/
Whenmenarebroughttogethertheynolongerdecideatrandomandindependentlyofo Whenmenarebroughttogethertheynolongerdecideatrandomandindependentlyofo

Whenmenarebroughttogethertheynolongerdecideatrandomandindependentlyofo - PDF document

lois-ondreau
lois-ondreau . @lois-ondreau
Follow
362 views
Uploaded On 2016-09-20

Whenmenarebroughttogethertheynolongerdecideatrandomandindependentlyofo - PPT Presentation

1TherstbestsellerlistofbookswaspublishedintheUSbyTheBookmanin1895seeBassettandWalter2001PublishersWeeklycompileditsrstbestsellerlistin1913TheinuentialNewYorkTimesbestsellerlistwasrstpublish ID: 469042

1TherstbestsellerlistofbookswaspublishedintheU.S.byTheBookmanin1895(seeBassettandWalter2001).Publishers'Weeklycompileditsrstbestsellerlistin1913.TheinuentialNewYorkTimesbestsellerlistwasrstpublish

Share:

Link:

Embed:

Download Presentation from below link

Download Pdf The PPT/PDF document "Whenmenarebroughttogethertheynolongerdec..." is the property of its rightful owner. Permission is granted to download and print the materials on this web site for personal, non-commercial use only, and to display it on your personal computer provided you do not modify the materials and that you retain all copyright notices contained in the materials. By downloading content from our website, you accept the terms of this agreement.


Presentation Transcript

Whenmenarebroughttogethertheynolongerdecideatrandomandindependentlyofoneanother;theyinuenceoneanother.Multiplexcausescomeintoaction.Theyworrymen,draggingthemtorightorleft,butonethingthereistheycannotdestroy,thisistheirPanurgeock-of-sheephabits.Andthisisaninvariant.HenriPoincaré,TheFoundationsofScience,19131IntroductionConsideraconsumerwhohasdecidedtopurchaseanentertainmentgoodlikeamusicalbum,acomputergame,orabook.Whichsuchgoodwouldonechooseamongthemyriadofpossiblechoices?Sincethesegoodsareoftenexperiencegoods,thequalitiesofthesegoodsare,tovaryingextents,uncertaintotheconsumerpriortoconsumption.Consumersofexperiencegoodsmaybasequalitypredictionsontheirownex-perience.Forexample,manyconsumerspurchasecreativeworksofauthorsthattheylikedinthepast.Someconsumersmaybasetheirqualityinferencesonrec-ommendationsreceivedfromfriendsandrelatives.Otherconsumershavegreatcondenceintherecommendationsofprofessionalreviewers.Morerecently,ithasbecomecommonplaceforconsumerstolearnaboutnewproductsbyevaluatinginformationconcerningthepastpurchasesofconsumerstheydonotknowpersonally.Intoday'smarketplace,informationconcerningpastpurchasesisincreasinglyoftensummarizedandreadilyavailableintheformofbestsellerlists.Bestsellerlistsarecompiledforgoodsasdiverseasbooks,music,DVDs,movies,computergames,electronicgadgetsandhouseholdappliances.1Thispaperaimstomeasuretheeffectontheconsumers'willingnesstopayofchangesinthepublicinformationconcerningthebestsellerrankofproducts.Theprimarycontributionofthepaperistoprovideempiricalevidencethatthepast 1TherstbestsellerlistofbookswaspublishedintheU.S.byTheBookmanin1895(seeBassettandWalter2001).Publishers'Weeklycompileditsrstbestsellerlistin1913.TheinuentialNewYorkTimesbestsellerlistwasrstpublishedin1942.Therstmusicbestsellerlist(thencalledahitparade)wasrstpublishedbyBillboardMagazinein1940.Currently,manyretailerspublishbestsellerlistsforseveralcategoriesofgoods.Amazon.com,forinstance,displaysonitswebsitehourly-updatedbestsellerlistsforabout30productcategoriesincludingbooks,electronics,automotive,homeimprovement,andgroceryandgourmetfood.2 expectedvalueofthesedifferencesisinvariant,estimatescanbecomputedusingsimulationmethods.Priortopurchasinganapp,consumersmaybecomeawareofthedownloadranksofthetopappsduringthepreviousday.Sincedownloadrankschangesig-nicantlyovertime,priorrankingscanbeusedasaregressortomeasuretheeffectofthepublicrankinformationontheconsumers'willingnesstopayinthepresentperiod.Animportantconcernintheevaluationofestimationresultsisthepossibleendogeneityofprevioussalesranks.Whileyesterday'srankscannotbeaffectedbytheunobservablesthataffectappdemandstoday,itispossiblethattheshocksthataffectthedemandforaproductarecorrelatedovertime.Ifso,yesterday'srankswouldbecorrelatedwithtoday'sdemandshocksandtheleast-squaresestimatesoftheranks'effectondemandneednotreectacausalrelationshipbetweenrankinformationandwillingnesstopay.Theinstitutionaldetailsoftheappmarketsuggestgoodproxiesforthepastrankinformationthatareuncorrelatedwiththedemandshocks.Thelistoftop100appsisdisplayedonseveralscreens.Thenumberofappsperscreenvariesfromdevicetodevice,buttheranks25and50providenaturalbreakpointsforthevisibilityofapps.Forinstance,onboththeiphoneandtheipodtouchdevicesthetopvedownloadedappsappearontherstscreen,thentheappswithranks6to25canbebrowsedbyscrollingdowncontinuously.Theranks26-50arethenavailablebyfollowingalinkthatappearsontherstscreenjustbelowtheappwithrank25.AsinstrumentsforthelaggedranksIusethemovementsofpastsalesranksfromaparticularrankofranks,asdeterminedbythesebreakpoints.Thesemovementsarecorrelatedwiththepastranks,butuncorrelatedwiththecurrentdemandshocks.Theestimationresultsindicatethatthepositionofanapponthelistofprevious-periodbestsellersisanimportantdeterminantofpresent-perioddemands.There-sultsshowthat,allelseequal,thewillingnesstopayofconsumersisdecreasingsteeplywiththesalesrankofanapp.Forinstance,thevalueattributabletotheprevious-periodrankof1isroughlytwiceaslargeasthecorrespondingvalueforrank2.2Inturn,thevalueattributabletorank2isabout30%largerthanthecorre-spondingvalueforanappwithrank3.Onlineretailerscommonlycompileandprominentlydisplaybestsellerlists.Giventhecostofdoingso,theseretailersmustgainsomeeconomicadvantage.Re- 2Asformostbestsellerlists,increasingrankscorrespondtolesspopularproducts.4 therstconsumerpreferstoactliketheothers.Theformeriscalledexpectationin-teractionandthelatteriscalledpreferenceinteraction.Manski(2000)emphasizedthatitisimportantforanalysisandforpolicytodistinguishbetweenexpectationinteractionsandpreferenceinteractions.Inourmarket,whenchoosingaproduct,aconsumermayfollowotherconsumersbecauseshebelievesthattheothercon-sumershavebetterinformation,orbecauseshehasapreferenceforimitation.Consumersendowedwithbestsellerinformationmayalsofollowothercon-sumersbecausetheybelievethatanyidiosyncraticnoisethataffectstheirproductqualityexpectationsdoesnotaffecttheaggregateconsumptiondecisions.Inreality,weknowverylittleaboutthereasonswhyconsumersfollowotherconsumers.Itislikelythatintheappmarketexpectationinteractionsareatworkinshapingthepur-chasedecisionsoftheconsumers.Theanonimityofbestsellerlistsmaydampentheroleofpreferenceinteractionsinmarkets.Inanycase,thepresentanalysismain-tainsanagnosticviewabouttheparticularmechanismthroughwhichtheaggregateconsumptiondecisionsofthecrowdaffectconsumers'preferences.Thispaperiscloselyrelatedtotwopapersthatinvestigatetheimpactoncon-sumersoflearningaboutthepastconsumptionchoicesofotherconsumers.TherstpaperbyCai,ChenandFang(2009)reportsresultsofarandomizedeldexperi-mentconductedinarestaurantsetting.Theirexperimentisdesignedtodistinguishbetweentheinformationaleffectofexpandingtheconsumers'knowledgeofthechoiceset(calledthesaliencyeffect)andtheinformationaleffectofobservationallearning.Theauthorsprovideevidencethatthedemandsforthemostpopularvedishesincreasesignicantlyasaresultofrevealinginformationabouttherankingofthetopvedishes.Theyndlittlesupportforthehypothesisthatsalesaredrivenbyasaliencyeffect.Theresultsoftheircontrolledeldexperimentsindicatethatmostoftheincreaseinthesalesofthetopdishesoccurasaresultofobservationallearning.Theauthorssuggestthatapartialexplanationforthecommonpracticeofdisplayingpopularityinformationonretailers'websitesisobservationallearning.Thepresentpaperbringsanewcontributiontothisvaluableinsightbyprovidingdirectmarketevidencethatpopularityinformationaffectsdemands.Cai,ChenandFang(2009)consider“lumpy”informationaleffectsinthesensethattheeffectofrevealinginformationaboutthemostpopulardishisnotdistinguishedfromtheeffectofrevealinginformationaboutthesubsequentfourpopulardishes.Icomple-menttheirndingsbyprovidingestimatesofhowdemandsareaffectedbyeachof6 retaintheassumptionthatsalesfollowapowerlaw,myestimationprocedureisdif-ferentfromtheproceduresdevelopedbyChevalierandGoolsbeeandBrynjolfsson,HuandSmith,andpermitsestimationofthedemandparametersofinterestwithoutknowledgeoftheparametersofthepowerlaw.Peoplehaveaperhapsinnatetendencytojointhecrowd.AstheexperimentsofMigram,BickmanandBerkowitz(1969)suggest,thismayhappenevenwhenthepeopleinthecrowddolittleelsethanstareattheemptysky.Thetendencytojointhecrowdcouldimplythatindividualsperceiveadistincteconomicadvantagefromfollowingtheactionsofothers.Ifso,onemayexpecttoseethatpopularitybegetspopularityinmarketswherepopularityispublic.Theexperimentalnd-ingsofCai,ChenandFang(2009)andSalganik,DoddandWatts(2006)showthatpopularitybegetspopularityintwoimportantmarkets.Popularityalsobegetspopularityinthenewsmedia,asshownbyThorson(2008).Heranalysisindicatesthatmost-emailedlistsdisplayedintheon-lineeditionsofnewspapersliketheNewYorkTimesandLosAngelesTimes,aswellasthelargerfamilyofnewsrecommen-dationengines,affectconsumersbehaviorbyprovidingconsumerswithnewwaystonavigateinformation.Citationsofacademicresearchseemtofollowasimilarpopularitypattern.7Thereisverylittlewrittenintheeconomicsliteratureonthesubjectofbest-sellerlists.Sorensen(2007)analyzestheimpactoftheNewYorkTimesbestsellerlistonsalesandonproductvariety.Hendsthatthelistingofabookonthebest-sellerlistcausesamodestincreaseinsales.Theobjectiveofthisresearch,likeoneofSorensen's(2007)researchobjectives,istomeasuretheeffectofbestsellerinformationondemand.Theavailabilityofpricesisthemosttangibleadvantageofthedataavailableforthisstudy.Becauseoflimitedinformationonsalesprices,Sorensenwasabletoonlyfocusonhowbestsellerstatusaffectstheautocorrelationofsales.Sincetheappmarketdatacontaindetailedpriceinformation,thisstudyinvestigateshowbothpricesandbestsellerstatusaffectproductdemands.Iturnnexttoashortpresentationoftheinstitutionaldetailsofthesoftwaremarketandofthedata. 7SeeMerton's(1968)discussionofthe“Mattheweffect”inscience.Foranopposingview,seeSimkinandRoychowdhury(2005),whoarguethatcitationsgeneratedaccordingtoaprocessbywhichascientistpicksthreepapersatrandom,citesthem,andalsorandomlycopiesaquarterofthesepapers'referenceststheempiricalcitationdistributionquitewell.8 throughamobileappstoreinterface,orthroughawiredconnectiontoapersonalcomputer.Theinterfaceforthewireddownloadisamulti-platformprogramcalleditunesthatisdevelopedandofferedasafreedownloadbyApple.Downloadsre-quireauserIDandapassword.ConsumersareuniquelyidentiedbytheiruserID.InordertoregisterwithApple,aconsumermustprovideavalidcreditcardnumberandthecard'sbillingaddress.Theverylargenumberofappsinthestoremakesitimpracticalforconsumerstosampleoftheentiresetofapps.Appleiswellawareofthisfactandfacilitatestheprocessofproductdiscoverybyconsumers.Itprovidesprominentlydisplayedlinkstothemostdownloadedappsbothonthemobileappinterfaceandontheitunesprogram.Importantly,themobileappstoreinterfacedisplaysonitsmainpagelinkstothetop25mostdownloadedfreeandpaidproducts,andranks26-50areavailablebyfollowingasubsequentlink.SeeFigure3intheAppendix.Thewireditunesinterfacealsoprominentlydisplaysthetop10freeandpaidappsonitsrstpage.Listsofthetop100mostdownloadedfreeandpaidappsareavailableintheitunesinterfaceoneclickawayfromthemainstorepage.Inadditiontotheselists,Applefacilitatesproductdiscoverybyconsumersthroughlistsoffeaturedproductsand,ontheitunesinterface,stafffavoriteproducts.Also,Appleprovideslistsofmostdownloadedappsbycategoryandallowsconsumerstosearchproductsbyname.12Developersandindustryexpertsperceivethetop100freeandpaidlistsasthemostimportantwaysforconsumerstolearnaboutapps.Importantly,sinceappsaresoldinmanycountries,therankingsarecomputedseparatelyforeachofthemorethan60countrystores.ThedataemployedinthepresentpaperconcernthedownloadranksofappssoldintheUnitedStatesstore,whichisthelargeststoreintermsofnumberofappssold.Asidefromreleasingquarterlyaggregatedownloadgures,Appledoesnotre-leaseinformationaboutthenumberofappsappdownloadedfromitsstore.Impor-tantly,Applehasnotreleasedanyinformationaboutthedetailsofcomputingthetop100mostdownloadedapps.Theinformationavailableconcerningthecomputationofdownloadranksis 12InSeptember2009,withthereleaseofitunes9.0,Applehasaddedalistofthetop100grossingappstothepreviouslypublishedlistsoftop100freeandtop100paidappsbythenumberofdownloads.10 paidapps.Sincetheempiricalpartofthispaperusesonlydataonpaidapps,Inowdiscusssomeofthecharacteristicsofthepaidappdata.Theaveragepriceofapaidappduringtheobservationperiodwas$2.72,withastandarddeviationof$2.25.Theminimumpriceofanappwas$0.99,andthemaximumpricewasasizable$29.99.Themedianpriceofanappduringtheobservationperiodwas$1.99.Onaverage,apaidappappearsinthetop100mostdownloadedliston31days.However,theappsthathaveatleastoncereachedthetop50appearonthetop100listforanaverageof45days,andtheappsthathavereachedthetop10appearonthetop100listforanaverageof63days.Thedistributionofthenumberofdaysonthe100mostdownloadedlistishighlyskewed,asindicatedbythemediannumberofdaysonthelistequalto18.Thisskewnessindicatesthatafewappssurviveonthelistforalongtime.Some15appsremainedonthetop100listfortheentireobservationperiod.However,mostappsremainonthetop100listforthreeweeksorless.Someappsappearonthetop100list,thenleavethelistandreturntothelistaftersometime.Thisprocessmayrepeatafewtimesforafewappsinthedata.Figure1displaysahistogramofthenumberofdaysonthetop100mostdownloadedlistapp.14 14Clearly,thenumberofdaysonthelistforappsthatenteredthelistatthebeginningandtowardtheendoftheobservationperiodisnotaccurate.However,thesamehighlyskeweddistributionofnumberofdaysonthelistobtainswhenIdroptheappsthatenteredthelistduringtherstandlast20daysoftheobservationperiod.Notableisthat15appshavesurvivedonthelistduringtheentireobservationperiod.12 r(j;t�1)ofproductjattimet�1,themeanutilityprovidedtoconsumersisgivenbydjt=Xjb�a�Pjt�Mr(j;t�1);(1)whereXjarecharacteristicsofproductj,Pjtisthepriceofproductjattimet,andMi(i=1;:::;100)aretherank-dependentparametersofprincipalinterestinestimation.Consumeriderivesrandomutilityuijtfromchoosingproductjattimet,givenby:uijt=djt+ej+ejt+xijt;(2)whereejtisani.i.d.,acrossproductsandacrosstime,disturbancerepresentingj'sunobservedcomponentofutilityattimet,ejrepresentsaproductxedeffect,andtheshocksxijtaredistributedindependentlyacrossconsumers,productsandtimeaccordingtotheType-Iextremevaluedistribution.16Assumption1isconsistentwithevidencefromappdevelopersandindustryanalyststhatproductsalesintheuppertailofthesalesdistributionaregovernedbyapowerlaw.Forthedevelopersthatmadepublictheirappranksandsales,apowerlawappearstottheirdataquitewell.17Importantly,Iassumeapowerlawdistributionofunitsalesonlyintheuppertailofthedistributionofsales,notfortheentiredistribution.Assumption2ismostlikelyinnocuousinlargemarkets.Itmakespossiblethecalculationoflogmarketsharesandensuresthatthesupportofsalesintheuppertailisboundedawayfromzero.Assumption3isstandardintheempiricalliteratureondiscreteconsumerchoice(seeBerry1994).Thedifferencebetweenthemean-utilityspecicationin(1)andtheutilityspecicationinthestandarddiscretechoicemodelisthepresenceoftheparametersM.Theseparametersrepresentchangesinwillingnesstopaythatareduetorankinginformation.PositivevaluesoftheparametersMrepresentincreasesinthewillingnesstopayofconsumers,whilenegativevaluesrepresentdecreasesinthewillingnesstopay.ThefollowinglemmaprovidesarelationshipbetweenthethesalesrankingsofproductsanddifferencesinmarketsharesundertheassumptionthatsalesarePareto 16Whilethetheoreticalmodelassumesthatthedisturbanceejtisi.i.d.,inSection5Idiscussthepossibleimplicationsofautocorrelationandprovidesomerobustnesschecks.17Onesuchaccountisatwww.joelcomm.com/app_store_ranktosales_revealed.html.15 parametersexpressthedifferencesinconsumerutilitythatresultfromthepublicinformationconcerningthemarketshareranksofaproductattimet�1.Totheextentthattheutilityofconsumerswhochooseaproducttodayisaffectedbythepublicinformationconcerningthemarketshareranksofproductsyesterday,oneexpectstheestimatesofrank-dependentparametersMtobesignicantlydifferentfromzero.Estimatingequation(4)iscomplicatedbythepossibleendogeneityofpriceandlaggedranks.Thispossibleendogeneityisdiscussedinthenextsection.Thexedproducteffectshelptocaptureanyunobservablecomponentsofproductqualitythataretime-invariantandmaybecorrelatedwithpriceorwithpreviousranks.Theavailabledatadonotallowthedirectestimationof(4).Note,however,thatthemarketshareoftheproductwithdownloadrankk+1attimetcanbeexpressedaslnsk+1;t�lns0t=Xk+1b�a�Pk+1t�Mr(k+1;t�1)+ek+1+ek+1t:(5)Subtracting(5)from(4),wehavelnskt�lnsk+1;t=ˆXktb�a�ˆPkt�Mr(k;t�1)+Mr(k+1;t�1)+ˆek+(ekt�ek+1t);(6)whereˆXkt=Xkt�Xk+1;t,ˆPkt=Pkt�Pk+1;tandˆekisthedifferencebetweenthexedeffectsthatcorrespondtotheproductswithdownloadrankskandk+1.Noticethat(6)doesnotcontaintheshareoftheoutsidegood.However,thedifferencesinmarketsharesonthelefthandsidearenotobserved.Lemma1showsthatwhensalesareParetodistributed,thelefthandsideof(6)isexponentiallydistributed.Ifrescaledappropriately,theparameterofthedistributionthatgovernsthelefthandsidedifferencesisnotdependentontheparameterstobeestimated.Accordingly,theseunobservedmarketsharescanbesimulatedandtheequationofinterestcanbeestimatedasifmarketshareswereknown.ReplicatingtheprocessmanytimeswithdifferentdrawsofthelefthandsidevariablepermitsestimationofthecoefcientsM.Arelationshipbetweentherank-specicvaluesMandthesalesranksofthetopproductscanbeformulatedbasedonthefollowingtheorem.Theorem1Givenassumptions1-3,fork21;:::;99andfort1;thefollowinghold:i.ykt=kq(lnskt�lnsk+1t)arei.i.d.exponentiallydistributedwithmean17 ofsalesneednotbethesame.ThereasonisthatthelocationparameterSmtofthepowerlawisallowedtovaryovertime.Thevariationofthisparameterdoesnotaffecttheresultsbecauseintheestimationprocedurethisparameterisdifferencedaway.Iturnnexttoadiscussionoftheestimationprocedureandoftheresults.5EstimationandResults5.1EstimationProcedureThissectionprovidesdetailsabouttheestimationprocedureanddiscussesthepo-tentialbiasesthatmayariseduetotheendogeneityofsomevariables.Inthedata,anobservationisadate-ranktuple(t;k;j)thatcorrespondstoappj.Thereare13;996date-rank-apptuplesinthedata.AppsareuniquelyidentiedinthedatabytheirIDcode.DenotedbyM=(M1;M2;:::;M100)isthevectorofrank-specicvaluationstobeestimated.Whiletheappxedeffectshelptocaptureanyunobservedcomponentsofquality,apossibleconcernisthatpricesareendogenousinthefollowingdynamicsense.Therearemorethan400apppricechangesinthedata.Manyofthesepricechangesappeartobecausedbychangesindownloadranks.If,forinstance,developerswhoseedecliningdownloadranksfortheirappstendtoreducethepriceoftheirapps,asthefolkloreontheonlinedeveloperforumssuggests,thenpricewouldbeendogenousin(7)andtheestimatedpricecoefcientwouldbebiased.Iinstrumentthepricevariableusingthelogarithmoflaggedsalesranks.Sincechangesindownloadranksdonotimmediatelytriggerpricechanges,Iuselagsofordertwoandthreeofthesalesranksaspriceinstruments.Bothpriceinstrumentsarestronglysignicantintherststage.Unitmeanpseudo-randomexponentialvariablesweregeneratedusingamul-tiplicativecongruentialrandomnumbergenerator(seeKennedyandGentle1980,pp.136-147).ThesevariablesaretheˆYsontheleft-hand-sideoftheestimatingequation:ˆY=K=ˆX(aM;a;b;e)+ˆe;(12)whereKdenotesthevectorofcurrentappranksandanasteriskdenotesparametersthataremultiples(byq)oftheparametersofinterest.ThedatamatrixˆXcontains19 Figure2:Rank-SpecicValues5.3Auto-correlatedDemandShocksAnimportantconcernforestimationisthepossibleendogeneityoftheprevious-dayrankdummiesintheestimatingequation12.Whileyesterday'sdownloadranksarenotaffectedbytheshocksthataffectappdemandstoday,demandshocksforaproductmaybeseriallycorrelated.Thiswouldcauseyesterday'srankstobecorrelatedwithtoday'sdemandshocks.Ineffect,themeasuredeffectofranksondemandcouldreectthisautocorrelationandnotadirecteffectofrankinformationondemand.Toseewhetherendogeneitycouldaffecttheresultsofestimation,theeffectofyesterday'sranksmaybeestimatedusingthemethodofinstrumentalvariables.However,giventherelativedearthofvariablesinthedata,obtainingcrediblein-strumentsforallthepastrankvariablesisimpractical.18Instead,aspecicationisusedthatrestrictsthecoefcientsMtobeproportionalwiththereciprocaloftheprevioussalesrank.Thereciprocalofpreviousranksmaybeinstrumentedusingmovementsof 18Moregranularmovementstoandfromparticularrankranges(e.g.,toandfromranks1-5,6-10,etc.)couldprovidegoodinstrumentsfortheprevious-dayrankvariables.Itturnsoutthatwhilemanyoftheseinstrumentsaresignicant,thegoodnessoftformostoftherst-stageregressionsispoor(mostrst-stageFstatisticsarelowerthan4).Notsurprisingly,giventheweakinstruments,thesecond-stageestimatesoftheeffectofpublicrankinformationondemandwereverynoisy.21 second-laggedrankstoandfromparticularrankrangesthatarenaturalbreakpointsinthewaythetoplistisdisplayed.Clearly,movementsofpastdownloadranksfromonerankrangetoanotherarecorrelatedwithcurrentranks.Becausetheappsinthebestsellerlistaredisplayedsequentially,appsdisplayedatthetopofthebest-sellerlistmayreceivemoreattentionfromconsumersthanappsatthebottomofthelist.Anappthathasjustmadethetop50(or25)ismorelikelytomaintainitstoprankingthananotherappthathasnotjustcrossedsuchathreshold.Ineffect,thein-creasedvisibilityofanappmayaffectitssubsequentsalesrank.Importantly,whilemovementsofrankstwodaysagoacrossvariousthresholdsarecorrelatedwithyes-terday'sranks,thesemovementsareunlikelytobecorrelatedwithtoday'sdemandshocks.Inprinciple,theserankmovementsaregoodinstrumentsforyesterday'sranks.TheestimatedparametersMareclosetotheestimateoftheimpactofprevioussalesrankondemandobtainedbyrestrictingtheparametersMtobeproportionalwiththereciprocalofthesalesrank.Theestimatedcoefcientonthereciprocalofsalesrankisequalto4.29,withastandarderrorof0.48.Theestimatedim-pactofsalesranksondemandcomputedusingthisestimate,bracketedbya95%condenceinterval,isdepictedinFigure2withthethinnercontinuousgreenline.Toaddressthepotentialendogeneityofpricesandprevioussalesranks,thesevariableswereinstrumentedusingthelagsofordertwoandthreeofsalesranks,aswellastwobinaryvariablesthatmeasurewhetherthetwice-laggedsalesrankofanapphasreachedthelistoftop50orthetop25appsfrombelow.Allinstrumentsarestronglysignicantintherststageregressions.FirststageresultsaresummarizedinTable6intheAppendix.Asindicatedbytheresultsofover-identicationtests,thenullhypothesisthattheinstrumentsandtheerrortermin(12)areorthogonalwasnotrejected.19Theinstrumentalvariablesestimateofthereciprocalofpastrankcoefcientwasequalto4.37,withastandarderrorof0.49;noticethatthisisonlyslightlyhigherthantheordinaryleastsquarescoefcientof4.29.20Thisndingisastrongindica-tionthatserialcorrelationisunlikelytobeacauseofconcernwhentheparametersofinterestMareestimatedbyordinaryleastsquares. 19ThemaximumvalueoftheSarganstatisticwas1.6,lowerthanthe1%c2(2)criticalvalueof9.21.ThemeanvalueoftheSarganstatisticforthe10,000simulationrunswas0.73.20TheIVcoefcientsandtheirstandarderrorsaregiveninTable5intheAppendix.22 product;italsoindicatesthatthelistsofnewlyreleasedappsmadepublicbyApplemayhavelittleeffectonconsumerchoice.However,asimpliedbythenegativeandsignicantcoefcientontheversionagevariable(VAge),demandislowerforappsthatarenotregularlyupdated.Theestimateofthepricecoefcientisnegative,asexpected,andstronglysig-nicant.Sincetheestimatedcoefcientisthetheunknownscaleparameterofthepowerlawmultipliedbythetruepricecoefcient,own-priceelasticitiesarenotidentied.Theinterpretationoftheempiricalresultsissubjecttoacaveat.Sinceappscouldreachalarge,butnitenumberofpotentialconsumers,itispossiblethatthedemandsforsomeproductsbecomesaturatedovertime.Iattempttocontrolforthissaturationeffectbyusingtheageofanappasadeterminantofdemand.Theesti-matedcoefcientsonbothappageanditssquarewerepositiveandsignicant.Inaddition,surveyevidence(seefootnote15)indicatesthatmorethanhalfofiphoneandipodtouchusersdownloadlessthanonepaidapppermonth.Additionally,thedataindicatethatthemeansurvivaltimeforanapponthemostdownloadedlistisclosetoamonth.Thesesuggestthatsaturationisnotlikelytosignicantlyaffecttheresults.Giventherelativelylargeestimatedvalueattributedbyconsumerstotheappsrankedontopofthebestsellinglist,itispuzzlingwhytopappsdonotmaintaintheirranksforlongerperiodsthanobserved.Acandidateansweristhattherearemanyfactorsotherthanrankingsthataffectconsumerchoice.Forinstance,adver-tisingbyAppleandconversionoffreelydownloadableappsintopaidonesplayanimportantroleinshapingconsumerpreferences.Withthehelpofadditionaldataonadvertisingandconversionoffreeapps,theeffectoffactorsotherthanpastapprankingsthataffectconsumerchoicemaybeidentied.6ConclusionsThemodelsofherdingandinformationcascadesofBanerjee(1992),Bikhchandani,HirshleiferandWelch(1992)andWelch(1992)haveanalyzedinteractionsbetweenconsumersthatmaygiverisetoinefcientoutcomes.Thesemodelsofbehaviorassumetheexistenceofcertainformsoflearningfromtheactionsofothers.Test-ingthisassumptionmayturnouttobecriticalforourunderstandingofeconomic24 importantcostofusingtheprocedureisadrasticreductionintherangeofempiricalmodelsofdiscreteconsumerchoicethatcanbetakentothedata.26 Variable Description Count Mean Stdev Median Min Max ID UniqueappIDnumber 452 Rank Apprankontop100list 13,996 47.86 28.35 47 1 100 L(Rank) Laggedrank 13,996 46.76 27.50 46 1 101 L2(Rank) Secondlag 13,996 46.07 26.96 45 1 100 L3(Rank) Thirdlag 13,996 46.09 27.06 45 1 100 Price PriceinUSDollars 13,996 2.72 2.25 1.99 0.99 29.99 Age Dayssincerstrelease 13,996 109.40 83.15 85 0 340 VAge Ageofcurrentversion 13,996 92.63 75.85 66 0 340 Size Appsize(megabytes) 13,996 17.20 29.11 7.8 0 412 NewVer NewVersionDummy 13,996 0.0162 0.1263 0 0 1 Table1:SummaryStatisticsNotes:Laggedrank101correspondstoapreviouslyunrankedapp.Thesizeofappsisroundedtothenearesttenthofamegabyte,sooneapp(forwhichtherearevetotalobservations)hasasizeofzero.Thesquaresofage,versionageandsizeusedintheregressionsbelowarenormalized.28 Variable Estimate Stderr t-value Variable Estimate Stderr t-value M61 0.1254 0.0252 4.9787 M85 -0.0189 0.005 -3.7812 M62 0.1142 0.0234 4.8734 M86 -0.0481 0.0098 -4.9196 M63 0.1298 0.026 5.0001 M87 0.0041 0.0036 1.1293 M64 0.1497 0.0301 4.9815 M88 -0.0061 0.0037 -1.6292 M65 0.0523 0.011 4.7531 M89 -0.0114 0.0039 -2.9459 M66 0.141 0.029 4.8551 M90 0.0555 0.0121 4.6004 M67 0.0792 0.0164 4.8328 M91 -0.0286 0.0065 -4.414 M68 0.062 0.0132 4.6888 M92 -0.05 0.0102 -4.8778 M69 0.0719 0.0151 4.7558 M93 -0.0287 0.0066 -4.3501 M70 0.055 0.0119 4.628 M94 0.0017 0.0039 0.4408 M71 0.0475 0.0103 4.6112 M95 -0.0613 0.0124 -4.9495 M72 0.0478 0.0103 4.66 M96 -0.0096 0.0037 -2.6214 M73 0.0782 0.0161 4.8609 M97 -0.1022 0.0201 -5.0721 M74 0.0204 0.0056 3.6263 M98 -0.013 0.0038 -3.3996 M75 0.0391 0.009 4.3517 M99 -0.0768 0.0153 -5.0348 M76 0.0553 0.012 4.6115 M100 -0.0697 0.0141 -4.9563 M77 -0.0052 0.0036 -1.4208 Price(a) -0.4707 0.095 -4.9572 M78 0.0603 0.0129 4.6603 Age 0.0069 0.0014 4.8745 M79 0.0327 0.0078 4.1673 Age2 0.2235 0.0427 5.2299 M80 0.0093 0.0042 2.193 Vage -0.0089 0.0018 -4.9586 M81 -0.0182 0.0048 -3.753 VAge2 -0.0147 0.0047 -3.1109 M82 0.0202 0.0057 3.5561 NewVer -0.0333 0.012 -2.7833 M83 -0.0417 0.0087 -4.8152 Size 0.0004 0.0006 0.6839 M84 0.0053 0.0037 1.4373 Size2 6.0596 1.2425 4.8769 Table2:EstimationResultsNotes:Notreportedarethecoefcientsonappdummies(417coefcientsweresignicantatthe10%condencelevel).Theestimatingequationis(12).Priceisinstrumentedusingthelogarithmsoftwice-andthrice-laggedranks;therst-stageFstatisticisequalto437.19(R2is0.95).Meansandstandarderrorsarecomputedusing10,000replications.30 Variable Estimate Stderr t-value Variable Estimate Stderr t-value M61 0.2666 0.0086 30.9159 M81 -0.0389 0.0085 -4.5635 M62 0.2426 0.0091 26.556 M82 0.0429 0.0086 4.9976 M63 0.2761 0.009 30.8259 M83 -0.0888 0.0079 -11.1993 M64 0.3183 0.0086 36.9556 M84 0.0111 0.0079 1.4143 M65 0.1113 0.0088 12.7127 M85 -0.0401 0.0078 -5.1524 M66 0.2993 0.0087 34.5094 M86 -0.1026 0.0081 -12.7142 M67 0.1684 0.009 18.693 M87 0.0084 0.0078 1.0831 M68 0.1316 0.0088 15.0381 M88 -0.0131 0.0084 -1.5608 M69 0.1527 0.0088 17.2784 M89 -0.0244 0.0076 -3.2073 M70 0.1167 0.0088 13.3079 M90 0.1178 0.0081 14.5665 M71 0.1009 0.0081 12.5227 M91 -0.0608 0.0078 -7.8078 M72 0.1016 0.0083 12.3041 M92 -0.1064 0.008 -13.3759 M73 0.1662 0.008 20.7469 M93 -0.0611 0.0078 -7.7782 M74 0.0432 0.0082 5.2984 M94 0.0033 0.0088 0.3712 M75 0.083 0.0087 9.4914 M95 -0.1305 0.0083 -15.6426 M76 0.1173 0.0081 14.5286 M96 -0.0207 0.0078 -2.6512 M77 -0.0111 0.0081 -1.3722 M97 -0.2174 0.0072 -30.2328 M78 0.1279 0.0078 16.3914 M98 -0.0283 0.0088 -3.1959 M79 0.0692 0.008 8.6572 M99 -0.1636 0.0081 -20.1672 M80 0.0195 0.0083 2.3649 M100 -0.1484 0.0081 -18.2835 Table3:Rank-DependentValuesNotes:ReportedvaluesarethemeansandstandarddeviationsoftheratiosbetweentheestimatesofMandtheestimateofafor10,000replications.Theestimatingequationis(12).ThevalueofM101wasnormalizedtozero.32 Figure3:TopAppsDisplayedontheMobileInterface34 [2009]Conley,TimothyG.andChristopherR.Udry(2009),“LearningAboutaNewTechnology:PineappleinGhana,”forthcoming,AmericanEconomicReview[2002]Duo,EstherandEmmanuelSaez(2002),“ParticipationandInvestmentDecisionsinaRetirementPlan:TheInuenceofColleagues'Choices,”JournalofPublicEconomics85(1),pp.121-148[1995]Foster,AndrewD.andMarkR.Rosenzweig(1995),“LearningbyDoingandLearningfromOthers:HumanCapitalandTechnicalChangeinAgri-culture,”JournalofPoliticalEconomy103(6),pp.1176-1209[1980]Kennedy,WilliamJ.,Jr.,andJamesE.Gentle(1980),StatisticalComput-ing,MarcelDekker,Inc.,NY[1950]Leibenstein,Harvey(1950),“Bandwagon,Snob,andVeblenEffectsintheTheoryofConsumers'Demand,”QuarterlyJournalofEconomics,64(2),pp.183-207[2000]Manski,Charles(2000),“EconomicAnalysisofSocialInteractions,”Jour-nalofEconomicPerspectives14(3),pp.115-136[1995]Mason,Roger(1995),“InterpersonalEffectsonConsumerDemandinEco-nomicTheoryandMarketingThought,1890-1950,”JournalofEconomicIssues29(3),pp.871-881[1978]McFadden,Daniel(1978),“ModellingtheChoiceofResidentialLocation,”inSpatialInteractionTheoryandPlanningModels,A.Karlqvistetal.(eds.),Amsterdam:NorthHolland[1968]Merton,RobertK.(1968),“TheMatthewEffectinScience,”Science159,pp.56-63[1969]Milgram,Stanley,LeonardBickmanandLawrenceBerkowitz(1969),“NoteontheDrawingPowerofCrowdsofDifferentSize,”JournalofPer-sonalityandSocialPsychology13(2),pp.79-82.[1948]Morgenstern,Oskar(1948),“DemandTheoryReconsidered,”QuarterlyJournalofEconomics62,pp.165-20136 [2009]Zhang,Juanjuan(2009),“TheSoundofSilence:ObservationalLearningintheU.S.KidneyMarket,”forthcoming,MarketingScience38

Related Contents


Next Show more