/
Q:=0@�210(p1;p2)�(10(p1;p2)+12(p1;p2))12(p1;p2)20(p1;p2)21(p1 Q:=0@�210(p1;p2)�(10(p1;p2)+12(p1;p2))12(p1;p2)20(p1;p2)21(p1

Q:=0@2 10(p1;p2)(10(p1;p2)+12(p1;p2))12(p1;p2)20(p1;p2)21(p1 - PDF document

luanne-stotts
luanne-stotts . @luanne-stotts
Follow
370 views
Uploaded On 2016-07-13

Q:=0@2 10(p1;p2)(10(p1;p2)+12(p1;p2))12(p1;p2)20(p1;p2)21(p1 - PPT Presentation

1 0 2 10p1p2 20p1p2 12p1p2 21p1p2 Figure1MarkovchainmodelofthecustomersswitchingbehaviourFigure2FromstandardMarkovchainanalysisthesteadystateprobabilitiesforeachofthethreestatesgr ID: 402426

1 0 2 10(p1;p2) 20(p1;p2) 12(p1;p2) 21(p1;p2) Figure1:Markovchainmodelofthecustomer'sswitchingbehaviourFigure2.FromstandardMarkovchainanalysis thesteady-stateprobabilitiesforeachofthethreestatesgr

Share:

Link:

Embed:

Download Presentation from below link

Download Pdf The PPT/PDF document "Q:=0@2 10(p1;p2)(10(p1;p2)+12(p1;..." is the property of its rightful owner. Permission is granted to download and print the materials on this web site for personal, non-commercial use only, and to display it on your personal computer provided you do not modify the materials and that you retain all copyright notices contained in the materials. By downloading content from our website, you accept the terms of this agreement.


Presentation Transcript

Q:=0@�2 10(p1;p2)�(10(p1;p2)+12(p1;p2))12(p1;p2)20(p1;p2)21(p1;p2)�(20(p1;p2)+21(p1;p2))1A:Figure2:InnitesimalgeneratoroftheMarkovchainmeansthatthecustomeriswithprovider1,state2thatheiswithprovider2andstate0thathedoesnotuseanyservice.Theparameter isaconstantrateindependentofprices.TheresultinginnitesimalgeneratorQisgivenin 1 0 2 10(p1;p2) 20(p1;p2) 12(p1;p2) 21(p1;p2) Figure1:Markovchainmodelofthecustomer'sswitchingbehaviourFigure2.FromstandardMarkovchainanalysis,thesteady-stateprobabilitiesforeachofthethreestatesgroupedintherowvector=(i)i=0;:::;2existandaregivenbythesolutionofequationsQ=0;2Xi=0i=1:Ifc= (212(p1;p2)+221(p1;p2)+10(p1;p2)+20(p1;p2))+10(p1;p2)21(p1;p2)+20(p1;p2)12(p1;p2)+10(p1;p2)20(p1;p2);wehave0=10(p1;p2)21(p1;p2)+10(p1;p2)20(p1;p2) c+12(p1;p2)20(p1;p2) c1=(20(p1;p2)+212(p1;p2)) c2= (10(p1;p2)+221(p1;p2)) c:III.NON-COOPERATIVEGAMEFROMTHEPROVIDERS'SIDETheprevioussectiondescribesthebehaviourofacustomerasafunctionofpricessetbyproviders.Thequestionisnowtodenethebestpricingstrategyforeachproviderknowingthatbehaviour.Wethereforehaveaso-calledStackelberggame[9],withleaders(theproviders)choosingtheirpricesknowingtheconsequencestheywouldhaveonusers'behaviour,andthefollowers(theusers)whosereactionisadirectconsequenceofproviders'prices.Thismeansthatprovidersplayrst,butusingbackwardinduction,theyanticipatetheresultingstrategyofenduserswhoactuallymakethelastmove.Itisimportanttostressthatourmodel,consideringasinglecustomerinfrontoftwoproviders,issufcientifassumingthateachuserhasabehaviourindependentofothers'.ThecaseofNuserscanthenindeedbeeasilyderivedbymultiplyingtheexpectedrevenuebyN(thankstotheindependence).IntherststepoftheStackelberggame,eachprovidertriestomaximizeitsrevenue.Thereisatrade-offtobeanalyzedbetweenthefactthatincreasingthepricewillincreasetherevenuepercustomer,butontheotherhandpotentiallyreducethenumberofcustomers(i.e.,theprobabilityofhavingtheuserascustomerinourcase).TherevenuepercustomerRiforprovideri2f1;2gisthereforeexpressedformallyasthepricechargedmultipliedbytheprobabilitythatthiscustomersisindeedwithprovideri,i.e.,Ri=pii8i2f1;2g,ormoreexactlyusingtheexpressionsforthesteady-stateprobabilitiesoftheMarkovchain:R1(p1;p2)=p1 (20(p1;p2)+212(p1;p2)) cR2(p1;p2)=p2 (10(p1;p2)+221(p1;p2)) c:Fromthoseexpressions,itisclearthattherevenueofaproviderdependsonthepricestrategyoftheconcurrent.Indeed,steady-stateprobabilitiesarefunctionsofrateswhichthemselvesdependonbothprices.Asaconsequence,thiststheframeworkofnon-cooperativegametheory[9].Eachproviderstrivestonditsbeststrategy,i.e.,itspricemaximiz-ingitsrevenue,whichcanbemodiedbythestrategyofthecompetitor.ThesolutionconceptisthatofaNashequilibrium:aNashequilibriumisapriceprole(p1;p2)suchthatnoprovidercanunilaterallyincreaseitsrevenue,i.e.,R1(p1;p2)=maxp10R1(p1;p2)andR2(p1;p2)=maxp20R2(p1;p2):IngeneraltheexistenceofaNashequilibriumcannotbeen-suredwithoutassumptions,noritsuniquenesswhenexistenceisshown.Inthecasewhereratefunctionsaresimpleenoughintermsofprices,wemayndtheformoftheNashequilibriaanalytically(seenextsection).Otherwise,thecomputationscanbeperformednumericallyusingthefollowingalgorithm.Wedenethebestresponseofeachproviderasafunctionof providedthosevaluesarepositive.AtmostoneNashequilib-riumwithstrictlypositivepricesispossibleinthatcase.V.NUMERICALRESULTSA.ChurnratesandpricesintheliteratureInSectionIIthetransitionratesthatmarkthepassagefromaprovidertotheotherareshowntodependonthepricesofferedbytheprovidersandSectionIVillustratesthat,inverysimpliedcases,theNashequilibriumcanbeobtainedanalytically,thoughnoteasily.Inordertoadoptamodelascloseaspossibletoreality,webrieyreviewtherelatedliteratureonthemathematicalrelationshipbetweenchurnratesandpricesinthissub-section,thatwhichwillbeadoptedduringournumericalanalysis.Signicanteffortshavebeenspenttoidentifythemostrelevantfactorsindeterminingchurn(oftennamedchurndeterminants).Inordertomodeltherelationshipbetweenpricesandchurnratesinaquantitativefashionbothparametricandnon-parametricapproacheshavebeenproposedintheliterature.Amongthenon-parametricapproacheswecancite[10],whereneuralnetworksanddecisiontreesareemployed,and[11]whereanovelevolutionarylearningalgorithmisproposed.Sinceweneedaclosedformrelationshipherewearemoreinterestedinparametricapproaches.Themostwidespreadmodeladoptedintheliteraturetorepresentthatrelationshipisthelogitmodel,whichemploysalogisticprobabilitydistributionfunction[12][13][14].Theargumentofthelogisticfunctionisalinearfunctionofanumberofchurndeterminants.Themostgeneralexpressionoftheprobabilitythatauserchurnsinthenextperiod(e.g.,ayearasin[12])isthenPchurn=1 1+e�I;(5)whereIisthelogitfactor,inturngivenbyI=nXi=1 iXi;(6)whereXi,i=1;:::;naretheexplanatoryvariables(churndeterminants)and i,i=1;:::;n,arethecoefcientsrepresentingtherelativeimportanceofthosedeterminants.Inthispaperwehavefocussedonthepricefactor,sothatwecangrouptheimpactoftheotherchurndeterminantsintheoverallterm ,arrivingatthesimplerexpressionPchurn=1 1+ e� p1=p2(7)fortheprobabilitythatinthespeciedperiodtheuserswitchesfromProvider1toProvider2.Wemayemploythatexpressionforatimeperiodofanyduration,sowecanadoptitintheMarkovchainmodeldescribedinSectionII.Wenotethat,accordingtoexpression(7),thereisanonzeroprobability,namelyPchurn=1 1+ ,thattheuserswitchesproviderduetotheensembleofotherdissatisfactionfactors,evenwhentheserviceofferedbythelosingproviderisfree.B.TransitionratesThetransitionratesthatweconsidernowarechosentoreecttheconclusionsoftheprevioussubsection.However,thedataandconclusionsdrawnfromtheliteraturedonotprovideuswithacompletedescriptionofallthetransitionratesweneed,inparticularthestatewhereusersdonotsubscribetotheserviceisnotencompassedinpreviousresults.Moreover,theliteratureconsidersdiscretizedtime,whereaswefocushereonacontinuous-timemodel.ThatlatterdifcultyisaddressedherebyassumingthattimeperiodsconsideredinSubsectionV-A,areshortwithrespecttothemeansojourntimeinagivenstate.Thisimpliesthatthediscretetimetransitionprobabilitiesareapproximatelythecontinuous-timetransitionratesmultipliedbytheperiodduration.Consequently,wewouldliketoconsidertransitionratesfromstatei2f1;2gtostatej2f1;2gnfigoftheform 1+ ie� pi=pj;where�0representstheinverseoftheperiodduration.Since representstheusersensitivitytoprices,weconsideritisthesameforthedifferentstatesofthemodel.However,suchanexpressionwouldimplythatalltransitionratesbeinaninterval[=(1+ i);]regardlessofthepricevalues.Thisisnotrealistic,sinceitwouldimplythataprovidercouldensureanarbitrarilylargerevenuebysettingaverylargeprice.Wethereforeneedthatthetransitionratestoaprovideritendto0and/orthattheratesfromprovideritendto1,whenpi!1.Tothatend,weslightlymodifythepreviousexpression,andtaketransitionratesoftheformij(pi;pj)= ie� pi=pj= ie pi=pj;(8)Weintroduceasymmetryamongprovidersthroughthepa-rameter i:asexplainedbefore,thisparameterencompassesthereasonsotherthanprice(e.g.,QualityofService,reputa-tion,...),whyausershouldleavestatei.Weproposetoaddresstheformerdifculty(nohintsregardingthetransitionsto/fromourstate0)byconsideringthatbeinginstate0correspondstoperceivingacostp0,thatreectstheinconveniencefornotbenettingfromtheservice.Wethereforetreatstate0asthetwootherstates,butconsideringp0asaxedvalueinsteadofastrategicvariable.Asaresult,thetransitionrateweconsiderfromanystatei2f0;1;2gtostatej2f0;1;2gnfigisgivenby(8).Themodelparametersthatweconsiderarethen:theusersensitivitytoprice ,thelikeliness itostayincurrentstatei,i=0;1;2,theinverseofperiodduration(thisparametershouldnotplayaroleinourmodel,sincebyatimeunitchangewecanassume=1),theuserperceivedcostp0fornotbenettingfromtheservice.C.NumericalanalysisofthegameInthissubsection,wesuggesttostudythegamewhileconsideringthepreviousexpressionsofthetransitionrates.Thedependenceofthoseratesonproviderpricesaretoocomplicatedtosolvetheproblemanalytically,thereforewe 0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5 Provider1pricep1 Provider2pricep2 BR1(p2) BR2(p1) Figure7:Best-replycurvesofbothproviderswhen 2=7(otherparametervaluestakenfromS).verybeginningofthosetechnologies.Ontheotherhand,someservices/technologiescanlosevaluebecausetheygetabandonedorcanbereplacedbyotherones.Serviceswithhigherimportance/impactcanthereforebemodeledbyalargerp0Forthosereasons,weinvestigatenowtheeffectoftheno-servicecostp0ontheoutcomesofthegame.Weassumethatthevariationsofp0areonalongertimescalethanthegameonpricesanduserbehavior,sothatwestillcomputetheNashequilibriumofthepricinggameasdescribedintheprevioussubsection.Figure8plotstheNashequilibriumprices(p1;p2)versusp0,whilethecorrespondinguserrepartitionatsteady-stateisplottedinFigure9.Weremarkthatthesteady-statedistribu-tion(again,atNashequilibriumdependingonp0)isalmostconstantwhenp0varies,andequilibriumpricesincreaseclosetolinearlywithp0.Therefore,ifprovidersareawareofanincreaseinp0,theyshouldraisetheirpricescorrespondinglytobenetfromtheincreasedvalueoftheservice.Interestingly,thispriceincreasecompensatestheservicevalueincreasefromthepointofviewoftheusers,sincetheproportionofuserschoosingtheserviceornotisunchanged.E.Inuenceofthepricesensitivity Westudyheretheeffectoftheparameter ,thatrepre-sentedusers'sensitivitiestopricedifferencesbetweenthedifferentstatesoftheMarkovchain.When increases,weexpectproviderstodecreasetheirpricessoastoattractmoreefcientlyamaximumofcustomers.TheNashequilibriumprices(p1;p2)when variesareshowninFigure10.WegivethecorrespondinguserrepartitionandproviderrevenuesinFigure11and12,respectively.Itappearsthatwhenthepricesensitivityexceedsagiventhreshold(thatisaround0:85),providersengageinapricewarthatmakestheirprice 0 20 40 60 80 100 0 50 100 150 200 250 300 Costp0 Serviceprices p1 p2 Figure8:Nashequilibriumpriceswhentheno-servicecostp0varies. 0 20 40 60 80 100 0 0:1 0:2 0:3 0:4 0:5 0:6 Costp0 Userrepartition d1 d2 d0 Figure9:UserrepartitionatNashequilibriumwhentheno-servicecostp0varies.tendto0,andtheynallygetnorevenuefromprovidingtheservice.Thisbenetsuserswhoallendupwithoneofthetwoproviders.Belowthatthreshold,anincreasedpricesensitivityalreadyimpliesaproviderpricereduction,andarevenuedecreaseforthem.Remarkalsothatprovider2,beingmoreattractivethanitsopponent(since 2� 1inourparametervalues),takesbenetofthatadvantagebysettinghigherprices.F.InuenceoftheasymmetrybetweenprovidersInourmodel,providersonlydifferfortheirparameter i,thatreectstheuserlikelinesstostaywithhim:from(8),alarger imeanslowertransitionratestotheotherstatesoftheMarkovchain.Thatasymmetrybetweenprovidersmayforexamplecomefromusersbeingmorereluctanttoleave

Related Contents


Next Show more