/
14.1 	 Competitive Factor Markets 14.1 	 Competitive Factor Markets

14.1 Competitive Factor Markets - PowerPoint Presentation

tracy
tracy . @tracy
Follow
66 views
Uploaded On 2023-10-31

14.1 Competitive Factor Markets - PPT Presentation

142 Equilibrium in a Competitive Factor Market 143 Factor Markets with Monopsony Power 144 Factor Markets with Monopoly Power C H A P T E R 14 Prepared by Fernando Quijano Illustrator ID: 1027680

demand labor marginal wage labor demand wage marginal curve market product supply factor competitive revenue rate firm input price

Share:

Link:

Embed:

Download Presentation from below link

Download Presentation The PPT/PDF document "14.1 Competitive Factor Markets" is the property of its rightful owner. Permission is granted to download and print the materials on this web site for personal, non-commercial use only, and to display it on your personal computer provided you do not modify the materials and that you retain all copyright notices contained in the materials. By downloading content from our website, you accept the terms of this agreement.


Presentation Transcript

1. 14.1 Competitive Factor Markets14.2 Equilibrium in a Competitive Factor Market14.3 Factor Markets with Monopsony Power14.4 Factor Markets with Monopoly PowerC H A P T E R 14Prepared by:Fernando Quijano, IllustratorMarkets for Factor InputsCHAPTER OUTLINE

2. Competitive Factor Markets14.1Demand for a Factor Input When Only One Input Is Variable● marginal revenue product Additional revenue resulting from the sale of output created by the use of one additional unit of an input.How do we measure the MRPL? It’s the additional output obtained from the additional unit of this labor, multiplied by the additional revenue from an extra unit of output.● derived demand Demand for an input that depends on, and is derived from, both the firm’s level of output and the cost of inputs.(14.1)This important result holds for any competitive factor market, whether or not the output market is competitive.In a competitive output market, a firm will sell all its output at the market price P. In this case, the marginal revenue product of labor is equal to the marginal product of labor times the price of the product:(14.2)  

3. MARGINAL REVENUE PRODUCTFIGURE 14.1In a competitive factor market in which the producer is a price taker, the buyer’s demand for an input is given by the marginal revenue product curve. The MRP curve falls because the marginal product of labor falls as hours of work increase. When the producer of the product has monopoly power, the demand for the input is also given by the MRP curve. In this case, however, the MRP curve falls because both the marginal product of labor and marginal revenue fall.

4. Note that the marginal revenue product tells us how much the firmshould be willing to pay to hire an additional unit of labor.As long as the MRPL is greater than the wage rate, the firm should hire more labor.If the marginal revenue product is less than the wage rate, the firm should lay off workers.The profit-maximizing condition is therefore(14.3) 

5. HIRING BY A FIRM IN THE LABOR MARKET(WITH FIXED CAPITAL)FIGURE 14.2In a competitive labor market, a firm faces a perfectly elastic supply of labor SL and can hire as many workers as it wants at a wage rate w*.The firm’s demand for labor DL is given by its marginal revenue product of labor MRPL.The profit-maximizing firm will hire L* units of labor at the point where the marginal revenue product of labor is equal to the wage rate.

6. A SHIFT IN THE SUPPLY OF LABORFIGURE 14.3When the supply of labor facing the firms is S1, the firm hires L1 units of labor at wage w1.But when the market wage rate decreases and the supply of labor shifts to S2, the firm maximizes its profit by moving along the demand for labor curve until the new wage rate w2 is equal to the marginal revenue product of labor. As a result, L2 units of labor are hired.

7. (14.4)Factor markets are similar to output markets in many ways. For example, the factor market profit-maximizing condition that the marginal revenue product of labor be equal to the wage rate is analogous to the output market condition that marginal revenue be equal to marginal cost.Recall that MRPL = (MPL)(MR) and divide both sides of equation by the marginal product of labor. Then,Equation (14.4) shows that both the hiring and output choices of the firm follow the same rule: Inputs or outputs are chosen so that marginal revenue (from the sale of output) is equal to marginal cost (from the purchase of inputs). This principle holds in both competitive and noncompetitive markets. 

8. FIRM’S DEMAND CURVE FOR LABOR (WITH VARIABLE CAPITAL)FIGURE 14.4When two or more inputs are variable, a firm’s demand for one input depends on the marginal revenue product of both inputs.When the wage rate is $20, A represents one point on the firm’s demand for labor curve.When the wage rate falls to $15, the marginal product of capital rises, encouraging the firm to rent more machinery and hire more labor. As a result, the MRP curve shifts from MRPL1 to MRPL2, generating a new point C on the firm’s demand for labor curve.Thus A and C are on the demand for labor curve, but B is not.Demand for a Factor Input When Several Inputs Are Variable

9. The Market Demand CurveA factor input such as skilled labor is demanded by firms in many different industries. Moreover, as we move from industry to industry, we are likely to find that firms’ demands for labor (which are derived in part from the demands for the firms’ output) vary substantially. Therefore, to obtain the total market demand for labor curve, we must first determine each industry’s demand for labor, and then add the industry demand curves horizontally.The second step is straightforward. Adding industry demand curves for labor to obtain a market demand curve for labor is just like adding individual product demand curves to obtain the market demand curve for that product.

10. THE INDUSTRY DEMAND FOR LABORFIGURE 14.5The demand curve for labor of a competitive firm, MRPL1 in (a), takes the product price as given. But as the wage rate falls from $15 to $10 per hour, the product price also falls. Thus the firm’s demand curve shifts downward to MRPL2. As a result, the industry demand curve, shown in (b), is more inelastic than the demand curve that would be obtained if the product price were assumed to be unchanged.DETERMINING INDUSTRY DEMAND

11. EXAMPLE 14.1THE DEMAND FOR JET FUELJet fuel costs have been highly volatile duringthe past several decades. Understanding thedemand for jet fuel is important to managers ofboth oil refineries and airlines.The price elasticity of demand for jet fueldepends both on the ability to conserve fueland on the elasticities of demand and supply of travel.Overall, the results show that the demand for jet fuel as an input to the production of airline flight-miles is very inelastic. In the short run, there is no good substitute for jet fuel. The long-run elasticity of demand is higher, however, because airlines can eventually introduce more energy-efficient airplanes.TABLE 14.1 SHORT-RUN PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND FOR JET FUELAIRLINEELASTICITYAIRLINEELASTICITY American–.06Delta–.15Continental–.09United–.10

12. EXAMPLE 14.1THE DEMAND FOR JET FUELTHE SHORT- AND LONG-RUN DEMAND FOR JET FUELFIGURE 11.6The short-run demand for jet fuel MRPSR is more inelastic than the long-run demand MRPLR. In the short run, airlines cannot reduce fuel consumption much when fuel prices increase. In the long run, however, they can switch to longer, more fuel-efficient routes and put more fuel-efficient planes into service.

13. The Supply of Inputs to a Firm● marginal expenditure curve Curve describing the additional cost of purchasing one additional unit of a good.● average expenditure curve Supply curve representing the price per unitthat a firm pays for a good.Profit maximization requires that marginal revenue product be equal to marginal expenditure:In the competitive case, the condition for profit maximization is that the price of the input be equal to marginal expenditure:(14.6)(14.5)  

14. A FIRM’S INPUT SUPPLY IN A COMPETITIVE FACTOR MARKETFIGURE 14.7In a competitive factor market, a firm can buy any amount of the input it wants without affecting the price. Therefore, the firm faces a perfectly elastic supply curve for that input. As a result, the quantity of the input purchased by the producer of the product is determined by the intersection of the input demand and supply curves. In (a), the industry quantity demanded and quantity supplied of fabric are equated at a price of $10 per yard. In (b), the firm faces a horizontal marginal expenditure curve at a price of $10 per yard of fabric and chooses to buy 50 yards.

15. The Market Supply of InputsBACKWARD-BENDING SUPP LY OF LABORFIGURE 14.8When the wage rate increases, the hours of work supplied increase initially but can eventually decrease as individuals choose to enjoy more leisure and to work less. The backward-bending portion of the labor supply curve arises when the income effect of the higher wage (which encourages more leisure) is greater than the substitution effect (which encourages more work).

16. SUBSTITUTION AND INCOME EFFECTS OF A WAGE INCREASEFIGURE 14.9When the wage rate increases from $10 to $30 per hour, the worker’s budget line shifts from PQ to RQ. In response, the worker moves from A to B while decreasing work hours from 8 to 5. The reduction in hours worked arises because the income effect outweighs the substitution effect. In this case, the supply of labor curve is backward bending.720

17. EXAMPLE 14.2LABOR SUPPLY FOR ONE- AND TWO-EARNERHOUSEHOLDSTABLE 14.2 ELASTICITIES OF LABOR SUPPLY (HOURS WORKED)GROUPHEAD’S HOURSWITH RESPECT TOHEAD’S WAGESPOUSE’S HOURSWITH RESPECT TOSPOUSE’S WAGEHEAD’S HOURSWITH RESPECT TOSPOUSE’S WAGE Unmarried males, no children.026Unmarried females, children.106Unmarried females, no children.011One-earner family, children–.078One-earner family, no children.007Two-earner family children–.002–.086–.004Two-earner family, no children–.107–.028–.059One of the most dramatic changes in the labor market in the twentieth century has been the increase in women’s participation in the labor force.One way to describe the work decisions of the various family groups is to calculate labor supply elasticities. When a higher wage rate leads to fewer hours worked, the labor supply curve is backward bending: The income effect, which encourages more leisure, outweighs the substitution effect, which encourages more work. The elasticity of labor supply is then negative.

18. Equilibrium in a Competitive Factor Market14.2LABOR MARKET EQUILIBRIUMFIGURE 14.10In a competitive labor market in which the output market is competitive, the equilibrium wage wc is given by the intersection of the demand for labor and the supply of labor curve (point A).When the producer has monopoly power, the marginal value of a worker vM is greater than the wage wM. Thus too few workers are employed. (Point B determines the quantity of labor that the firm hires and the wage rate paid.)

19. Economic RentFor a factor market, economic rent is the difference between the payments made to a factor of production and the minimum amount that must be spent to obtain the use of that factor.ECONOMIC RENTFIGURE 14.11The economic rent associated with the employment of labor is the excess of wages paid above the minimum amount needed to hire workers. The equilibrium wage is given by A, at the intersection of the labor supply and labor demand curves.Because the supply curve is upward sloping, some workers would have accepted jobs for a wage less than w*. The green-shaded area ABw* is the economic rent received by all workers.

20. LAND RENTFIGURE 14.12When the supply of land is perfectly inelastic, the market price of land is determined at the point of intersection with the demand curve. The entire value of the land is then an economic rent. When demand is given by D1, the economic rent per acre is given by s1, and when demand increases to D2, rent per acre increases to s2.

21. EXAMPLE 14.3PAY IN THE MILITARYTo deal with a shortage of skilled labor, themilitary changed its wage structure tomaintain an effective fighting force. To reducethe shortage, the military offered pay raises,reenlistment bonuses targeted at skilled jobs,and emphasis on the benefits of subsidized housing, food, medical care, education, and technical training.THE SHORTAGE OF SKILLEDMILITARY PERSONNELFIGURE 11.13When the wage w* is paid to military personnel, the labor market is in equilibrium.When the wage is kept below w*, at w0, there is a shortage of personnel because the quantity of labor demanded is greater than the quantity supplied.

22. Factor Markets with Monopsony Power14.3In some factor markets, individual buyers have buyer power that allows them to affect the prices they pay.Often this happens either when one firm is a monopsony buyer or there are only a few buyers, in which case each firm has some monopsony power.Firms with monopsony power buy large quantities and can negotiate lower prices than those charged smaller purchasers. In other cases, there might be only two or three sellers of a factor and a dozen or more buyers, but each buyer nonetheless has bargaining power—it can negotiate low prices because it makes large and infrequent purchases and can play the sellers off against each other when bargaining over price.Throughout this section, we will assume that the output market is perfectly competitive. In addition, because a single buyer is easier to visualize than several buyers who all have some monopsony power, we will restrict our attention at first to pure monopsony.

23. Monopsony Power: Marginal and Average ExpenditureMARGINAL AND AVERAGE EXPENDITUREFIGURE 14.14When the buyer of an input has monopsony power, the marginal expenditure curve lies above the average expenditure curve because the decision to buy an extra unit raises the price that must be paid for all units, not just for the last one. The number of units of input purchased is given by L*, at the intersection of the marginal revenue product and marginal expenditure curves. The corresponding wage rate w* is lower than the competitive wage wc.LC

24. Purchasing Decisions with Monopsony PowerBargaining PowerA buyer with monopsony power maximizes net benefit (utility less expenditure) from a purchase by buying up to the point where marginal value (MV) is equal to marginal expenditure:For a firm buying a factor input, MV is just the marginal revenue product of the factor MRP.(14.7)The amount of bargaining power that a buyer or seller has is determined in part by the number of competing buyers and competing sellers. But it is also determined by the nature of the purchase itself.

25. EXAMPLE 14.4MONOPSONY POWER IN THE MARKET FORBASEBALL PLAYERSIn the United States, major league baseball is exemptfrom the antitrust laws. This exemption allowedbaseball team owners (before 1975) to operate amonopsonistic cartel.Like all cartels, this one depended on an agreementamong owners. The agreement involved an annualdraft of players and a reserve clause that effectively tied each player to one team for life, thereby eliminating interteam competition for players. As a result, baseball owners had monopsony power in negotiating new contracts with their players.During the 1960s and early 1970s, baseball players’ salaries were far below the market value of their marginal products.Fortunately for the players, and unfortunately for the owners, there was a strike in 1972 followed by a lawsuit by one player and an arbitrated labor-management agreement. This process eventually led in 1975 to an agreement by which players could become free agents after playing for a team for six years.The result was an interesting experiment in labor market economics. Between 1975 and 1980, the market for baseball players adjusted to a new post-reserve clause equilibrium. The average player’s salary doubled in real terms.

26. EXAMPLE 14.5TEENAGE LABOR MARKETS AND THE MINIMUM WAGEIncreases in the national minimum wage rate (whichwas $4.50 in early 1996 and $7.20 in 2011) werecontroversial, raising the question of whether the costof any unemployment that might be generated wouldbe outweighed by the benefit of higher incomes tothose whose wages have been increased.A study of the effects of the minimum wage on employment in fast-food restaurants in New Jersey found that employment had actually increased by 13 percent after the minimum wage went up. One possibility is that restaurants responded to the higher minimum wage by reducing fringe benefits and providing less on-the-job-training.An alternative explanation for the increased New Jersey employment holds that the labor market for teenage (and other) unskilled workers is not highly competitive.There is no evidence of monopsony power in the fast-food industry. If firms do have monopsony power but the fast-food market is competitive, then the increase in the minimum wage should have no effect on the price of fast food.The analysis of the minimum wage remains hotly debated. New empirical studies should shed more light on the effects of the minimum wage.

27. Factor Markets with Monopoly Power14.4Monopoly Power over the Wage RateMONOPOLY POWER OF SELLERS OF LABORFIGURE 14.15When a labor union is a monopolist, it chooses among points on the buyer’s demand for labor curve DL. The seller can maximize the number of workers hired, at L*, by agreeing that workers will work at wage w*. The quantity of labor L1 that maximizes the rent earned by employees is determined by the intersection of the marginal revenue and supply of labor curves; union members will receive a wage rate of w1. Finally, if the union wishes to maximize total wages paid to workers, it should allow L2 union members to be employed at a wage rate of w2. At that point, the marginal revenue to the union will be zero.

28. Unionized and Nonunionized WorkersWAGE DISCRIMINATION IN UNIONIZED AND NONUNIONIZED SECTORSFIGURE 14.16When a monopolistic union raises the wage in the unionized sector of the economy from w* to wU, employment in that sector falls, as shown by the movement along the demand curve DU. For the total supply of labor, given by SL, to remain unchanged, the wage in the nonunionized sector must fall from w* to wNU, as shown by the movement along the demand curve DNU.

29. EXAMPLE 14.6THE DECLINE OF PRIVATE-SECTOR UNIONISMFor several decades, the membership of labor unions has been declining. As we moved into the 21st century the rate of decline began to diminish and it has stabilized in recent years at about 12 percent. In 2010, unionization in the public sector, was 36.2 percent, and only 6.9% in the private sector.During the past two decades, a number of economic forces have led to a further narrowing of the union-nonunion wage differential. The demand for unionized employees has become increasingly elastic over time as firms have found it easier to substitute capital for skilled labor in the production process. Globalization has meant that many companies were able to organize their production processes so as to hire non-union labor, either within or outside the United States. Faced with an elastic demand for its services, unions would have little choice but to give ground on wages in order to maintain employment levels. Under substantial competitive pressure, they have agreed to maintain a two-tier wage and benefits structure.

30. EXAMPLE 14.6THE DECLINE OF PRIVATE-SECTOR UNIONISMUNION WORKERS AS A PERCENTAGE OF TOTALFIGURE 14.17The percentage of workers that are unionized has been declining steadily over the past 30 years.

31. EXAMPLE 14.7WAGE INEQUALITY REVISITEDIn Example 2.2, we explained how the rapid growth inthe demand for skilled relative to unskilled labor hasbeen partly responsible for the growing inequality in the distribution of income in the United States.As we explained, while the demand for skilled laborhas steadily increased, the supply of skilled labor hasnot grown much. Instead, it has been the supply of unskilled labor that has grown.From 1980 through the present, college graduates’ relative wages have grown. In 1963 the hourly wage of a typical college graduate was 1.5 times that of a high school graduate. By 2009, that ratio had increased to 1.95. By 2010, the median weekly salary of those with a college degree (but no further education) was $1038, whereas those with a high-school degree earned only $626. Moving beyond college to a further professional degree led to a median wage of $1610.11.Education clearly pays. Workers with more education not only receive higher salaries, but they are also much less likely to lose their jobs and become unemployed in an economic downturn. For example, in 2010 the average unemployment rate was 5.4% for those with a bachelor’s degree, and 14.9% for those who had not completed high school. Education and computer use have gone hand-in-hand to increase the demand for skilled workers.

32. EXAMPLE 14.7WAGE INEQUALITY REVISITEDEDUCATION, EARNINGS AND EMPLOYMENTFIGURE 14.18Median weekly earnings (in 2010) were much higher, and average unemployment rates were much lower, for workers with higher levels of education.