/
Intermediate Microeconomics Intermediate Microeconomics

Intermediate Microeconomics - PowerPoint Presentation

yoshiko-marsland
yoshiko-marsland . @yoshiko-marsland
Follow
519 views
Uploaded On 2017-05-13

Intermediate Microeconomics - PPT Presentation

Part I CONSUMER THEORY II Laura Sochat Constrained optimisation There are n goods consumed in quantities making up a bundle The agent income is M and the ID: 547668

good income effect price income good price effect demand consumer utility goods substitution change leisure curve quantity function demanded

Share:

Link:

Embed:

Download Presentation from below link

Download Presentation The PPT/PDF document "Intermediate Microeconomics" is the property of its rightful owner. Permission is granted to download and print the materials on this web site for personal, non-commercial use only, and to display it on your personal computer provided you do not modify the materials and that you retain all copyright notices contained in the materials. By downloading content from our website, you accept the terms of this agreement.


Presentation Transcript

Slide1

Intermediate Microeconomics

Part I

CONSUMER THEORY (II)

Laura SochatSlide2

Constrained optimisation

There

are n goods consumed in quantities

, …, making up a bundle , …, The agent income is M, and the given market prices of each good are , …, .Agent’s preferences are represented by a utility function U (i.e the agent has rational preferences).Preferences are monotonic and (generally) convex.We have seen the graphical representation of optimisation.The utility function is our objective function, and the budget set gives us the constraint, and is given by: , or

 Slide3

Optimisation with two goods

We have seen before the graphical method of solving for the optimising bundle of goods, using the tangency condition:

Let’s now look at the

Lagrangean methodObtain the F.O.C.s

 

Solve the system to find the values of

and , for which the Lagrangian is maximised, and the constraint holds.

 Slide4

Examples, and alternative method

Suppose that

represents the consumer’s income,

the price of good X, and the price of good Y. Assume that the consumer’s preferences for goods X and Y, are defined by the following utility function:Solve for the optimal bundle of X and Y, and comment on the findingsAn alternative method could be to substitute for X, or Y, within the utility function and solve for the first order condition: , also assume that , , and Given the values of 𝑃𝑥, 𝑃𝑦, and 𝐼, It is possible to solve for the optimal bundle. Slide5

Choosing between two types of taxes, using consumer theory

Assuming the original budget constraint is given by

Suppose the government wishes to raise tax revenue. Should they raise quantity

tax (on good 1)? Or income tax?Show the results in a graphThink about the limitations of this example in terms of:Uniform income taxesUniform quantity taxes Slide6

Marshallian demand functions

Solutions to the earlier maximisation problem, the optimal values for the quantity of goods consumed by the consumer can be expressed as a function of prices and income. These are demand functions such as:

Prices and income, has before, are exogenous and the consumer has no power over their values. Marshallian demand functions are homogeneous of degree zero  Slide7

Interpretation of the Lagrange Multiplier

It is interpreted as the marginal utility of an extra dollar of consumption expenditure, that is the marginal utility of income:

That is we can say that a dollar of extra income should increase the consumer’s utility by

 Slide8

Roy’s identity

Substituting for the Marshallian demands into the original utility function, we obtain an expression for the actual level of utility obtained:

This is called the indirect utility function, and has the following properties:It is non-increasing in every price, decreasing in at least one priceIncreasing in IncomeHomogeneous of degree zero in price and income Slide9

Roy’s identity- The envelop theorem

Consider the case of two goods.

Taking the total derivative of the Indirect utility function we get

that (1): Next we need to make use of two results found before:The first order conditions tell us the value of the marginal utilities, which we can use in (1) , Taking the total derivative of the budget constraint and substituting to obtain the following This gives us an important result, Roy’s Identity

 Slide10

The Envelop Theorem

More generally, the result above can be assumed, by using the envelop theorem. Consider the following maximisation problem:

The constant

is given exogenously. We can solve the problem as usual:F.O.Cs are given by

Substituting for

and

into the objective function, we obtain the value function:

 Slide11

The value function is the maximised value of our objective function. Taking the total derivative of the value function with respect to

:

Differentiating the constraint, with respect to

 

The Envelop Theorem Slide12

Expenditure minimisation

We

can find optimal decisions of our consumer using a different

approach.We can minimise the consumer’s expenditure subject to a given level of utility that the consumer must obtain The goal and the constraint have been reversed.This will be important to separate income and substitution effects.The basic set up consists again of n goods making up a bundle, and each good has a specific price. The consumer has a utility target, say , and his preferences are rationalThe consumer is choosing to solve the following problem Slide13

Expenditure minimisation solution

Solution to the expenditure minimisation problem are called

Hicksian

demand functions and take the form They are also called compensated demand, and represent the cost minimising value of each goodExample- Solve for the Hicksian demand in the case of a Cobb Douglas Utility function (where )  Slide14

Shepard’s Lemma

Remember Roy’s identity, obtained after solving for the utility maximisation problem, and using the Envelop Theorem

Shepard’s Lemma is obtained the same way, and will recover the following result. If the price of a good changes by a small amount, then demand (compensated), will also change by a small amount, therefore the increased cost of consumption will be equal to the compensated demand.

Using the expenditure function (minimised objective function), we get the following:E

 Slide15

Connecting the two results- Two sides of the same coin

From utility maximisation, we obtained the Marshallian demands, from which we can obtain the indirect utility function:

The indirect utility function tells us that utility indirectly depends on prices and Income.

It maps prices and income into maximum utilityFrom expenditure minimisation, we obtain the expenditure function, using Hicksian demands:In both cases, prices and income are given, and you choose the xs…

The constraint in the primal becomes the objective in the dual

 Slide16

Using the rational choice model to derive individual demand: A

change in the price of one good.

Remember the demand curve we have seen before, giving us relationship between the price of a good and the quantity demanded of that good.

Price (P)Quantity demandedABDemandSlide17

Using the rational choice model to derive individual

demand: A

change in the price of one good.

Price (P)Quantity demandedThe price consumption curve

Changing the price of good X, we obtain different budget lines-Using rational consumer

theory, we

can find the optimal bundles corresponding to the different budget line and

obtain

the price-consumption curve by linking them

Price of fish

Quantity demanded

4

22

6

15

12

7Slide18

Using the rational choice model to derive individual

demand: A

change in the price of one good.

Price (P)Quantity demanded126471522Demand curve

Price of fish

Quantity demanded

4

22

6

1512

7Slide19

Recall the effect of a change in income on the budget constraint: It leads to a shift in the budget constraint, and therefore to an increase in the feasible set.

A change in Income: The Income-Consumption curve and the Engel curve

All other goods (£)

Fish (Kg/week)The income consumption curve609012058

12

10

1520

Income

Quantity demanded

120

12

90

8

60

5

 

 

 Slide20

A change in Income: The Income-Consumption curve and the Engel curve

Income

Fish (Kg/week)

The Engel curve 60901205812

Income

Quantity demanded

12012908

60

5

 

 

 Slide21

Different types of goods

The income elasticity

tells us how quantity demanded responds to a change in income. It is given by: As income increases by 1%, quantity demanded increases by ξ%. A good is said to be normal, if ξ>0, the quantity demanded of a normal good increases (decreases) as income increases decreases) A good is said to be inferior, if ξ<0, the quantity demanded of an inferior good decreases (increases) as income increases (decreases)A good is said to be a luxury good if ξ>1A good is said to be a necessary good if ξ<1 Slide22

Income elasticities and Income consumption curves

 

 

  

 

Assume income increases; The budget constraint shifts to the right.

: Both goods are normal, quantity demanded of both goods has increased following the increase in income

:

is a normal good, while

is inferior. Quantity demanded of good 2 has fallen following the increase in income : Good 2 in normal, while good 1 is inferior.

 Slide23

Difference preferences: What would the Engel curves look like?

Perfect substitutes

Perfect complements

Homothetic preferencesQuasilinear preferences Slide24

The Engel curve when one of the good is both normal and inferior

All other goods (£)

X

The income consumption curve  

 

 

 

 

The Engel curve

Income

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

From

to

, the increase in income lead the consumer to demand more of X.

From

to

, however, the increase in income lead the consumer to demand less of X.

 

The income consumption curve

The Engel curve

 

 

 

 

 

 Slide25

The effect of a change in the prices of goods: The income and substitution effects

From the law of demand, we know that an increase (decrease) in the price a good leads to an decrease (increase) in the quantity demanded of that good. We can divide the total effect of a price change into two effects:

The

substitution effect refers to the change in the relative price of the good. As the price of a good rises (falls), other goods become relatively cheaper (more expensive), making them more (less) attractive to the consumer. Even if the consumer was to stay on the same indifference curve, optimisation will lead to the consumer having to equate the marginal rate of substitution to the new price ratioThe income effect refers to the change in real income from a rise (fall) in the price of one good. The consumer is now poorer (richer), leading to a change in quantity demanded. The individual cannot stay on the same indifference curve and will have to move to a new one Slide26

The income and substitution effects (Hicks) : A normal good

All other goods (£)

Fish (Kg/week)

  

All other goods (£)

Fish (Kg/week)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Substitution effect

Income effect

Assume that we compensate the consumer, by providing him with enough money to achieve the

same level of utility

than before the price of fish increased. We draw an imaginary budget constraint tangent to the old IC.Slide27

The income and substitution effects (Hicks) : An inferior good

All other goods (£)

 

  

 

 

  

 

 

All other goods (£)

 

 

 

Income effect

Substitution effect

Total effect

The income elasticity of an inferior good being negative, the income effect from a price increase will be positive, while the substitution effect is still negative.

X

XSlide28

The income and substitution

effect (Hicks) : A

giffen

good

Substitution effect

Income effect

Total effect

All other goods (£)

 

 

 

 

Suppose the price of

falls, leading to a new (rotated) BL.

being an inferior good, the substitution effect will lead to the consumer consuming more of good 1, while the income effect will lead the consumer to consume less of the good.

In this situation, the substitution effect is completely offset by the income effect.

 

 

 Slide29

How to calculate the effects?

STEP 1

Utility maximisation

Allows us to find the initial optimising bundle of goods chosen by the consumer at initial pricesSTEP 2Expenditure minimisationAllows us to maintain the level of utility fixed at initial level, while minimising expenditure at new prices STEP 3Utility maximisationAllows us to calculate the income effect from the consumer’s maximisation problem at the new set of prices Slide30

Compensated Hicksian

demand

The compensated demand is the solution obtained from the expenditure minimisation problem (subject to a fixed level of utility).

It gives us the smallest possible expenditure at the old level utility- It is often called the compensated demand, as it accounts only for the substitution effectThe own price demand curve derived before, the Marshallian demand, is the uncompensated demand curve. It accounts for both the income and the substitution effect Slide31

Compensated H

icksian

demand

The compensated Hicksian demand can be derived as shown on the graph to the left.The effect of the price change are compensated so as to force the individual to remain on the same indifference curve. Slide32

The income and substitution effects (

Slutsky

) : A normal good

All other goods (£)  

All other goods (£)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Substitution effect

Income effect

Assume that we compensate the consumer, by providing him with enough money to achieve the same

purchasing power

than before the price of fish increased. We draw an imaginary budget constraint tangent to go through the original optimal bundle.

X

XSlide33

As seen in the graph above, the ‘pivoted’ budget line represents a situation where the consumer has been compensated to ensure its purchasing power remained unchanged (at the new set of prices, the consumer can still consume the initial optimal bundle)

Consider the general situation the

price of good

changes from to How can we calculate the amount of money income needed to keep that initial bundle affordable?The substitution effect is the change in demand for a good when its price changes, and at the same time, money income is compensated.

 

An algebraic interpretation: The substitution effectSlide34

Consider still a change is the price of good

, from

to

The income effect will be the change in the demand for the good, when we change income from to , while holding the price of the good at the new level. That is:What can you say about the direction of the income effect, based on the type of good, good 1 is?What about the sign of the substitution effect? An algebraic interpretation: The Income effectSlide35

Putting the two together, we obtain the

S

lutsky

identity:

While we often see the

Slutsky

identity in terms of absolute changes, it is often useful to look at it in terms of rate of change:

 

An algebraic interpretation: The

S

lutsky

equation Slide36

Marshallian demand elasticities

The price elasticity of demand

measures the proportionate change in quantity demanded in response to a proportionate change in a good’s own price. Apart from the exception of a

Giffen good, the own price elasticity of demand is always negative. Cross price elasticity of demand, , measures the proportionate change in quantity demanded in response to a proportionate change in the price of some other good

 Slide37

Application: Labor-Leisure choice

Consider a consumer choosing how to spend his time. He has a choice between working, and consuming leisure (N).

The consumer spends his total income on a variety of goods (a composite good) which costs £1 per unit.

How many goods the consumer buys depends on how much he earns; so does the cost the leisure. When the consumer isn’t working, he is losing earnings. The consumer’s utility depends on how many goods he buys, and how many hours he spends not working (consuming leisure) The consumer’s total income is given by : Where represents hourly wage Slide38

24

0

0

24

Work hours per day

Leisure hours per day

Time constraint

Composite good per day (£)

 

 

At point A, the consumer’s optimal choice is to consume 16 hours of leisure, and work for 8 hours.

 

Application: Labor-Leisure choice

The slope of the budget constraint is given by -

, the price of one extra unit of leisure is an hour of foregone earnings working.

 Slide39

24

0

0

24

Work hours per day

Leisure

hours per dayComposite good per day (£)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Time constraint

Wage per hour (£)

Demand for leisure

 

 

 

Application: Labor-Leisure choice

 

 

 

We can now derive a demand curve for leisure. Increasing the wage from

to

, we obtain a new rotated budget constraint and a new optimal bundle of work and leisure (12, 12).

 Slide40

 

Wage per hour (£)

Demand for leisure

  

 

 

 Application: Labor-Leisure choice

Wage per hour (£)

 

 

Supply of labor

 

 

 

 Slide41

Application: Labor-Leisure choice – Income and substitution effects

0

24

Work hours per day

Leisure

hours per day

 Time constraint

Income effect

Substitution effect

Total effect

Composite good per day (£)

A

B

C

From A to B is the substitution effect: At the higher wage, leisure is now more expensive. The consumer will substitute leisure for work.

From B to C is the income effect, with the now higher wage, the consumer consumes more leisure.

What does this tell you about leisure?

What would happen if leisure becomes an inferior good after the wage increases above a certain threshold?