t;t+h];withoutlossofgenerality,weomitAfromthispointonwards.25 Wethushave2u(t;h)Var(r(t+h;h)jFt;i(t+h;h)=1)=Var(M(t+h)�M(t)jFt;i(t+h;h)=1)=Var(M(t+h)jFt;i(t+h;h)=1)=E�M(t+h)2jFt;i(t+h;h)=1�fE(M(t+h)jFt;i(t+h;h)=1)g2=E�[M;M]t+hjFt;i(t+h;h)=1�fE(M(t+h)jFt;i(t+h;h)=1)g2=E[M;M]t+hi(t+h;h) (t;h)jFt�EM(t+h)i(t+h;h) (t;h)jFt2;where(t;h)Pr[i(t+h;h)=1jFt]:UsingCorollary3inChapterII.6ofProtter(1992),whereitisshownthatE�M(t+h)2=E�[M;M]t+h,wehave2d(t;h)Var(r(t+h;h)jFt;i(t+h;h)=1)=E[M;M]t+h(1�i(t+h;h)) 1�(t;h)jFt�EM(t+h)(1�i(t+h;h)) 1�(t;h)jFt2;and2u(t;h)�2d(t;h)=E[M;M]t+hi(t+h;h) (t;h)�[M;M]t+h(1�i(t+h;h)) 1�(t;h)jFt+EM(t+h)(1�i(t+h;h)) 1�(t;h)jFt2�EM(t+h)i(t+h;h) (t;h)jFt22u(t;h)�2d(t;h)=1 (t;h)(1�(t;h))E�[M;M]t+h(i(t+h;h)�(t;h))jFt�1 (t;h)(1�(t;h))E(M(t+h)(i(t+h;h)�(t;h))jFt)EM(t+h)(t;h)�(t;h)i(t+h;h)+i(t+h;h)�i(t+h;h)(t;h) (t;h)(1�(t;h))jFt:SinceE[i(t+h;h)jFt]=(t;h),wehave2u(t;h)�2d(t;h)=1 (t;h)(1�(t;h))E��[M;M]t+h�[M;M]t(i(t+h;h)�(t;h))jFt�1 (t;h)(1�(t;h))E((M(t+h)�M(t))(i(t+h;h)�(t;h))jFt)EM(t+h)(1�2(t;h)) (t;h)(1�(t;h))(i(t+h;h)�(t;h))+2jFt26 2u(t;h)�2d(t;h)=1 (t;h)(1�(t;h))E��[M;M]t+h�[M;M]t(i(t+h;h)�(t;h))jFt�1 (t;h)(1�(t;h))E((M(t+h)�M(t))(i(t+h;h)�(t;h))jFt)(1�2(t;h)) (t;h)(1�(t;h))E((M(t+h)�M(t))(i(t+h;h)�(t;h))jFt)+2M(t)2u(t;h)�2d(t;h)=1 (t;h)(1�(t;h))E��[r;r]t+h�[r;r]t(i(t+h;h)�(t;h))jFt�1 (t;h)(1�(t;h))E(r(t+h;h)(i(t+h;h)�(t;h))jFt)(1�2(t;h)) (t;h)(1�(t;h))E(r(t+h;h)(i(t+h;h)�(t;h))jFt)+2M(t)((t;h)(1�(t;h)))�2u(t;h)�2d(t;h)=E��[r;r]t+h�[r;r]t(i(t+h;h)�(t;h))jFt�E(r(t+h;h)(i(t+h;h)�(t;h))jFt)(1�2(t;h)) (t;h)(1�(t;h))E(r(t+h;h)(i(t+h;h)�(t;h))jFt)+2M(t)((t;h)(1�(t;h)))�2u(t;h)�2d(t;h)=cov�[r;r]t+h�[r;r]t;i(t+h;h)jFt�cov(r(t+h;h);i(t+h;h)jFt)(1�2(t;h)) (t;h)(1�(t;h))cov(r(t+h;h);i(t+h;h)jFt)+2M(t):Hence,twocomponentsdrivetheconditionalskewness.The rstcomponentistheconditionalcovariancebetweenreturnsandtheindicatorvariablethatshowswhetherthemarkethasanupwardordownwardmovement.Thesecondcomponentistheconditionalcovariancebetweenthequadraticvari-ationofreturnsandthesameindicatorvariable.Fromthispointon,wefocusonthelattercomponent,since,asweshowlaterinthisappendix,itisdrivenbyjumpsinthereturns.Theformercomponentistheskewnessinducedbytheinstantaneouscorrelationbetweenlog-returnsandvolatility:2u(t;h)�2d(t;h)1 (t;h)(1�(t;h))cov�[r;r]t+h�[r;r]t;i(t+h;h)jFt:27 Lety(t+h;h)�y(1)(t+h;h);y(2)(t+h;h)0�[r;r]t+h�[r;r]t;i(t+h;h)0:FromCorollary1ofABDL(2003),wehavecov�[r;r]t+h�[r;r]t;i(t+h;h)jFt=Ehy(1);y(2)it+h�hy(1);y(2)itjFt:Inotherwords,theconditionalcovariancebetweenquadraticreturnvariationandtheupsidein-dicatorequalstheconditionalexpectationofthequadraticcovariationbetweenthequadraticreturnvariationandtheupsideindicator.Proposition2ofABDL(2003)providesaconsistentestimatorofy(1);y(2)t:Recallthatproposition:Foranincreasingsequenceofrandompartitionsof[0;T],0=m;0m;1;suchthatsupj1(m;j+1�m;j)!0andsupj1m;j!Tform!1withprobabilityone,wehavelimm!18:Xj1hy(1)(t^m;j)�y(1)(t^m;j�1)ihy(2)(t^m;j)�y(2)(t^m;j�1)i9=;!hy(1);y(2)it;andthuswehavelimm!18:jt+hXj=jt[r;r]m;j�[r;r]m;j�1(i(m;j)�i(m;j�1))9=;!hy(1);y(2)it+h�hy(1);y(2)it;wherejtinfm;jt(j),jt+hsupm;jt+h(j)andi(t)i(t;t)=1[r(t)(t;0)]:Thus,Pjt+hj=jt[r;r]m;j�[r;r]m;j�1(i(m;j)�i(m;j�1))isameasureofrealizedskewness.Wenowsimplifythederivedrealizedskewnessexpression[r;r]m;j�[r;r]m;j�1(p(m;j)�p(m;j�1))2;andwecanshowthati(m;j)�i(m;j�1)=1[p(m;j)�p(m;j�1)0]�1[p(m;j)�p(m;j�1)0];sothatthemeasureofrealizedskewnessbecomesjt+hXj=jt(p(m;j)�p(m;j�1))21[p(m;j)�p(m;j�1)0]�1[p(m;j)�p(m;j�1)0]:Thus,usingBarndor -Nielsenetal.'s(2010)(henceforth,BKS(2010))notation,wehaveshownthattherealizedskewnessisthedi erencebetweentheupsiderealizedsemi-variance(RS+)andthedownsiderealizedsemi-variance(RS�):28 RS+(t+h;h)=jt+hXj=jt(p(m;j)�p(m;j�1))21p(m;j)�p(m;j�1)0RS�(t+h;h)=jt+hXj=jt(p(m;j)�p(m;j�1))21p(m;j)�p(m;j�1)0:Torecap,wehave2u(t;h)�2d(t;h)1 (t;h)(1�(t;h))E�RS+(t+h;h)�RS�(t+h;h)jFt:FurtherusingBKS(2010)results,wecanprovidemoreinsightintothesourcesofconditionalskewness.BKS(2010)showthatRS+(t+h;h)�RS�(t+h;h)!t+hXt(ps)2[1ps0�1ps0];wherepsp(s)�p(s�)isthejumpattimes:Hencepositiveskewnessisdrivenbythefactthatpositivejumpamplitudesarehigherthannegativeamplitudes,whereasnegativeskewnessisdrivenbythefactthatnegativejumpamplitudesarehigherthanpositiveamplitudes.29 Figure1:Realizedvolatilityandrealizedrelativesemi-varianceforS&P500returns,1986{2009 Inthis gureweplotrealizedvarianceandrealizedrelativesemi-varianceforS&P500returns,sampledat15-minutefrequency.Toprovideamoreinformativeillustration,weplotdailyrealizedvolatilitiesandtheendofthemonthrealizedrelativesemi-variance(every22ndobservationisplotted)values.Figure2:Skewness-KurtosisBoundaryforSkewedGeneralizedStudent-t,SkewedGEDandBinormalDistributions This guredepictstheskewness-kurtosisboundariesforHansen(1994)skewedgeneralizedStudent-tdistributionandskewedGEDagainstthetheoreticalboundaryimpliedbyTheorem12.a,page134ofWidder(1946).Thetheoreticalboundaryisobtainedfrom234�1with4&#x-322;0,where3=E(z3t)and4=E(z4t)arethenon-centeredthirdandfourthmomentsofarandomvariablefztg1t=0.30 1986 1990 1993 1997 2001 2006 2009 0 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.07 0.08 Daily Realized Volatility From 15-minute Returns 1986 1991 1995 1999 2004 2009 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 Daily Realized Skewness From 15 minutes Returns 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 Kurtosis FrontierBinormal Distribution Skewed Generalized Error Distribution Figure3:ImpactofSkewnessandPeakednessParametersonSkewnessandKurtosisSurfacesforSkewedGeneralizedStudent-tDistribution This gureshowsthecontributionoftheskewness,,andpeakednessparameter,,ingeneratingskewness(toppanel)andkurtosis(bottompanel)surfacesfortheskewedgeneralizedStudent-tdistributionofHansen(1994).Therangeofparametersischosensuchthattheydonotviolatetheskewness-kurtosisboundary.Figure4:ImpactofSkewnessandPeakednessParametersonSkewnessandKurtosisSurfacesforSkewedGeneralizedErrorDistribution This gureshowsthecontributionoftheskewness,,andpeakednessparameter,,ingeneratingskewness(toppanel)andkurtosis(bottompanel)surfacesfortheskewedgeneralizederrordistribution(SGED).Therangeofparametersischosensuchthattheydonotviolatetheskewness-kurtosisboundary.31 1 0.5 0 0.5 1 3 3.5 4 4.5 5 30 20 10 0 10 20 30  and  1 0.5 0 0.5 1 4 4.2 4.4 4.6 4.8 5 0 50 100 150 200 250  and  1 0.5 0 0.5 1 0 1 2 3 4 5 5 0 5  and  1 0.5 0 0.5 1 0 1 2 3 4 5 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40  and  Table1:SummaryStatisticsoftheData PanelA:DescriptiveStatistics,ExcessReturns ReturnSeries Mean(%)Std.Dev.(%)SkewnessKurtosisJ-Bp-Value S&P500 3.4821.94-1.2431.870.01 PanelB:DescriptiveStatistics,Relativedownsidesemi-variance RSV(%)Std.Dev.(%)SkewnessKurtosisJ-Bp-Value S&P500(NP) 1.848.711.2116.360.01 Thetoppanelofthistablereportssummarystatisticsofexcessreturns.Calculationofthereturnsisbasedonsubtractingthedaily3-monthU.S.Treasurybillratefromthelogdi erenceofthemarkettotalreturnindex.Meanofexcessreturnsandstandarddeviationsarereportedasannualizedpercentages.Excesskurtosisvaluesarereported.Thecolumntitled\J-Bp-Value"reportsp-valuesofJarqueandBera(1980)testsofnormalityinpercentages.Thebottompanelreportsthecomputedstatisticsoftheobservedrelativesemi-variance(RSV)inthedata.ReportedRSVisbasedonthemeandi erencebetween ltereddownsideandupsidesemi-variances.The rstcolumnreportstheannualizedRSV,andthesecondcolumnisthestandarddeviationofthisquantity.Duetoavailabilityofhigh-frequencydataforS&P500returns,wereportthenon-parametricestimateforrelativedownsidesemi-variancefortheUnitedStatesdenotedasS&P500(NP),basedon15-minutereturns.ThesampleperiodisJanuary1980toSeptember2010.Source:ThomsonReutersDatastreamandFREDIIdatabankattheFederalReserveBankofSt.Louis.32 Table2:EstimationResultsfortheConditionalSkewnessDynamicswithGeneralizedStudent-tDistribution(1) NM0M1M2M3M4M5M6M7M8 1980-2009 0-0.1047*-0.1050*-0.1147*-0.0327*-0.0594*-0.1109*-0.1246*-0.0324*-0.0655*(0.0298)(0.0296)(0.0428)(0.0136)(0.0282)(0.0297)(0.0435)(0.0128)(0.0286)1+0.1070*0.1222*0.1080*0.1511*0.1144*0.1211*0.1208*0.1584*(0.0253)(0.0544)(0.0224)(0.0459)(0.0260)(0.0486)(0.0220)(0.0443)1�0.0981*0.0814*0.0840*0.0716*(0.0385)(0.0312)(0.0426)(0.0353)20.6593*0.6590*0.6694*0.6643*(0.0955)(0.0915)(0.0823)(0.0902) 0-1.4635*-1.4464*-1.4450*-1.4660*-1.4663*-1.4762*-1.0870*-0.7289*-0.4997*(0.1159)(0.1364)(0.1368)(0.1365)(0.1361)(0.1567)(0.1594)(0.1737)(0.1947) 1+-0.5805*-1.0077*-0.6848*-0.9800*(0.1898)(0.1191)(0.1283)(0.1092) 1�0.2368*0.1909*(0.0943)(0.0762) 20.5119*0.4309*(0.1097)(0.1158) LogL24639.424837.724846.024846.124852.424853.124849.124867.824861.624878.7LRStat396.60*16.60*0.20NA1.40NA37.40*NA34.20*BIC-3.2494-3.2732-3.2731-3.2720-3.2728-3.2717-3.2724-3.2725-3.2716-3.2715 1980-1989 0-0.0157-0.0129-0.0307-0.0022-0.0133-0.0110-0.0678-0.0018-0.0326(0.0546)(0.0517)(0.0732)(0.0168)(0.0407)(0.0512)(0.0731)(0.0165)(0.0493)1+0.08530.11200.0864*0.10560.07830.14460.0760*0.1282(0.0444)(0.0902)(0.0341)(0.0728)(0.0462)(0.0947)(0.0357)(0.0845)1�0.06700.07670.00730.0481(0.0706)(0.0469)(0.0646)(0.0598)20.6741*0.6702*0.6777*0.6617*(0.1566)(0.1557)(0.1681)(0.1757) 0-1.8280*-1.7839*-1.7848*-1.7891*-1.7887*-1.7515*-1.5049*-0.0407-0.6140(0.2053)(0.2007)(0.2006)(0.2012)(0.2011)(0.2128)(0.2418)(0.0219)(0.4645) 1+0.0591-0.6017*0.0510-0.5835*(0.0941)(0.1869)(0.0294)(0.1680) 1�0.21160.1201(0.1321)(0.1017) 20.9779*0.5330*(0.0121)(0.2576) LogL8190.18308.48310.18310.28312.48312.58310.38313.88314.28316.4LRStat236.60*3.400.20NA0.20NA7.00*NA4.40BIC-3.2268-3.2674-3.2650-3.2619-3.2628-3.2597-3.2620-3.2571-3.2573-3.2519 Thistablereportstheestimatedparametersof~and~asinequation(10),andwhereinnovationsfollowaskewedGSTprocessasinHansen(1994).Nrepresentsthebaselinenormallydistributederrorscase.ModelsM0toM8representequations(14)to(21),respectively.Tosavespace,wereportestimatedvaluesfor1and1+onthesamerow.Estimatedstandarderrorsarereportedinparentheses,belowtheestimatedparameters.\LogL"representsthecomputedloglikelihoodfunction.Wereportlikelihoodratioteststatistics,\LRStat,"withrespecttotheprecedingmodel.\NA"impliesthatthemodelsarenon-nested,andthustheLRteststatisticisnotcomputed.Allmodelsarepreferredtothebenchmarknormalmodel,basedonthelikelihoodratiotest.Thus,wedonotreporttheseteststatistics.*representsrejectionofthenullhypothesisinquestionatthe5%con dencelevel.\BIC"representsBayesianinformationcriteriafortheestimatedmodels.33 Table3:EstimationResultsfortheConditionalSkewnessDynamicswithGeneralizedStudent-tDistribution(2) NM0M1M2M3M4M5M6M7M8 1990-1999 0-0.0643-0.0582-0.1636*-0.0090-0.0788-0.0527-0.1666*-0.0022-0.1037(0.0515)(0.0516)(0.0769)(0.0156)(0.0538)(0.0508)(0.0770)(0.0154)(0.0533)1+0.1503*0.3335*0.1488*0.2739*0.1572*0.3567*0.1614*0.3524*(0.0457)(0.1101)(0.0377)(0.0982)(0.0415)(0.1040)(0.0339)(0.0957)1�0.05960.09490.06860.0946(0.0683)(0.0509)(0.0696)(0.0528)20.7029*0.6455*0.6945*0.5963*(0.1141)(0.1341)(0.0990)(0.1210) 0-1.5922*-1.5691*-1.5289*-1.6366*-1.6053*-1.6505*-1.1899*-0.6799*-0.1532(0.2022)(0.2221)(0.2297)(0.2164)(0.2221)(0.2274)(0.2842)(0.1876)(0.2080) 1+-0.7164*-1.1082*-0.7516*-1.1332*(0.2075)(0.2077)(0.1571)(0.1588) 1�0.20260.1884(0.2201)(0.1723) 20.6061*0.6387*(0.0957)(0.0920) LogL8628.38687.38692.88694.68697.68698.88696.68702.78706.68714.3LRStat118.00*11.00*3.60NA2.40NA12.20*NA15.40*BIC-3.3989-3.4161-3.4151-3.4127-3.4139-3.4113-3.4135-3.4097-3.4113-3.4081 2000-2009 0-0.2392*-0.2404*-0.1073-0.1069-0.1131-0.2593*-0.0932-0.0897-0.1127(0.0530)(0.0530)(0.0835)(0.0972)(0.1023)(0.0530)(0.0805)(0.0877)(0.1090)1+0.0762-0.09450.0818-0.09770.0359-0.16220.0570-0.1522(0.0521)(0.0983)(0.0509)(0.1025)(0.0491)(0.0904)(0.0422)(0.0935)1�0.2391*0.2392*0.2398*0.2475*(0.0952)(0.0959)(0.0820)(0.1006)20.5504-0.03060.6375-0.1292(0.3974)(0.2909)(0.3412)(0.2886) 0-0.2152*-0.2614*-0.3293*-0.2537*-0.3307*0.3538*0.2914*-0.0378-0.4276(0.0546)(0.0560)(0.0741)(0.0625)(0.0713)(0.1140)(0.1363)(0.2236)(0.4257) 1+-2.0265*-1.9913*-1.9479*-1.7840*(0.2790)(0.2322)(0.2298)(0.2403) 1�0.7292*-4.0525(0.1026)(3.5040) 20.4158*0.3005(0.0875)(0.1588) LogL7866.47890.57891.77893.87892.17893.97910.27916.27916.57919.5LRStat48.20*2.404.20NA3.60NA12.00*NA6.00*BIC-3.1109-3.1143-3.1116-3.1094-3.1087-3.1063-3.1159-3.1121-3.1122-3.1072 Thistablereportstheestimationresultsforthe1990{99and2000{09subsamples.RefertothenotestoTable2formoreinformation.34 Table4:EvaluatingtheConditionalRelativeDownsideVariancewithGeneralizedStudent-tDistribution M0M1M2M3M4M5M6M7M8 1980-2009 0-3.016E-06-1.16E-05*-1.16E-05*-1.81E-05*-1.72E-05*-1.19E-05*-1.33E-05*-1.96E-05*-1.91E-05*(2.229E-06)(1.86E-06)(1.87E-06)(2.73E-06)(1.94E-06)(1.87E-06)(1.85E-06)(1.94E-06)(1.93E-06) 12.4336*1.5751*1.5727*0.9441*1.02501.5274*1.4075*0.8826*0.9819(0.0839)(0.0338)(0.0345)(0.0251)(0.0277)(0.0338)(0.0304)(0.0244)(0.0497) R20.12260.26550.25680.19050.18580.25380.26310.17880.1877JT292.89*309.64*295.44*48.692*79.044*284.57*231.66*125.66*98.71* 1980-1989 0-1.37E-06-8.69E-07-8.90E-08-9.59E-06-6.36E-06-3.08E-07-2.74E-06-1.09E-05-7.90E-06(1.17E-05)(7.96E-06)(8.07E-06)(9.40E-06)(6.64E-06)(5.70E-06)(5.53E-06)(6.72E-06)(6.50E-06) 12.0431*1.7049*1.7341*0.8763*1.00701.6928*1.4798*0.8189*0.9870*(0.2120)(0.0534)(0.0556)(0.0414)(0.0468)(0.1086)(0.0450)(0.0402)(0.0395) R20.08680.51060.49880.31450.32150.05430.52540.29800.3460JT24.22*174.24*174.30*9.974*0.938162.75*113.90*22.091*1.585 1990-1999 01.88E-06-1.33E-05*-1.32E-05*-1.34E-05*-1.32E-05*-1.35E-05*-1.38E-05*-1.47E-05*-1.47E-05*(4.33E-06)(3.20E-06)(3.21E-06)(3.05E-06)(2.17E-06)(2.26E-06)(2.27E-06)(2.12E-06)(2.14E-06) 13.2425*1.12761.13821.02241.04221.08471.03660.9304*1.0414(0.3154)(0.1386)(0.1387)(0.1015)(0.1061)(0.1355)(0.1352)(0.0964)(0.1005) R20.04030.02560.02600.03880.03690.02480.02280.03570.0318JT50.740*18.136*17.94*19.27*37.18*36.18*37.25*48.48*47.01* 2000-2009 0-1.55E-06-4.05E-06-8.24E-06-7.45E-06-8.15E-06*-3.63E-07-9.52E-06*-2.20E-06-7.14E-06*(5.05E-06)(4.88E-06)(4.72E-06)(4.88E-06)(3.33E-06)(3.53E-06)(3.37E-06)(3.51E-06)(3.37E-06) 11.2052*1.08080.95790.94890.96371.07910.8153*1.01920.9872(0.0501)(0.0426)(0.0366)(0.0394)(0.0367)(0.0428)(0.0326)(0.0410)(0.0362) R20.18800.20460.21510.18820.21650.20230.20060.19800.2113JT16.91*4.2964.3794.0126.693*3.42240.18*0.6114.613 ThistablereportsMincer-ZarnowitzregressionresultsfromRVdt+1(h)�RVut+1(h)= 0+ 1(Vart[rt+1jrt+1mt]�Vart[rt+1jrt+1&#x-295;mt]),whereerrortermsintheparametricmodelfollowaskewedStudent-tdistribution.*indicatesrejectionofthenullhypothesisthat i=i;i=0;1atthe5%con dencelevelorbetter.JTrepresentsthevalueoftheteststatisticbuiltunderthenullhypothesisthat 0and 1arejointlyequalto0and1,respectively.*andydenotetherejectionofthisnullhypothesisatthe5and10%con dencelevels,respectively.Thecriticalvaluesforthistestare5.991and4.605,respectively,basedon2df=2.35 Table5:EstimationResultsfortheConditionalSkewnessDynamicswithSkewedGED(1) NM0M1M2M3M4M5M6M7M8 1980-2009 0-0.1347*-0.1317*-0.1355*-0.0450*-0.0764*-0.1316*-0.1370*-0.0449*-0.0997*(0.0293)(0.0270)(0.0346)(0.0150)(0.0257)(0.0268)(0.0277)(0.0150)(0.0273)1+0.1218*0.1281*0.1234*0.1717*0.1221*0.1244*0.1236*0.1944*(0.0211)(0.0402)(0.0186)(0.0393)(0.0185)(0.0293)(0.0151)(0.0305)1�0.1188*0.0948*0.1195*0.0751*(0.0314)(0.0323)(0.0129)(0.0274)20.6347*0.6226*0.6355*0.5666*(0.0830)(0.0714)(0.0799)(0.0936) 00.3199*0.3215*0.3216*0.3174*0.3168*0.3221*0.4620*0.3184*0.3730*(0.0070)(0.0071)(0.0071)(0.0071)(0.0070)(0.0225)(0.0229)(0.0573)(0.0454) 1+0.0034-0.2414*-0.0024-0.2345*(0.0186)(0.0373)(0.0216)(0.0386) 1�0.1280*0.1268*(0.0177)(0.0216) 2-0.00530.2492*(0.1669)(0.1053) LogL24639.424824.024838.724838.724848.124848.924838.724859.024848.124869.7LRStat369.20*29.40*0.00NA1.60NA40.60*NA43.20*BIC-3.2494-3.2714-3.2722-3.2710-3.2722-3.2711-3.2710-3.2713-3.2698-3.2704 1980-1989 0-0.0767-0.0525-0.0193-0.0202-0.0030-0.0419-0.0958-0.0199-0.0761(0.0513)(0.0505)(0.0695)(0.0176)(0.0294)(0.0382)(0.0724)(0.0144)(0.0392)1+0.1111*0.07170.1146*0.0881*0.0856*0.1085*0.0962*0.1565*(0.0395)(0.0559)(0.0255)(0.0241)(0.0399)(0.0430)(0.0237)(0.0421)1�0.1424*0.1263*0.02790.0334(0.0518)(0.0279)(0.0434)(0.0506)20.5797*0.5741*0.5613*0.5535*(0.1352)(0.1435)(0.1610)(0.2190) 00.3210*0.2508*0.2507*0.2527*0.2510*0.2743*0.3873*0.13480.2560*(0.0113)(0.0090)(0.0089)(0.0090)(0.0090)(0.0377)(0.0499)(0.1313)(0.0941) 1+0.0648*-0.1384*0.0423-0.1223*(0.0290)(0.0662)(0.0259)(0.0645) 1�0.1563*0.1291*(0.0379)(0.0355) 20.50720.4137(0.4725)(0.2611) LogL8190.18290.88295.38295.68299.08299.28298.38303.68301.38305.8LRStat201.40*9.00*0.60NA0.40NA10.60*NA9.00*BIC-3.2268-3.2604-3.2591-3.2561-3.2575-3.2544-3.2572-3.2531-3.2522-3.2478 Thistablereportstheestimatedparametersof~and~asinequation(11),andwhereinnovationsfollowaskewedGED.Nrepresentsthebaselinenormallydistributederrorscase.ModelsM0toM8representequations(14)to(21),respectively.Tosavespace,wereportestimatedvaluesfor1and1+onthesamerow.Estimatedstandarderrorsarereportedinparentheses,belowtheestimatedparameters.\LogL"representsthecomputedloglikelihoodfunction.Wereportlikelihoodratioteststatistics,\LRStat,"withrespecttotheprecedingmodel.\NA"impliesthatthemodelsarenon-nested,andthustheLRteststatisticisnotcomputed.Allmodelsarepreferredtothebenchmarknormalmodel,basedonthelikelihoodratiotest.Thus,wedonotreporttheseteststatistics.*representsrejectionofthenullhypothesisinquestionatthe5%con dencelevel.\BIC"representsBayesianinformationcriteriafortheestimatedmodels.36 Table6:EstimationResultsfortheConditionalSkewnessDynamicswithSkewedGED(2) NM0M1M2M3M4M5M6M7M8 1990-1999 0-0.0767-0.0845*-0.1917*-0.0121-0.0977*-0.0827-0.1934*-0.0123-0.1486*(0.0518)(0.0462)(0.0571)(0.0182)(0.0435)(0.0469)(0.0650)(0.0097)(0.0347)1+0.1631*0.3541*0.1614*0.3099*0.1632*0.3862*0.1607*0.4361*(0.0387)(0.0571)(0.0374)(0.0722)(0.0346)(0.0673)(0.0142)(0.0385)1�0.07570.1046*0.1095*0.1175*(0.0582)(0.0381)(0.0456)(0.0282)20.7051*0.5881*0.7141*0.4931*(0.1130)(0.1464)(0.0617)(0.0656) 00.3210*0.3154*0.3218*0.2896*0.2987*0.3054*0.4211*0.5355*0.2802*(0.0123)(0.0121)(0.0124)(0.0116)(0.0117)(0.0390)(0.0512)(0.0743)(0.0592) 1+-0.0412-0.2250*-0.0459*-0.2925*(0.0388)(0.0692)(0.0212)(0.0609) 1�0.07910.1180*(0.0624)(0.0428) 2-0.8665*0.5614*(0.0555)(0.1392) LogL8628.38684.18692.98695.48699.58701.18693.48699.58702.28710.0LRStat111.60*17.60*5.00NA3.20NA12.20*NA15.60*BIC-3.3989-3.4148-3.4151-3.4131-3.4147-3.4122-3.4123-3.4085-3.4096-3.4064 2000-2009 0-0.2635*-0.2622*-0.1409-0.1136-0.1457-0.2552*-0.1326*-0.0878-0.1361(0.0492)(0.0455)(0.0767)(0.0951)(0.0924)(0.0508)(0.0661)(0.0650)(0.1137)1+0.0798-0.06950.0857-0.07130.0536-0.1378*0.0779-0.1522*(0.0451)(0.0791)(0.0478)(0.0617)(0.0668)(0.0337)(0.0615)(0.0531)1�0.2265*0.2271*0.1903*0.2181*(0.0997)(0.0922)(0.0734)(0.0667)20.5586-0.02390.6498*-0.1111(0.3577)(0.2454)(0.2383)(0.1505) 00.4713*0.4646*0.4589*0.4655*0.4588*0.4678*0.6886*0.2559*0.6867*(0.0199)(0.0197)(0.0193)(0.0197)(0.0193)(0.0418)(0.0403)(0.1258)(0.0939) 1+-0.1262*-0.4590*-0.1286*-0.4716*(0.0515)(0.0624)(0.0474)(0.0640) 1�0.2288*0.2476*(0.0297)(0.0277) 20.44270.0302(0.2648)(0.1816) LogL7866.47893.47895.07896.97895.67896.97898.17919.57899.97919.6LRStat54.00*3.203.80NA2.60NA42.80*NA39.40*BIC-3.1109-3.1154-3.1130-3.1106-3.1101-3.1075-3.1111-3.1134-3.1056-3.1072 Thistablereportstheestimationresultsforthe1990{99and2000{09subsamples.RefertothenotestoTable5formoreinformation.37 Table7:EvaluatingtheConditionalRelativeDownsideVariancewithSkewedGED M0M1M2M3M4M5M6M7M8 1980-2009 0-2.99E-06-2.36E-06-2.44E-06-9.72E-06*-7.80E-06*-2.41E-064.17E-06*-9.80E-06*2.02E-06(3.25E-06)(2.79E-06)(2.80E-06)(2.80E-06)(2.03E-06)(1.97E-06)(2.09E-06)(1.98E-06)(2.26E-06) 11.00330.97020.96140.7091*0.6974*0.96940.6680*0.7071*0.9604(0.0380)(0.0226)(0.0226)(0.0186)(0.0191)(0.0225)(0.0167)(0.0186)(0.0423) R20.10370.23520.23200.19480.18110.23590.21000.19420.1376JT0.8562.4683.698256.62*265.82*3.343399.22*273.80*0.886 1980-1989 0-1.65E-061.61E-05y1.63E-05y1.21E-066.81E-061.59E-05*3.54E-05*1.07E-063.91E-05*(1.23E-05)(8.85E-06)(8.90E-06)(9.65E-06)(6.99E-06)(6.24E-06)(6.75E-06)(6.84E-06)(1.17e-05) 10.845251.2084*1.2036*0.7324*0.7736*1.2065*0.9007*0.99281.0314(0.1094)(0.0447)(0.0450)(0.0357)(0.0391)(0.0444)(0.0358)(0.0357)(0.0311) R20.05770.42850.42260.30130.28600.43060.39300.29960.2199JT2.02125.07*23.80*56.20*34.49*28.16*32.19*0.06612.18* 1990-1999 02.58E-06-7.73E-06*-7.66E-06*-8.75E-06*-7.50E-06*-7.80E-06*-4.78E-06-8.76E-06*-1.94E-06(4.61E-06)(3.58E-06)(3.58E-06)(3.31E-06)(3.43E-06)(5.05E-06)(4.13E-06)(3.31E-06)(4.59E-06) 11.3910y0.7908y0.7889y0.7286*0.7109*0.7880*0.95370.7280*0.9849(0.2051)(0.1210)(0.1209)(0.097)(0.0970)(0.1210)(0.0950)(0.0970)(0.0690) R20.03530.03230.03270.04320.04130.03250.02590.04320.0244JT3.9467.636*7.622*14.87*13.74*7.820*1.57514.95*0.228 2000-2009 0-1.35E-06-1.17E-05*-1.19E-05*-1.56E-05*-1.58E-05*-1.18E-05*-6.39E-06-1.57E-05*-8.05E-06(5.24E-06)(4.89E-06)(4.90E-06)(4.85E-06)(4.92E-06)(4.89E-06)(5.13E-06)(4.85E-06)(5.34E-06) 11.09320.7952*0.7859*0.6909*0.6314*0.7942*1.05120.91560.9531(0.0705)(0.0500)(0.0500)(0.0460)(0.0440)(0.0500)(0.0517)(0.0465)(0.0520) R20.16120.16540.16360.15490.14140.16530.15350.15480.1606JT1.81422.22*24.14*56.33*80.56*22.49*3.50513.89*3.085 ThistablereportsMincer-ZarnowitzregressionresultsfromRVdt+1(h)�RVut+1(h)= 0+ 1(Vart[rt+1jrt+1mt]�Vart[rt+1jrt+1&#x-295;mt]),whereerrortermsintheparametricmodelfollowaskewedStudent-tdistribution.*indicatesrejectionofthenullhypothesisthat i=i;i=0;1atthe5%con dencelevelorbetter.JTrepresentsthevalueoftheteststatisticbuiltunderthenullhypothesisthat 0and 1arejointlyequalto0and1,respectively.*andydenotetherejectionofthisnullhypothesisatthe5and10%con dencelevels,respectively.Thecriticalvaluesforthistestare5.991and4.605,respectively,basedon2df=2.38 Table8:EstimationResultsfortheConditionalSkewnessDynamicswithBinormalDistribu-tion NM0M1M2M3M4 1980-2009 0-0.2435*-0.1853*-0.1989*-0.0955*-0.1127*(0.0329)(0.0299)(0.0438)(0.0237)(0.0380)1+0.2055*0.2342*0.1819*0.2143*(0.0272)(0.0729)(0.0252)(0.0607)1�0.1948*0.1687*(0.0375)(0.0338)20.4187*0.4128*(0.0960)(0.0953) LogL24639.424667.024692.324692.424697.824698.1LRStat55.20*50.60*0.20NA0.60BIC-3.2494-3.2530-3.2552-3.2540-3.2547-3.2536 1980-1989 0-0.2022*-0.1182*-0.0595-0.0689*0.0071(0.0543)(0.0482)(0.0766)(0.0306)(0.0543)1+0.2709*0.15560.2291*0.0922(0.0436)(0.1211)(0.0400)(0.0910)1�0.3230*0.2883*(0.0758)(0.0633)20.3750*0.4270*(0.1203)(0.1180) LogL8190.18197.58213.78214.28216.78218.0LRStat14.80*32.40*1.00NA2.60BIC-3.2268-3.2296-3.2330-3.2301-3.2311-3.2285 1990-1999 0-0.2211*-0.1529*-0.3460*-0.0864-0.2925*(0.0579)(0.0524)(0.0799)(0.0446)(0.0880)1+0.2079*0.6721*0.1861*0.5903*(0.0440)(0.1424)(0.0432)(0.1516)1�0.06260.0683(0.0712)(0.0658)20.36430.1669(0.2108)(0.1573) LogL8628.38635.78644.78649.88646.08650.4LRStat14.80*18.00*10.20*NA8.80*BIC-3.3989-3.4018-3.4023-3.4012-3.3997-3.3983 2000-2009 0-0.3209*-0.3029*-0.1736-0.1140-0.1826(0.0618)(0.0593)(0.0947)(0.0855)(0.1288)1+0.0881-0.12790.0919-0.1307(0.0640)(0.1402)(0.0556)(0.1451)1�0.2270*0.2279*(0.1026)(0.1034)20.5806*-0.0325(0.2780)(0.3113) LogL7866.47879.67880.67882.17881.37882.1LRStat26.40*2.003.00NA1.60BIC-3.1109-3.1162-3.1135-3.1109-3.1106-3.1078 Thistablereportstheestimatedparametersof~,where~=�ln[p =2�1+1]andinnovationsfollowabinormaldistribution.Nrepresentsthebaselinenormallydistributederrorscase.ModelsM0toM4representequations(14)to(17),respectively.Tosavespace,wereportestimatedvaluesfor1and1+onthesamerow.Estimatedstandarderrorsarereportedinparentheses,belowtheestimatedparameters.\LogL"representsthecomputedloglikelihoodfunction.Wereportlikelihoodratioteststatistics,\LRStat,"withrespecttotheprecedingmodel.\NA"impliesthatthemodelsarenon-nested,andthustheLRteststatisticisnotcomputed.Allmodelsarepreferredtothebenchmarknormalmodel,basedonthelikelihoodratiotest.Thus,wedonotreporttheseteststatistics.*representsrejectionofthenullhypothesisinquestionatthe5%con dencelevel.\BIC"representsBayesianinformationcriteriafortheestimatedmodels.39 Table9:EvaluatingtheConditionalRelativeDownsideVarianceforBinormalDistribution M0M1M2M3M4 1980-2009 0-2.30E-06-1.06E-05*-1.09E-05*-1.36E-05*-1.35E-05*(3.13E-06)(2.66E-06)(2.67E-06)(2.72E-06)(1.93E-06) 11.5177*1.13171.11990.9262*0.9371(0.0502)(0.0849)(0.0752)(0.0229)(0.0435) R20.13200.25490.24740.21330.2096JT107.11*18.03*19.19*35.17*50.93* 1980-1989 05.70E-06-9.84E-06-1.05E-05-1.06E-05-1.30E-05(1.11E-05)(8.08E-06)(7.86E-06)(9.04E-06)(6.53E-06) 12.0913*1.2928*1.2435*0.98600.7991*(0.1570)(0.0423)(0.0386)(0.0419)(0.0362) R20.15370.48840.51480.36200.3334JT48.58*49.38*41.57*1.48834.86* 1990-1999 09.24E-07-1.44E-05*-1.85E-05*-1.34E-05*-1.79E-05*(4.24E-06)(3.10E-06)(2.93E-06)(3.07E-06)(2.09E-06) 12.2048*0.85650.5137*0.94371.1143(0.2150)(0.1029)(0.0806)(0.0975)(0.0856) R20.04010.02680.01580.03590.0182JT31.46*23.52*76.39*19.43*75.47* 2000-2009 0-1.26E-06-3.28E-06-5.06E-06-6.55E-06-4.97E-06(5.05E-06)(4.90E-06)(4.76E-06)4.88E-06(3.36E-06) 11.1713*1.07190.99810.93951.0034(0.0485)(0.0424)(0.0374)(0.0385)(0.0374) R20.18880.20370.22170.19190.2231JT12.54*3.3271.1344.2702.192 ThistablereportsMincer-ZarnowitzregressionresultsfromRVdt+1(h)�RVut+1(h)= 0+ 1(Vart[rt+1jrt+1mt]�Vart[rt+1jrt+1&#x-295;mt]),whereerrortermsintheparametricmodelarebinormallydistributed.*indicatesrejectionofthenullhypothesisthat i=i;i=0;1atthe5%con dencelevelorbetter.JTrepresentsthevalueoftheteststatisticbuiltunderthenullhypothesisthat 0and 1arejointlyequalto0and1,respectively.*andydenotetherejectionofthisnullhypothesisatthe5and10%con dencelevels,respectively.Thecriticalvaluesforthistestare5.991and4.605,respectively,basedon2df=2.40