/
2THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEWMONTHYEARHelpman(1991),ourmodelcharacterizes 2THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEWMONTHYEARHelpman(1991),ourmodelcharacterizes

2THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEWMONTHYEARHelpman(1991),ourmodelcharacterizes - PDF document

min-jolicoeur
min-jolicoeur . @min-jolicoeur
Follow
388 views
Uploaded On 2015-11-12

2THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEWMONTHYEARHelpman(1991),ourmodelcharacterizes - PPT Presentation

4THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEWMONTHYEARFurthermoreinourmodeltheprocessoftechnologicaldiversi cationtakesplacewithinthe rmnotacross rmsFinallyourresultsdonothingeon nancialdevelopmentThesetheoreticald ID: 191148

4THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEWMONTHYEARFurthermore inourmodeltheprocessoftechnologicaldiversi cationtakesplacewithinthe rm notacross rms:Finally ourresultsdonothingeon nancialdevelopment.Thesetheoreticald

Share:

Link:

Embed:

Download Presentation from below link

Download Pdf The PPT/PDF document "2THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEWMONTHYEARHelpm..." is the property of its rightful owner. Permission is granted to download and print the materials on this web site for personal, non-commercial use only, and to display it on your personal computer provided you do not modify the materials and that you retain all copyright notices contained in the materials. By downloading content from our website, you accept the terms of this agreement.


Presentation Transcript

2THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEWMONTHYEARHelpman(1991),ourmodelcharacterizestechnologicalprogressasanexpansioninthenumberofinputvarieties.Thenumberofvarietiesevolvesendogenouslyinresponsetoproducers'incentivestoaddtotherangeofinputstheyuse,andincreasesinthenumberofvarietiesraisetheaveragelevelofproductivity.Ourcontributionistomakethemodelstochastic,sothatitcanbeusedtostudyitsimplicationsforoutputvolatility.Inparticular,weassumethateachvari-etycanbea ectedbyaproductivityshock;thustheexpansioninthenumberofvarietiescanprovidediversi cationbene ts,andhencereducethelevelofvolatilityoftheeconomy.1Inotherwords,thereductioninvolatilityarisesasalikelyby-productof rms'incentivestoincreaseproductivity.Assuch,ourmodelhighlightsahithertooverlookedimplicationofexpanding-varietygrowthmodels,whichmakesthemsuitabletoexplainthedeclineinvolatilitythataccompaniesthedevelopmentprocess.Wesay\suitabletoexplain"because,interestingly,oncetechnologicaldiver-si cationisembeddedinanendogenousgrowthmodelwithmultiple rms,itispossibletogenerateexampleswherevolatilityanddevelopmentdonotnecessarilymoveinoppositedirections.Thishappens,forexample,ifasigni cantnumberof rmsadoptsaninputthatisalreadywidelyusedbyother rms;theeconomyasawholemaythenbecomehighlytechnologicallyconcentratedandhenceexposedtoshockstothatparticularinput,leadingtoepisodicsurgesinvolatility|higherproductivityinthiscasecancomeatthecostofhighervolatility.Inpractice,however,developmentandvolatilitymoveinoppositedirectionsmostofthetime,andthisisindeedthecaseinvirtuallyallournumericalexperiments.Thisoc-cursbecausetheintroductionofanewvarietyintheeconomyalwaysincreasesthelevelofdevelopment,andraisesthedegreeoftechnologicaldiversi cationbyreducingthecontributiontooutputofpreviouslyexistingvarieties(thusloweringvolatility).Acalibratedversionofthemodelcanyieldadeclineinvolatilitywithdevelopmentquantitativelycomparabletothatinthedata.Asimpleexampleofthemechanismoftechnologicaldiversi cationiso eredbyacomparisonofaneconomyusingonlylabourandaneconomyusinglabourandcapital.Understandardassumptionsontechnology,thelatterwilltendtobemoreproductiveonaper-capitabasis.Ourpointisthatitwillalsobelessvolatile.Inparticular,anyshockthatreducesthesupplyoflabour(suchasanepidemic,ageneralstrike,etc.)willhaveabiggernegativeimpactontheeconomythatdoesnothavescopetosubstitutelabourwithcapital.Or,tothinkofacurrentlymorerealisticexample,considerleading-edgesteelproducersthathavethecapacitytoprocessironoreofarangeofqualitiesascomparedtomorebasicproducerswhocanonlyaccepthigh-qualityoresasinput.Clearlytheformeraremoreproductive,and,inaddition,theyshouldbelesssusceptibletoshockstothe(globalorlocal)supplyofhigh-qualityironore.21Inputvarietiesarebroadlyconstruedtoencompassbothtangibleandintangibleinputsortechnolo-gies.Shocksarevariety-speci candtotheextentthatthevarietiesareusedbyapositivemeasureof rms,theyleadtoaggregatevolatility.2Throughoutthepaper,wefocustheanalysisonthecaseinwhichdi erentvarietiesaregross 4THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEWMONTHYEARFurthermore,inourmodeltheprocessoftechnologicaldiversi cationtakesplacewithinthe rm,notacross rms:Finally,ourresultsdonothingeon nancialdevelopment.Thesetheoreticaldi erencesleadtoimportantdi erencesinempiricalimpli-cations.First, nancialdiversi cationmodelspredictanincreasein rm-levelvolatilitywiththelevelofdevelopment,andanegativecomovementbetweenag-gregateand rm-levelvolatility.Instead,ourmodelpredictsadeclinein rm-levelvolatilitywithdevelopmentandapositivecomovementbetweenaggregateand rm-levelvolatility.Onthesetwopredictions,ourmodel ndssupportinrecentworkbyDavis,Haltiwanger,JarminandMiranda(2006),whodocumentthatintheUnitedStates,overtime,privatelyheld rmshaveexperiencedasubstan-tialdeclineinvolatility;theauthorsfurthershowthatthedeclineinaggregatevolatilityintheUnitedStateshasbeenoverwhelminglydrivenbythedeclinein rm-levelvolatility(andnotbytheaggregationofhighlyvolatile rmsexposedtoincreasinglylesscorrelatedidiosyncraticshocks).Inthenextsectionwedis-cussnewevidencefor17othercountriescon rmingthetendencyforapositivecomovementbetweenaggregateand rm-levelvolatility.Asecondtestablepredictionofmodelsof nancialdiversi cationisthatthedeclineinaggregatevolatilitywithdevelopmentisbroughtaboutby nancialdevelopment.Inourmodel,thedeclineinvolatilitytakesplaceindependentlyofthelevelof nancialdevelopment.Asweargueinthenextsection,thisimpli-cationiscorroboratedbytheevidence.Thestrongnegativecorrelationbetweenvolatilityanddevelopmenttakesplaceatalllevelsof nancialdevelopment.Putdi erently,evencontrollingforthelevelof nancialdevelopment,thereremainsastrongnegativecorrelationbetweenvolatilityanddevelopmentthatneedsexpla-nation.Whileweviewbothmarginsofdiversi cationforthe rm, nancialandtechnological,ascomplementaryandempiricallyplausible,ourmodelwillfocusexclusivelyonthesecondone.6Asmentioned,ourmodelpositsnotradeo betweenproductivityandvolatil-ityatthemicroeconomiclevel.Theabsenceofatradeo ismotivatedbythe ndingthatcountriesatearlystagesofdevelopmenttendtospecializeinlow-productivity,high-riskactivities,whereastheoppositepatternisobservedatlaterstagesofdevelopment.Moreover,evenwithinnarrowlyde nedsectors,develop-ingcountriestendtofeaturebothlowerproductivityandhighervolatilitythandevelopedcountries.(SeeKorenandTenreyro(2007)).7;8oursettingrisk-neutral rmsstillwantto\diversify"(i.e.,expandthenumberofinputsinproduction).6Technologicaldiversi cationisalsocomplementarytoother nance-relatedmechanismsemphasizedintheliterature.Inparticular,shockscanbeampli edbyintroducing nancialfrictions,ataskwedonotundertakeintheinterestofclarityandsimplicity.Formodelswith nancialfrictions,see,amongothers,BernankeandGertler(1990),KiyotakiandMoore(1997),Aghion,Angeletos,BanerjeeandManova(2010).7Thesectoralcompositionoftheeconomyalonecannotaccountforthedi erencesinvolatilitybetweendevelopedanddevelopingcountries;the\within"sectordeclineinvolatilityisatleastasimportantinexplainingvolatilitydi erencesbetweendevelopedanddevelopingeconomies(KorenandTenreyro2007).8Indepartingfromanecessarytradeo betweenproductivityandvolatility,ourpaperisclosertoKraayandVentura(2007),thoughthemechanismsaredi erent:intheirmodel,thekeyideaisthat 6THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEWMONTHYEARcontributionofthepaper,themodelismorestylizedinotherdimensionsthathavebeenemphasizedintherealbusinesscycle(RBC)ortheNewKeynesianliterature.Thepaperdoes,ontheotherhand,speaktootherregularitiesthatarenotaddressedintheRBCorNewKeynesianliterature,whichwediscussinthenextsection.Thepaperisorganizedasfollows.SectionIdocumentsasetofempiricalobser-vationsthatmotivateourmodelanddi erentiateitfromalternativeexplanations.SectionIIpresentsthemodeloftechnologicaldiversi cationandderivesitsim-plicationsforaggregatedynamics.SectionIIIpresentsaquantitativeanalysisofthemodel.SectionIVo ersconcludingremarks.TheWebAppendixprovidesadditionalevidencesupportingtheregularitiesinSectionI.Itthenpresentstheproofs,generalizesthemodel,anddiscussesitsrobustnessunderdi erentassumptions.Inparticular,itstudiestheconditionsunderwhichtechnologicaldiversi cationtakesplacewhenvarietiesaregrosscomplements,asisthecaseintheO-ringtheoryformulatedbyKremer(1993),anditworksouttheimpli-cationsofthemodelunderdi erentassumptionsregardingtechnologyandriskpreferences.I.EmpiricalMotivationThissectionpresentsthemainempiricalobservationsthatmotivatethethe-oreticalmodel,andalongwhichweshalllaterevaluateit.Italsodiscussesasetofauxiliaryempiricalresultsthatjustifythesearchfornewmodels.Intheinterestofspace,mostofthesupportingtablesand guresarereportedintheWebAppendix.A.EmpiricalObservationsEmpiricalObservation1.GDPvolatilitydeclineswithdevelopment,bothinthecrosssectionandforagivencountryovertime.Thenegativeassociationbetweenaggregatevolatilityandthelevelofdevelop-ment,notedinLucas(1988)'sseminalpaper,isoneofthestylizedfactsinthemacro-developmentliteratureandthestartingmotivationofthispaper.There-lationissummarizedinthe rstcolumnofTable1;whichreportstheresultsfromaregressionofthe(log)levelofvolatility,measuredasthestandarddeviationoftheannualgrowthrateofrealGDPpercapitaovernonoverlappingdecadesfrom1960through2007,ontheaverage(log)levelofrealGDPpercapitaofthecor-respondingdecade.ThedatacomefromthePennWorldTables(PWT,version6.3)andareadjustedforpurchasing-powerparity(PPP).Thesecondcolumndisplaystheregressionresultsaftercontrollingforcountry-speci c xede ects;itindicatesthatforagivencountryovertime,growthandchangesinvolatilityopmentareconsideredunrelatedphenomenaor,putdi erently,thelevelofdevelopmentplaysnoroleindetermining uctuations. 8THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEWMONTHYEARTable2|Firm-LevelVolatilityandSize Notes:Allvariablesareinlogs.Theequationsusethe5yearstandarddeviationofannual(real)salesgrowthratesfrom1975to2007.Thetwosizemeasures(numberofemployeesandvolumeofsales)arecomputedattheirmeanvaluesoverthelustrum.Year xede ectsincludedinallregressions.Clustered(by rm)standarderrorsinbrackets.*Signi cantat10%;**signi cantat5%;***signi cantat1%.fornonoverlapping5-yearperiodsfrom1975through2005.Thenegativecorre-lationremainsstrongevenifweinclude rm- xede ectstoconsiderwithin- rmvariationonly.InTableA1oftheWebAppendixwereportnewevidenceonthecross-sectionalrelationbetween rm-levelvolatilityandsizeforabroadgroupofcountriesatdi erentstagesofdevelopment.Thesize-volatilityrelationshipisconsistentlynegativeinallcountries.Thereisalsoevidencethattheshareofsmall rmsintheeconomy(measuredintermsofoutputoremployment)correlatesnegativelywithincomepercapitabothacrosscountries(LeidholmandMead(1987)andBanerji(1978))andwithincountriesovertime(Little,MazumdarandPage(1987)andSteel(1993)).Thiswillbethecaseinourmodel:economieswithlowerincomepercapitahaveahighershareofsmallandhighlyvolatile rms(i.e., rmsusingarelativelysmallnumberofvarieties).Aspreviouslystated,inourmodeltechnologicaldiversi cationstemsfromthediversi cationof(broadlyconstrued)inputs,notoutputs.Itishencepertinenttonotethatthedeclinein rmvolatilitywithsizeisnotdrivensimplybylarge rmsoperatinginabiggernumberofbusinesssegments;inotherwords,diversi cationinoutputalonedoesnotaccountforthenegativecorrelation.WeinvestigatethisissueintheWebAppendix,wherewecon rmthattheresultsinTable2arerobusttocontrollingforthenumberofbusinesssegmentsinwhich rmsoperateandthattheseresultsalsoholdforasampleof rmsoperatinginasinglebusinesssegment|thatis, rmswithnodiversi cationalongtheoutputdimension.EmpiricalObservation3.Firm-levelandaggregatevolatilitytendtodisplayapositivecomovement. VOL.VOLNO.ISSUETECHNOLOGICALDIVERSIFICATION9Aggregatevolatilityandthevolatilityofprivatelyowned rmstendtocomovepositively.AsshownbyDavisetal.(2006),thedeclineinaggregatevolatilityintheU.S.economythattookplacefromthemid1980suntilthemid2000shasbeenoverwhelminglydrivenbythedeclineinvolatilityofnonlisted rmsandnotbytheaggregationofincreasinglymorevolatile rmsdisplayingprogressivelylowercorrelationintheirperformance.14;15Asimilarlypositivecomovementbe-tween rm-levelandaggregatevolatilityisdocumentedforFrancebyThesmarandThoenig(2011)andforGermanybyStrotmann,DopkeandBuch(2006).IntheWebAppendixwestudyarelativelylongtimeseriesof rm-leveldataforHungary,con rmingapositivecomovementbetween rmandaggregatevolatility.TheresultsarereportedinFigureA1.Inaddition,theWebAppendixreportsfurtherevidencefor14othercountries,forwhichwehaveshortertimeseriesof rm-leveldata.Theresults,whileonlysuggestivegiventhedatalimitations,in-dicatethat rm-levelandaggregatevolatilitytendtomoveinthesamedirection.B.AlternativeExplanationsandAdditionalEvidenceFinancialdevelopment.Thepositivecomovementbetween rm-levelandag-gregatevolatilityisonedistinguishingfeatureofourmechanismvis-a-vismodelsof nancialdiversi cation.Inaddition,in nancialdiversi cationmodels,thedeclineinaggregatevolatilitywithdevelopmentisbroughtaboutby nancialde-velopment.Inthedata,however,thevolatility-developmentrelationshipholdsatdi erentlevelsof nancialdevelopment,measuredasprivatecreditoverGDP.16ThisrelationshipisillustratedinFigureA2oftheWebAppendix,wherewesplitthelevelof nancialdevelopmentintodi erentquartiles.Theplotsshowthatthedeclineinvolatilitywithdevelopmentisnotsensitivetothecountry'slevelof nancialdevelopment,thekeymediatingmechanismin nancialdiversi cationmodels.Putdi erently,evencontrollingforthelevelof nancialdevelopment,thereremainsastrongnegativecorrelationbetweenvolatilityanddevelopmentthatneedsexplanation.Equallyimportant,whiletheunivariateregressionsbe-tweenvolatilityand nancialdevelopmentyieldanegativecoecient,thecorre-lationvanishesonceothercontrolsareaddedtothespeci cation.Instead,therelationbetweenvolatilityanddevelopmentappearsrobusttothesamecontrolsandisnotalteredbytheinclusionofaproxyfor nancialdevelopment.ThisisillustratedinTablesA4andA5oftheWebAppendix,whichreporttheresultsfromregressionsofvolatilityonanumberofcovariates.1714CominandPhilippon(2005)hadpreviouslydocumentedthatpubliclytradedU.S. rmsexperiencedanincreaseinvolatilityduringthesameperiod.However,publiclytraded rmsareonlyasmallfractionofall rms.Sinceamajorityof rmsinmostcountriesareprivatelyheld,theevidencefromDavisetal.(2006)ismoreinformativeforourpurposes.15Modelsof nancialdiversi cationrequireadecreaseincross- mcorrelationovertimeinordertogenerateadeclineinaggregatevolatility.Inourmodel,thiscorrelationwillbeconstant.16ThedatacomefromtheWorldBank'sFinancialStructureDatabase(v.4)andcorrespondtotheseriesprivatecreditbydepositmoneybanksandother nancialinstitutionsoverGDP.17Anadditionaldi erencewith nancialmodelsconcernstherelationbetweenproductivityandvolatil-ityatthemicroeconomiclevel.KorenandTenreyro(2007) ndanegativecorrelationbetweenproduc- VOL.VOLNO.ISSUETECHNOLOGICALDIVERSIFICATION11tivecorrelationbetweensalesgrowthandgrowthintechnologydiversi cationatalllevelsofaggregation.GambardellaandTorrisi(1998)measuretechnologicaldiversi cationofthelargestU.S.andEuropeanelectronics rmsbycalculat-ingtheHer ndahlindexofeach rm'snumberofpatentsin1984{1991.Theirmain ndingsarethatbetterperformance(intermsofsalesandpro tability)isassociatedwithincreasedtechnologicaldiversi cationandlowerproductdiver-si cation.Theyconcludethattechnologicaldiversi cationisthekeycovariatepositivelyrelatedwithvariousmeasuresofperformance.Feenstra,MarkusenandZeile(1992)provideevidencethatinputdiversi cationleadstogrowthandproductivitygains.UsingdataonSouthKoreanconglomer-ates,they ndthattheentryofnewinput-producing rmsintoaconglomerateincreasestheproductivityofthatconglomerate.Infarming,therearemultipleexamplesofinputsleadingtoproductivitygainsandfastergrowth.TheWorldBank(2011)reportsthatinlargerscalecropproduction,thetwoshorttermin-terventionswiththegreatestimpactinproductivityaretheuseofhighqualityseedandchemicalfertilizers.Thesamestudylistsanumberofinputsthatbothincreaseagriculturalproductivityandlowervolatility,includingfertilizers,mod-ernseeds,agronomicskills,irrigationsystems,andcellphones(usefultotransmitinformationonweathernews).IntheWebAppendixwediscussadditionalstudiesandpresentevidencefrominput-outputtablesindi erentcountriesshowingthatpurchases(directorindi-rect)byagivensectorfromitselfrelativetototalpurchasesbythatsectorhavefallensigni cantlyovertimeinOECDcountriesfrom1970to2007.Thetrendtowardshigherusageofinputsfromothersectorsisanothermanifestationofthetechnologicaldiversi cationmechanism.II.AModelofTechnologicalDiversi cationBeforespecifyingthemodelindetail,weo erabriefinformalpreviewofthemainfeatures.Monopolisticallycompetitive rmsproducegoodsusingavarietyofinputs(or,morebroadly,technologies).Thereisfreeentryby rmsandnew rmsstartupwithnovarieties.Firmscanaddnewvarietiestotherangeofinputstheyusebyengaginginsomeadoptione ort(e.g.tolearnhowtouseit).Inparticular,theycaninvestresourcesinanadoptionprocess,whichsucceedsthesoonerthemoreresourcesthe rminvests.Indecidinghowmuchtoinvestinadoptioneach rmseekstomaximizethepresentdiscountedvalueofpro ts.(Since rmsarerisk-neutral,pro tmaximizationistheonlygoalofthisprocess.)Hencetheadoptionpartofthemodelisverysimilartostandardexpanding-varietymodels,exceptthattheadoptiongoesonsimultaneouslyinmultiple rmsand,duetotherandomelementsofthemodel,itimpliesthatdi erent rmswillhavedi erentnumbersofvarietiesatagivenpointintime.Themodel'sinnovativefeatureisthatvarietiesaresubjecttoproductivityshocks.Inparticular,onceanewvarietyhasbeenaddedtoa rm'srangeofinputsortechnologies,itbecomesapermanentpartofitsproductiveprocessuntil VOL.VOLNO.ISSUETECHNOLOGICALDIVERSIFICATION13WebAppendixderivestheconditionsunderwhichtechnologicaldiversi cationcanleadtolowervolatilitywhen"1,thatis,wheninputsarecomplements.Onecouldre-interpretthevarietiesinourmodelnotasinputsbutasdisem-bodiedtechnologiestoturnlaborintooutput.Expandingthenumberofvarietiesofsuchtechnologiesisalsolikelytobothincreaseproductivityandprovidetech-nologicaldiversi cation.Hence,intherestofthepaperwerefertothevarietiesinterchangeablyasinputsandastechnologies.20Noticethatweareimplicitlyassumingthatthe rmuseseachvarietyincon-stantquantities,herenormalizedto1.Whatvariesisthenumberofvarieties,thequantityoflaborassignedtoeachofthem|capacityutilization|(bothofwhichdependonthe rm'sdecisions),andtheproductivityofeachvariety(whichwillberandom).Inreality,thequantityofeachinputvarietywillalsovary,butabstractingfromthisdecisionallowsustofocusontechnologicaldiversi cation,whichcomesfromanexpansioninthenumberofvarieties,withoutoverlycompli-catingtheanalysis.Underthetechnologyinterpretation,theassumptionwouldbe neasis.Weassumethatvarietieshaveaconstantproductivityduringtheirrandomlifetime;whenashockhitsthevariety,itceasestocontributetoproduction.(Avarietycanpotentiallybere-adoptedif rmsincurnewadoptioncosts|seebelow.)Thearrivalofshocksforagivenvarietyiiscommontoall rmsusingthisvariety,anditfollowsaPoissonprocesswitharrivalrate .Shocksareindependentacrossvarieties.BecauseashockarriveswithaPoissonprocess,theinput'sproductivelife-timefollowsanexponentialdistributionwithparameter .Hence,conditionalonvarietyiworkingattime0,thedistributionofi(t)isgivenbyi(t)=(1withprob.e� t;0withprob.1�e� t:LetaJ(bt)beaPoissonprocesswitharrivalratebandjumpsofsizea.21Withthisnotation,thedynamicsofavariety'sproductivitycanbewrittenas(3)di(t)=�i(t)dJi( t);wherethesubindexiinJi( t)highlightsthatthePoissonprocessesarevariety-speci candindependentacrossvarieties.Productivityisconstant(at1)beforeajumpoccurs,anditjumpsdowntozerowiththe rstarrivalofdJi�0.20Anotherinterpretationisthattheproductionfunctiontakestheformy=APixi1�1=""=("�1)wherexiistheintermediategoodproducedbythe rmbytransforminglabourthroughxi=ili.Nothingsubstantialchangeseitheriftheinputsareproducedbyspecializedproducersandsoldtothe rmatarms'length;inthiscase,shockstoimapintoinputpriceshocks.21See,forexample,CoxandIsham(1980),Section3.1. VOL.VOLNO.ISSUETECHNOLOGICALDIVERSIFICATION15sourceofoutput uctuationsinthelasthalfcentury.Aninputdoesnotneedtobeanexhaustiblenaturalresourcetobecome(tem-porarilyorpermanently)unavailable.Inthe2011droughtinEastAfricaalargefractionofthelivestockhasdied,causingdrasticdropsinoutput.In1993anexplosioninaSumitomoplantinJapanledtotheannihilationoftwo-thirdsoftheworldsupplyofthehigh-gradeepoxyresinusedtosealmostcomputerchips,causingshortagesandpricehikesinthesemiconductorindustryforseveralmonths.Moregenerally,disastersofdiversenaturecandestroytheoutputofintermediategoodsproducers.Similarly,governmentpoliciescanhinderthepro-ductionoruseofcertainintermediateproducts.Humancapitalisnotimmunefromsuchshockseither:Pol-PotandMaoZedongwipedoutthehumancapitalofanentiregenerationintheirrespectivecountries.Evenifnottakenliterally,theprocessdescribedinequation(3)canalsobeseenasashort-cuttomodellessradicaldisruptions;inthatspirit,shockstoicanresult,forexample,fromchangesintaxesorregulatorypolicies,increasesinthecostofproductionortheimportpriceofavariety(orfromthepriceofaninputneededtousethatvariety,suchasthepriceoffuels),tradedisruptions,weather-relatedshocksthatrenderavarietyuselessorseverelyhinderitstransportationtoitsdestination,andsoon.24B.AFirm'sStaticDecisionsSince rmsengageinmonopolisticcompetition,each rmfacesaniso-elasticdemandwithelasticity":(5)y(j;t)=Y(t)p(j;t)�";whereaggregateoutputY(t)istakenasthenumeraire,andp(j;t)isthepricechargedby rmjattimet.Theproductionfunction(4)pinsdownthenumberofworkersnecessarytosatisfythisdemand,l(j;t)=y(j;t)n(j;t)1=(1�")=A(t)=Y(t)p(j;t)�"n(j;t)1=(1�")=A(t):Firmswithmorevarietiesofinputsaremoreproductive(astandardlove-of-varietye ect)andhencecanproduceagivenlevelofoutputwithfewerworkers.The rmhiresworkersincompetitivelabormarkets.Attimetitfacesawageratew(t),whichdependsontheaggregatestateoftheeconomy,andistakenasgivenbyindividual rms.Flowpro tsarerevenueminuslaborcost,sotheoperatingpro tofthe rmis(6)(j;t)=Y(t)p(j;t)1�"�n(j;t)1=(1�")w(t)Y(t)p(j;t)�"=A(t):24Atransportationortradedisruptionmightmakeatechnologyorvarietytemporarilyunavailable,butthevarietycanpotentiallycomebackintouseafterreinvestment. VOL.VOLNO.ISSUETECHNOLOGICALDIVERSIFICATION17Lunitsofthe nalgoodperunitoftimeinordertoadopttheir rsttechnologicalvariety.Theadoptionofthe rstvarietywillthenbesuccessfulwithaPoissonarrivalrate,thatis,theexpectedwaitingtimeofanewentranttobecomeaproductive rmis1=.Theentrantmayalsoexitatanypointintime.27Risk-neutral rmsareindi erentastowhichvarietytochoose,sinceallva-rietiesentersymmetricallyintheirpro tfunctionandtheirsolegoalispro tmaximization.Sincethechoiceisindeterminate,asatie-breaker,weassumethat rmstrytoadopttechnologieswithlowerindexes rst.A rmofsizenhasthusaccesstotechnologies1;2;:::;nandwould,uponsuccess,adopttechnologyn+1next.Thistie-breakingconditioncapturesthenotionthatsometechnologiesorinputsareeasiertoadoptandhencetendtobeadopted rstbymost rms.28Let(n)=f[I(n)=L;n]=n;forn�0,denotetheadoptionintensityofasize-n rm.Becausefishomogeneousofdegreeone,the owcostofthisadoptionintensityis(7)I(n)=g[(n)]Ln;n�0whereg(:)istheinverseoff(:;1),anincreasing,convexfunction.Forprospectiveentrantswithn=0,the owcostofadoptingthe rstvarietyissimplyI(0)=L:Statevariables.Becausenistheonly rm-levelstatevariable,weintroduceachangeofvariablesandindex rmsbyn.Atype-n rmhasexactlynworkingvarietiesatitsdisposal.Becauseweonlyneedtokeeptrackoftheworkingvarieties,wheneveravarietyishitbyashock,theindexofallvarietieswithahigherindexisreadjustedsoastoleavenoholesintheordering.29De neasmk(t)themeasureof rmshavingexactlyk=0;1;2;:::workingvarietiesattimet.LetM(t)=fm0(t);m1(t);m2(t);:::gdenotethe rm-sizemassdistributionattimet.Hence,thetotalmassof rmsattimetisgivenbyM(t)=P1k=0mk(t).30Eventhoughentrantshavezeroproductivityandhencedonotcontributetooutputoremployment,theymaybecomesuccessfulinadoptingtheir rstvariety,soitisimportanttotrackthem.ThemassdistributionM(t)sucientlycharacterizesthestateoftheeconomy,bothintermsofaggregateallocationsandprices,andintermsofdynamics.NotethatM(t)israndom:the rm-sizemassdistributionwilldependontherealizationofadversetechnologyshocks.LetSdenotethesetofallpossible rm-sizemassdistributions.WeassumethatM(t)followsaMarkovprocesswith27Inequilibrium,freeentrypinsdownthevalueofaprospectiveentrantatzero.Hencethemarginalentrantwillbeindi erentbetweencontinuingtospendonadoptioncostsorexiting.28Thiscouldalternativelybemodeledbyassumingafunctionalformfor xedcostsofinvestment,wherebydi erentvarietieshavedi erentcostsofinvestmentsandhencelower-costvarietiesareadopted rst.Thecoreresultswillbesimilartotheorderingassumptioninthetext.29Thatis,ifaneconomyhasvarietiesk=1;2;3;4andvariety3fails,then,variety4isreindexed3andthenewsetofvarietieshasindexesk0=1;2;3:30NotethatM(t)isnotaprobabilitydistributionasthetotalmassM(t)isingeneraldi erentfrom1;theprobability(share)of rmswithkvarieties,isgivenbymk(t) M(t). VOL.VOLNO.ISSUETECHNOLOGICALDIVERSIFICATION19maximizethepresentvalueofconsumption,discountedattherate:UZ1t=0e�tC(t)dt:TheEulerequationpinsdowntherisklessrateofreturnintheeconomyatr(t)=.Investorsmaximizetheexpectedpresentvalueofpro ts,discountedattherate.Toensurenon-negativegrowthanda nitevalueforthe rm,weimposethefollowingparameterrestrictionson ,andthecostofadoption:(11)g0( ) andlimx! +g(x)=1;The rstconditionensuresthatavarietyispro tableenoughsothatitisworthinvestinginadoptioncostswhenavarietysu ersashock.Thesecondconditionensuresthatadoptioniscostlyenoughsothatthegrowthrateoftheeconomywillneverexceed,thesubjectivediscountrate.Bellmanequation.LetV(n;M)denotethevalueofasize-n rmwhenthestateoftheeconomyisM.Itistheexpectedpresentvalueofthestreamoffuturepro ts,comingfromnetoperatingrevenuesminusthecostsofadoption,V(n;M)=maxfp;IgEZ1t=0e�tf[n(t);M(t)]�I[n(t)]gdtwhereM(t)andn(t)evolvesubjecttothelawsofmotiondescribedinequations(9)and(10),respectively.Fromtheperspectiveofa rm,thereisa rm-levelstatevariable,n,andanaggregatestatevariable,M,thetwoofwhichcontainalltheinformationrelevantinitsdecision.The rmchoosesthepriceofitsproduct(takingaggregatedemand,theproductionfunctionandwagesasgiven),andtheintensitywithwhichitinvestsinadoptingnewvarieties.Thepolicyvariablesarethuspand.Giventhe owpro tfunctioninequation(6),thecostfunctionforadoptioninequation(7),andthelawofmotionforMinequation(9),theBellmanequationforthe rm'spro tmaximizationproblemcanbewrittenas:V(n;M)=maxp;If(p;n;M)�I+(n)[V(n+1;M)�V(n;M)]+ nXi=1[V(n�1;M+Gi(M))�V(n;M)]++ 1Xi=n+1[V(n;M+Gi(M))�V(n;M)]+VMF(M)):(12)incentivetodiversifydoesnothingeonthe nancialstructureoftheeconomyorthedegreeofriskaversion(thoughquantitativelytheymaya ecttheseincentives). VOL.VOLNO.ISSUETECHNOLOGICALDIVERSIFICATION21DenotebyN(M)theaggregatenumberofvarietiesde nedas:(16)N(M)ZMndM=1Xi=1imi;whereRMdMstandsfortheLebesgueintegralover rmswithdi erentsizes,withrespecttothe rm-sizemeasureM.34AggregateproductivityA(M)isgivenbyapositivefunctionA(N;m0)�0thatdependsonthetotalnumberofvarietiesNusedbyproductive rms,andonthemassofzero-size rmsm0,whichdonotcontributetoproduction.WeassumethatA(N;m0)satis esthefollowingproperties:N(M)0,m0(M)0and(17)1 "�1+N(M)1�m0(M);whereN(M)@lnA(N;m0) @lnNistheelasticityofA(N;m0)withrespecttoN(hold-ingm0 xed),andm0(M)isthecorrespondingelasticitywithrespecttom0(holdingN xed).TheseconditionsarejointlysucientfortheexistenceanduniquenessofaBEGP.TheassumptionthatAisnondecreasinginN(N(M)0)embedstheideathattherecanbeknowledgespilloversacrossproductive rms.Notethattheinequalityisweak,soN(M)=0isapossibility.Theassump-tionthatAisdecreasinginm0(m0(M)0)impliesthatforagivennumberofvarietiesN,whenevertherearetoomanynewentrantsrelativetoequilibrium,pro tsper rmfall,reducingtheincentivestoenter.Intuitively,unproductive rmswithnovarietiescontributenegativelytotheaveragestockofknowledgeoftheeconomy.The nalinequalityconditionensuresthatthecontributionofnew rmstoGDPgrowthvanishesastheeconomygrowsandguaranteesapositivemeasureofnew rmsinequilibrium.Notethattheseconditionsaresucient,butnotnecessaryforaBEGP.Inparticular,ifN(M)=m0(M)=0,theeconomyfeaturesaBEGPwhen"=2.35Similarly,ifm0(M)=0,theeconomyfeaturesaBEGPwhenN(M)=1�1 "�1.Inthebaselinequantitativeexercise,weallowforverysmallexternale ects,consistentwiththeempiricalliterature.Theentrymarginm0adjustssoastopreventexplosivegrowthinthecaseoflowsubstitutability("2),ortoprevent34ThesumP1i=1imiwillbe nitewithprobabilityoneatanypointintime,aslongaswestartfromaninitial rm-sizemassdistributionM0with niteN.Thisisbecauseatanypointintimet;N(t)hasa niteupperbound.Fromcondition(11),adoptionintensitybyincumbentscannotbegreaterthan +forany rm.Hencevarietiesusedbyincumbent rmscanatmostgrowattherate +.Asitwillbecomeclear,thegrowthstemmingfromthecreationofnew rmsism0 N(M),whichisboundedfromaboveby" ,whereis nite.Hence,foranyt;N(t)N(0)e( ++" )t:Notethatafterapositiveamountoftimehaspassed,nwillhavefullsupportwithprobabilityone.ThisisbecausesuccessfuladoptionfollowsaPoissonprocess,whichmakesthenumberofnewvarietiesaPoisson-distributedrandomvariable.35IfN=m0=0and"=2;theaggregatedemandexternalityandthecompetitione ectcanceloutandpro tspervarietyareconstant,whichissucientforaBEGP. VOL.VOLNO.ISSUETECHNOLOGICALDIVERSIFICATION23implicitlyde nedby(21)g0()= :Wagesand naloutputarelinearinN.Wagesare(22)w(M)=("�1)N(M); naloutputis(23)Y(M)="N(M)L;where=(+ �) +g()ispercapitapro tspervariety,whichisconstant.Firmpricesare:(24)p(n;M)=N(M) n1=("�1):Themassofnewentrantsm0satis es(25)=1 "N(M)"�2 "�1A(N;m0):ThelawofmotionforMisMarkovwithFiandGikde nedasFi(M)=((i�1)mi�1�imiifi�1;m0�m1ifi=1:(26)Gik(M)=8�&#x]TJ ;� -1; .63; Td;&#x [00;:mi+1�miifki;mi+1ifk=i+1;0ifk&#x]TJ ;� -1; .63; Td;&#x [00;i+1:(27)TheproofofthisandallotherpropositionsareintheWebAppendix.Equation(20)showsthe rmvalueasafunctionoftheadoptioncostofnewentrants.EachnewentrantspendsLforanexpected1=unitsoftimebeforebecomingaproductive rmandachievingavalueofV(1;M)=v.Therestofthe rmvaluefunctionislinearinn.Equation(21)isthe rst-orderconditionforoptimaladoption.Thisconditionpinsdownaunique,constantthatisindependentofn.Equation(22)showshowwagesdependontheaggregatenumberofvarieties.Whentheeconomyusesmoreinputvarieties,aggregatelaborproductivityishigher,andwagesarehigherintermsofthe nalgood(thenumeraire).WehavealreadysubstitutedouttheequilibriumvalueoftheexternalproductivityA(equation(25)).Equation(23)expresses naloutputasafunction VOL.VOLNO.ISSUETECHNOLOGICALDIVERSIFICATION25nvarietieston+1varieties.Recallthatasize-n rmadoptsnewvarietieswitharrivalrate(n)=nforn1and(0)=.Ateverypointintime,ameasureZM(n)dMdt=N(M)dt+m0(M)dtof rmsbecomessuccessfulinadoptingthenextvariety.Thesecondtypeofshockisthefailureofaparticulartechnologyk.Thisshockdecreasesthenumberofvarietiesby1forall rmsthatusevarietyk.Becausethereisapositivemassofthese rms,thisshockinducesaninstantaneousjumpinN.Theaggregateimpactoftheshock(and,ultimately,aggregatevolatility)willdependonthemeasureof rmsusingtechnologyk.Notethatbecausetechnologyshocksarecommonacross rms,theywillalsoinducecorrelationsacross rms.Thisiswhythereisaggregateuncertaintyevenwithacontinuumof rms.38LetMidenotethemassof rmsusingvarietyi.Because rmsadoptlower-indexedvarieties rst,thisisthesameasthemassof rmswithiormorevarieties,Mi=P1k=imk.Then,usingtheaggregationaboveandtheMarkovdynamicsofMasgivenbyequations(26)-(27),wecanwritethedynamicsofNasfollows:(30)dN=[N+m0]dt�1Xi=1MidJi( t):The rsttwotermsarethee ectofinnovation.Each rm'sadoptionissubjecttoanindependentPoissonprocess,thesumofwhichisadeterministicprocessbythelawoflargenumbers.Thesecondtermcapturesadverseproductivityshocks,whicharecommonacross rmsandarenotwashedoutbyaggregation.BecausevarietyiisusedbyameasureMiof rms,ashockdJireducesthetotalnumberofvarietiesbyMi.Proposition3.Inarecursiveequilibrium,theexpectedgrowthrateofthenum-berofvarietiesN(andhenceofoutputY)is(31)E(dN=N) dt=+m0 N� ;anditsinstantaneousvarianceis(32)Var(dN=N) dt= 1Xk=1s2k;wheresk=Mk=NmeasuresthecontributionofvarietyktoGDP.38Becausepositiveshocks(technologyadoptions)areindependentacross rms,whilenegativeshocks(technologyfailures)arecommon,aggregateshockswillhaveanegativelyskeweddistribution.ThisisconsistentwithevidencepresentedbyJovanovic(2006)fortheU.S.economy.SeeWebAppendixforfutherreferencesaswellasnewevidenceonskewnessinothercountries. VOL.VOLNO.ISSUETECHNOLOGICALDIVERSIFICATION27Proposition4.Forallinitialvarietydistributions,M(0)=M0,therecursiveequilibriumconvergestoabalanced-expected-growthpath.Theexpectedlong-rungrowthratexisimplicitlyde nedby(33)g0( +x)= ;withx2[0;)and givesthepercapita rmvaluepervariety.Inthelong-run,asN!1,thecontributionofentrantsm0togrowthvanishesasm0 N!0:TheproofmakesuseofthesucientconditionsN(M)0,m0(M)0and(17).Asstressedearlier,theseconditionsarejointlysucientbutnotnecessaryforaBEGP.Note,inparticular,thattherearetwoalternativewaystoachieveaBEGPinoursetup.The rst,whichdoesnotrelyonexternale ects,istoimposeaparametricrestrictionontheelasticityofsubstitution.Speci cally,whenN(M)=m0(M)=0;aBEGPexistsif"=2:43Thesecondalternativethatdoesnotrelyonexternale ectsfromentry(i.e.,m0(M)=0)istoimposetherestrictionthatN(M)=1�1 "�1.44ThesetwooptionscauseoutputtobelinearinN,thekeyconditionforaBEGP.Inthebaselinequantitativeexerciseweallowforsmallexternale ects,consistentwiththeliterature,andintheWebAppendixwepresenttheresultswithoutexternale ects.G.GDPDynamicsalongtheBalanced-Expected-GrowthPathSinceatanytimet(instantaneous)GDPgrowthdY(t)=Y(t)isarandomvari-able,itnotonlyhasanexpectedvaluebutalsoavariance.Thisvarianceisnotconstant,evenontheBEGP.(Noticethatifitwere,themodelwouldhavenohopeofexplainingthecross-sectionalpatternsofvolatilityanddevelopmentthatmotivatethepaper.)Instead,itdependsonthesetoftechnologiesinuse,aswellastheirdistributionamong rms.Ingeneral,thesedependontheparticularhistoryofshocksthathavehittheeconomy,sothevariancemustbecomputedbynumericalsimulation.Beforeweturntothistask,weo ersometheoreticalresultsthatbothhelptounderstandthesimulationsandprovidesomeintuitiononthemainmechanismatplay.ThevolatilityofN(andhenceofY)dependsonthewholedistributionofvarietiesusedby rms.Ifsomevarietiesareusedbymore rmsthanothers,thenshocksa ectingthesevarietiesaregoingtohavealargerimpactonGDP.Throughtheintroductionofnewvarieties,technologicalprogressincreasesthede-greeoftechnologicaldiversi cation(andhencelowersvolatility)whileincreasingthelevelofdevelopment.Thisimpartsanaturaltendencyforanegativecorrela-tionbetweenvolatilityanddevelopmentthatwillbeprevalentinournumericalanalysis.Note,however,thatinprincipletherelationshipbetweenvolatilityanddevelopmentdoesnotalwaysneedtobestrictlynegative.Tounderstandthis43Inthiscase,pro tspervarietyareconstantandthereisnoentryof rms:m0=0:44Asbefore,inthiscase,thereisnoentryandm0=0: VOL.VOLNO.ISSUETECHNOLOGICALDIVERSIFICATION29pathwithrate� .Thedeclineinvolatilitythusresultsasaby-productofthedevelopmentprocess.Beforemovingtothequantitativeresults,acommentontheasymmetryinthesourcesofaggregatevolatilityisinorder.Inthemodel,positiveshocksatthemicrolevelaverageuptoasmoothaggregateprocess,whereasnegativeshocksatthemicrolevelgenerateaggregatevolatility.Whileofcoursethisisamodellingsimpli cation,theasymmetryleadstonegativeskewnessinthedistributionofgrowthrates,apredictionthatisconsistentwiththedata(seeWebAppendix).III.VolatilityandDevelopment:AQuantitativeAssessmentOuranalysissofarhasshownthatvolatilitydeclinesmonotonicallywiththedegreeoftechnologicaldiversi cationandthat,ceterisparibus,theintroductionofanewvarietyintheeconomyincreasesthelevelofdevelopmentandthedegreeoftechnologicaldiversi cation,thusloweringvolatility.Wehavealsoarguedthatthegrowthprocess,throughtheexpansioninthenumberofvarieties,tendstoimpartanegativecorrelationbetweenvolatilityanddevelopment,thoughthistendencymaybeoverturnedundercertainhistoriesofshocks;speci cally,itisconceivablethatcountriesthatuseafewvarietiesveryintenselydisplaybotharelativelyhighlevelofdevelopmentandhighvolatilityduetotheirlackofdiversi cation.Toestablishwhethertheseoccurrencesarefrequentorrare,onehastosimulatethemodel.Ourstrategyistogeneratearti cialdatabysimulatingthemodel1,000timesfor64di erenteconomies(countries)from1870through2007.Alleconomiesstartatthestageofdevelopmenttheywerein1870,accordingtoMaddison(2010).(Thereare64countriesatdi erentstagesofdevelopmentwithdataonGDPpercapitain1870;seeWebAppendixforthelistofcountries.)Aninitial(single-parameter)logarithmic rm-sizedistributionforeacheconomyiscalibratedsoastomatchthelevelofdevelopmentofthecountryin1870(weshallelaborateonthislater).Allparameterscharacterizingtheevolutionoftheeconomiesareiden-tical.However,shocksarecountry-speci canddi erentrealizationsofshocksleadtopotentiallydi erentgrowthpaths.Weanalyzetherelationbetweenvolatilityandthelevelofdevelopmentforthesimulatedeconomiesandcomparepatternsofvolatilityanddevelopmentinthelast48yearsofoursimulationstothecorre-spondingpatternsinthecross-sectionaldatathatwealreadyexaminedinSectionI,coveringtheperiod1960-2007.NotethatbecausethevolatilityofaggregateGDPdependsonthedistributionoftechnologiesacross rms,oursimulationsneedtokeeptrackoftheentiredistributionoftechnologyusageacross rmsatallpointsintime.Weemphasizethatinrealitythereareseveraladditionalmechanismsdrivingacountry'seconomicdevelopmentanditspatternsofvolatility.Thegoalofthisnumericalexerciseistostudyhowthemodelbehaveswithreasonableparametervalues,nottorunahorseraceamongpotentialexplanations. VOL.VOLNO.ISSUETECHNOLOGICALDIVERSIFICATION31numberofvarietiesintheeconomyanddecreaseswiththenumberofentrants.WedonothavedirectestimatesofNandm0;theliteraturehaspointedtosmallbutnonzeroexternale ects.Forexample,Combes,DurantonandGobillon(2011a)and(2011b)estimatebothpositiveurbanexternalitiesandcongestionscoststobeoftheorderof0:03.HencewehaveselectedN=�m0=0:03asthebaseline.(NotethatthemagnitudesdonotneedtocoincidetosatisfythesucientconditionsforBEGP.)Forrobustness,weexperimentwithdi erentvaluesforNand(�m0)between0and1satisfying(17).Wefoundthatthechoiceoftheseparameterswasnotimportantfortherelationbetweenvolatilityanddevelopment;therobustnessresultsareavailableintheWebAppendix.(NotethatinthelimitcaseinwhichN=m0=0,anecessaryandsucientconditionforbalancedgrowthisthat"=2:TheresultsforthiscaseareinTableA12oftheWebAppendix.)Initialconditions.Weinitializethemodelin1870andassumethatineachcountry,theinitial rm-sizedistributionislogarithmic.(Thisisthedistributionof rms'sizeinKletteandKortum(2004),discussedthoroughlyinthecontextof rms'sizesbyIjiriandSimon(1977).49)Wecalibratetheparameterofthecountry-speci cdistributionsoastomatchthecountry'slevelofdevelopmentin1870,accordingtoMaddison(2010).Hence,allcountriesstartatthelevelofdevelopmenttheyhadin1870.Morespeci cally,thelogarithmicdistributionisgivenby:(34)pk=�1 ln(1�)k k;k1wherepkisthefractionof rmsusingkvarieties.Weassumeallcountriesstartwithaunitmassofproductive rms,M1,in1870,andletthedistributionof rmsvaryacrosscountrieswithacountry-speci cparameterc.50Thus,pkmapsintomk,themassof rmswithk1varieties.Themeanofthesizedistributionis(35)1Xk=1kpk=�1 ln(1�) 1�;whichisincreasingin.ThismeanmapsintoN,whichislinearlyrelatedtoGDPpercapita:Y(M)=L="N(M).HencefromdataonrealGDPpercapitain1870(GDPPCc;1870),foragiven",wecanobtainNc;1870,whereNc;1870is49Thelogarithmicdistributionisappealinginthiscontext,bothbecauseitcanmatchimportantfea-turesofthe rm-sizedistribution(KletteandKortum(2004))andbecauseitreliesonasingleparameter,whichwecancalibrateusingaggregatedata.50Overtime,thesizeofM1(t)willadjustthroughtheentrymargin. VOL.VOLNO.ISSUETECHNOLOGICALDIVERSIFICATION33duringthe138yearsofsimulation.Atanypointintime,wecantakeasnapshotoftheeconomybycountingthenumberof rmsineachsizebin,m1t;m2t;:::RealGDPpercapitaattimetcanthenbecalculatedas"Pnmaxi=1imit.ToconstructstatisticsthathavethesameinterpretationasthoseintheempiricalanalysisofSectionI,wecomputedecadeaveragesof(thelogof)GDPpercapitaand(logsof)standarddeviationsofpercapitaGDPgrowth(ourmeasureofvolatility).RecallthatinSectionIwerunaregressionofcountry-levelvolatilityonincomeforthenearly vedecadesbetween1960and2007.Torunasimilarregressiononoursimulatedpanelofcountriesweusedthelast48yearsofdatageneratedinoursimulations.Toreducesimulationerror,wereportthemeansfrom1,000simulations.B.ResultsThissectionpresentsanddiscussestheresultsfromthebaselinecalibration,alongwiththethreemainregularitiesmotivatingthemodel.1.GDPvolatilitydeclineswithdevelopment,bothinthecrosssectionandforagivencountryovertime.The rstsetofrowsinTable3showsforeachvalueof ,themodel-generatedslopecoecientsandthecorrespondingstandarderrorsfromOLSregressionsofdecade(log)volatilityontheaverage(log)GDPpercapitaofthedecade,poolingdatafromallsimulatedcountriesinthelast vedecades.Thelasttwocolumnsintherowshowthecorresponding guresusingtwosamplesofPPP-adjusteddatafromthePWT.The rstsampleusesthesetofcountriesforwhichMaddison'sdataareavailablein1870|thecountriesforwhichwepindowntheinitialconditions.WerefertothissubsampleastheMaddisonsampleandtheresultsarereportedinthenext-to-lastcolumn.Thelastcolumnusesthewholesample,reproducingtheresultsinthe rstcolumnofTable1:Thesecondsetofrowsshows,correspondingly,thewithin-countryslopesandthestandarddeviationsresultingfromthemodel-generateddatafordi erent s,aswellastheempiricalresultsbasedontheMaddisonsample,andthewholesample(thelattercorrespondingtothesecondcolumnofTable1):Asinthedata,thetime-seriesslopesgeneratedbythemodeltendtobelargerinmagnitudethanthecorrespondingcross-sectionalslopes.Theseresultsindicatethatfortheparametervaluesanalyzed,thecoecientsinboththepooledandwithin-countryregressionsarenegativeandsigni cantatstandardcon dencelevelsandquantitativelycomparabletothoseinthedata.Toassesswhetherandtowhatextentthemodelcanaccountforthedeclineinvolatilitywithdevelopmentseeninthedata,itisimportanttoknownotonlytheslopecoecientsbutalsothedegreeofdispersioninGDPgeneratedbythemodel.Inthe1960s,thestandarddeviationof(log)percapitaGDPacrosscountriesinthedatawas0.970(thecorrespondingvaluewas0.977inMaddison'ssample).5353Thisisthestandarddeviationacrosscountriesofthedecade-average(log)GDPpercapita. VOL.VOLNO.ISSUETECHNOLOGICALDIVERSIFICATION35Table3|VolatilityandDevelopment:QuantitativeResultsforDifferent Notes:Thetableshows,correspondingly,thecross-sectionalandwithin-countryslopecoecientsandstandarddeviations(inparentheses)fromregressionsof(log)volatilityofannualizedquarterlygrowthratescomputedovernon-overlappingdecadesontheaverage(log)levelofdevelopmentinthedecade;aconstant(notreported)isincludedineachregression.Thecrosssectionalregressionsarebasedonpooleddatafor5decades.ThethirdsetofrowsshowsthestandarddeviationofaverageloggedGDPpercapitaoverthewholedecade(andthestandarddeviationover1,000simulations).Thefourthlineshowsthepercentvariationinvolatilitygeneratedbya1standarddeviationincreaseintheloggedGDPpercapita.MaddisonsampleisasubsetofthewholesamplethatincludesthecountrieswithdataonGDPin1870(fromMaddison,2010).Theresultscorrespondtothebaselinecalibration;theparametervaluesare:=3;N=�m0=0:03;and=0:10.Seetextforexplanations.theeconomycorrelatesnegativelywithincomepercapita.Thisisalsothecaseinourmodel.Aregressionoftheshareofsmall rms56onlogGDPpercapitainthemodel,yieldsnegativeandsigni cantcoecients,rangingfrom-0.049(s.e.=0.011)for =0:05to-0.025(s.e.=0.009)for =0:20.3.Firm-levelandaggregatevolatilitytendtodisplaypositivecomovement.Inthemodel-generateddata, rm-levelvolatility,measuredasthestandarddeviationofsalesgrowthforthemedian rm,andaggregatevolatilityareposi-tivelycorrelated.Themeancorrelations(andthestandarddeviationsover1,000simulations|inparentheses)are,correspondingly0.489(0.048)for =0:05;0.421(0.042)for =0:10;0.359(0.055)for =0:15;and0.274(0.059)for =0:20:Interestingly,theresultsalsosuggestthatwhenthevolatilityofshocksishigher(thatis, ishigher);thecorrelationbetweenmicroandmacrovolatilitybecomesweaker.Thismodelpredictioncanpotentiallybetestedinthefuture,aslongertimeserieson rm-leveldatafordi erentcountriesaregathered.Inall,thepositivecomovementgeneratedbythemodelisconsistentwiththeavailableevidence(seeSectionIandtheWebAppendix).Finally,asnotedearlier,inamajorityofcountries,thedistributionofgrowthratesisnegativelyskewed(skewnessismeasuredasthesamplethirdstandardizedmoment).Themodeliscapableofgeneratingthisnegativeskewness,asonlynegativeshocksatthemicrolevelcontributetoaggregatevolatility(positivemicroeconomicshocksadduptoadeterministicaggregateprocess).Theaverage56Small rmsarede nedasthosehaving veorfewerinputvarieties: 36THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEWMONTHYEARskewnessforcountriesinthemodel-generateddatarangesfrom�0:285when =0:05to�0:076when =0:20:When =0:10;skewnessis�0:141.Theaverageskewnesscoecientinthedataishigher:�0:390.Themodelcouldyieldhigherskewnessifnegativeshockswerenotindependentacrossvarieties.Inall,thequantitativeexerciseleadsustoconcludethatthetechnological-diversi cationmodel,thoughstylized,canpotentiallyaccountforasubstantialpartofthedeclineinvolatilitywithdevelopmentobservedinthedata.Themodelo ersanalternativechanneltoaccount(atleastpartially)forthevolatility-sizerelationshipobservedatthe rmlevel,andgeneratesapositivecorrelationbetween rm-leveldataandaggregatevolatilitythatappearsinlinewithrecentempirical ndingsinthisarea.IV.ConcludingRemarksWearguethattechnologicaldiversi cationo ersapromising(yetsofarover-looked)explanationforthenegativerelationbetweenvolatilityanddevelopment.Wedosobyproposingamodelinwhichtheproductionprocessmakesuseofdif-ferentvarietiessubjecttoimperfectlycorrelatedshocks.AsinRomer(1990)andGrossmanandHelpman(1991),technologicalprogresstakesplaceasanexpan-sioninthenumberofinputvarieties,increasingproductivity.Thenewinsightinthemodelisthattheexpansionininputvarietiescanalsoleadtolowervolatilityinproduction.First,aseachindividualvarietymatterslessandlessinproduc-tion,thecontributionofvariety-speci c uctuationstooverallvolatilitydeclines.Second,eachadditionalvarietyprovidesanewadjustmentmargininresponsetoexternalshocks,makingproductivitylessvolatile.Inthemodel,thenumberofvarietiesevolvesendogenouslyinresponsetopro tincentivesandthedecreaseinvolatilityresultsasaby-productof rms'incentivestoincreasepro ts.Wesimulatethemodelforplausibleparametervaluesand ndthatitcanquanti-tativelyaccountforasubstantialfractionofthestatisticalvariationinvolatilitywithrespecttodevelopmentobservedinthedata.Therearethreenaturaldirectionsforfurtherinvestigation.First,extendingthesetuptoamulti-sectormodelthatexplicitlydistinguishesbetweenwithin-andacross-sectordiversi cation.Second,allowingforinternationaltradetoanalyzethetradeo betweenhighersectoralspecialization(possiblybroughtaboutbyincreasedtradeopenness),andthescopeforinputortechnologydiversi cationfacilitatedbytrade.57ThethirddirectionentailsextendingthemodeltomatchtheregularitiesemphasizedintheRBCliterature,withafocusonpoorcountries.Someofthefrictions(andshocks)neededtoaugmentourmodelwillbesimilartotheextensionsmadetotheRBC(orNewKeynesian)model.Thekeycontributionofourmodelwillbeontheendogenouslinkbetweenacountry'sdevelopmentanditssusceptibilitytoshocks,alinkthatisnotaddressedbytheRBCliterature.57SeeCaselli,Koren,LisickyandTenreyro(2010)foranexplorationofthesemechanisms. 38THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEWMONTHYEARmakingthetheoriesfacethefacts."JournalofMonetaryEconomics,51(1):39{83.Comin,Diego,andThomasPhilippon.2005.TheRiseinFirm-levelVolatil-ity:CausesandConsequences.Cambridge,MA:NBERMacroeconomicsAnnual.GertlerandRogo (eds.).Cox,David,andVitIsham.1980.PointProcesses.London:ChapmanandHall.Davis,Steven,JohnHaltiwanger,C.J.Krizan,RonaldJarmin,JavierMiranda,AlfredNucci,andKristinSandusky.2009.\MeasuringtheDy-namicsofYoungandSmallBusinesses:IntegratingtheEmployerandNonEm-ployerBusinesses."InProducerDynamics:NewEvidencefromMicroData.,ed.Dunne,JensenandRoberts.NBER.Davis,Steven,JohnHaltiwanger,RonJarmin,andJavierMiranda.2006.VolatilityandDispersioninBusinessGrowthRates:PubliclyTradedver-susPrivatelyHeldFirms.Vol.21,Cambridge,MA:NBERMacroeconomicsAn-nual.Acemoglu,Rogo ,andWoodford(eds.).Ethier,Wilfred.1982.\NationalandInternationalReturnstoScaleintheMod-ernTheoryofInternationalTrade."AmericanEconomicReview,73(3):389{405.Feenstra,Robert,JamesMarkusen,andWilliamZeile.1992.\Account-ingforGrowthwithNewInputs:TheoryandEvidence."AmericanEconomicReview,82(2):415{21.Gabaix,Xavier.2011.\Thegranularoriginsofaggregate uctuations."Econo-metrica,79(3):733{772.Gambardella,Alfonso,andSalvatoreTorrisi.1998.\Doestechnologicalconvergenceimplyconvergenceinmarkets?Evidencefromtheelectronicsin-dustry."ResearchPolicy,27:445{463.Granstrand,Ove.1998.\Towardsatheoryofthetechnology-based rm."Re-searchPolicy,27(5):465{489.Granstrand,Ove,KeithPavitt,andPariPatel.1997.\Multi-technologycorporations:Whytheyhavedistributedratherthandistinctivecorecompeten-cies."CaliforniaManagementReview,39:8{25.Greenwood,Jeremy,andBoyanJovanovic.1990.\FinancialDevelop-ment,Growth,andtheDistributionofIncome."JournalofPoliticalEconomy,98(5):1076{1107.Griliches,Zvi.1957.\Hybridcorn:Anexplorationintheeconomicsoftechno-logicalchange."Econometrica,25(4):501{522.Grossman,Gene,andElhananHelpman.1991.InnovationandGrowthintheGlobalEconomy.Cambridge,MA:TheMITPress.Grossman,Gene,andEstebanRossi-Hansberg.2010.\ExternalEconomiesandInternationalTradeRedux."QuarterlyJournalofEconomics,125(2):829{858. 40THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEWMONTHYEARRamey,Garey,andValerieRamey.1995.\Cross-countryevidenceonthelinkbetweenvolatilityandgrowth."AmericanEconomicReview,85(5):1138{51.Romer,Paul.1986.\IncreasingReturnsandLong-RunGrowth."JournalofPoliticalEconomy,94(5):1002{1037.Romer,Paul.1990.\EndogenousTechnologicalChange."JournalofPoliticalEconomy,98(5):71{102.Rossi-Hansberg,Esteban,andMarkWright.2007.\EstablishmentSizeDynamicsintheAggregateEconomy."AmericanEconomicReview,97(5):1639{1666.Saint-Paul,Gilles.1992.\TechnologicalChoice,FinancialMarketsandEco-nomicDevelopment."EuropeanEconomicReview,36:763{781.Sichel,Daniel.1993.\BusinessCycleAsymmetry:ADeeperLook."EconomicEnquiry,31(2):224{36.Steel,William.1993.\SmallEnterprisesinIndonesia:Role,Growth,andStrategicIssues."Workingpaper194.JakartaDevelopmentStudiesProjectII.Strotmann,Harald,JorgDopke,andClaudiaBuch.2006.\Doestradeopennessincrease rm-levelvolatility?"EconomicStudies2006-40,DeutscheBundesbank.Sutton,John.2002.\TheVarianceofFirmGrowthRates:TheScalingPuzzle."Physica,312(3-4):577{590.Thesmar,David,andMathiasThoenig.2011.\ContrastingTrendsinFirmVolatility."AmericanEconomicJournal:Macroeconomics,3(4):143{80.WorldBank.2011.\RisingFoodandEnergyPricesinEuropeandCentralAsia."WorldBank.WorkingPaper61097.