/
IZA Discussion Paper No. 3112 IZA Discussion Paper No. 3112

IZA Discussion Paper No. 3112 - PDF document

marina-yarberry
marina-yarberry . @marina-yarberry
Follow
369 views
Uploaded On 2016-03-15

IZA Discussion Paper No. 3112 - PPT Presentation

October 2007 ABSTRACT Dismissals for Cause The Difference That Just Eight Paragraphs Can Make This paper provides evidence about the effects of dismissalsforcause requirements a specific comp ID: 256758

October 2007 ABSTRACT Dismissals for

Share:

Link:

Embed:

Download Presentation from below link

Download Pdf The PPT/PDF document "IZA Discussion Paper No. 3112" is the property of its rightful owner. Permission is granted to download and print the materials on this web site for personal, non-commercial use only, and to display it on your personal computer provided you do not modify the materials and that you retain all copyright notices contained in the materials. By downloading content from our website, you accept the terms of this agreement.


Presentation Transcript

IZA Discussion Paper No. 3112 October 2007 ABSTRACT Dismissals for Cause: The Difference That Just Eight Paragraphs Can Make * This paper provides evidence about the effects of dismissals-for-cause requirements, a specific component of employment protection legislation that has received little attention despite its potential relevance. We study a quasi-natural experiment generated by a law introduced in Portugal in 1989: out of the 12 paragraphs in the law that dictated the costly procedure required for dismissals for cause, eight did not apply to firms employing 20 or fewer workers. Using detailed matched employer-employee longitudinal data and difference-in-differences matching methods, we examine the impact of that differentiated change in firing costs upon several variables, measured from 1991 to 1999. Unlike predicted by theory, we do not find robust evidence of effects on worker flows. However, firm performance improves considerably while wages fall. Overall, the results suggest that firing costs of the type studied here decrease workers’ effort and increase their bargaining power. JEL Classification: E24, J64, J65 Keywords: employment protection legislation, worker flows, wages, firm performance Corresponding author: Pedro S. Martins School of Business and Management Queen Mary, University of London Mile End Road London E1 4NS United Kingdom E-mail: p.martins@qmul.ac.uk * I am grateful to Alcides Martins (Alcides Martins & Associados) for helping me with the very detailed Portuguese employment law. I also thank Dick Allard, Giulio Fella, Winfried Koeniger and Eshref Trushin for detailed comments and the ESRC (RES-062-23-0546) and for research support. All views and any errors in this paper are of my responsibility only. sensethatthose ringconstraintsmaystrengthenthebargainingpowerofincumbentworkersvis-a-vistheiremployers,whilethelattertendtoberegardedasthestrongerpartinthebargainingprocess.Inanycase,thelegalproceduressurroundingdismissalsforcausecaninducedeadweightlosses,asthecostsborneby rmswhencarryingoutsuchdismissalsarenotrecoupedbytheworkersa ected.Thosedeadweightlossescanthenresultininecientlylownumbersofseparationsand,indirectly,alsoininecientlylownumbersofhirings.Moreover,whileonecanarguethatemployersmaybeabletobargainwithworkersoveracompensationpaymentlargeenoughforthelattertoaccepttoquit,adverseselectionproblemsmaymakesuchapproachparticularlycostlyfor rms(ifworkerstobe redhaveworseoutsideoptions,theyarelikelytodemandhighercompensationpayments).Furthermore,if rmscircumventtheconstraintsimposedbyEPLbymakingcompensationpaymentstoworkersthatunderperformorthathavedisciplinaryproblems,thatmayundermineworkermorale(Bewley1999)andreducethelevelsofe ortoftheremainingworkforce.3Inthispaper,weseektoassessthecausalimpactoftheadministrativeproceduresthatrestrict ringsforcause.Asfarasweknow,wearethe rsttoexamineempiricallytheroleofthisspeci ccomponentofEPL.Ouranalysisisbasedonaquasi-naturalexperimentthatoccurredinPortugal,acountrywellknownforitsverystrictEPL(Blanchard&Portugal2001,OECD2004,Boteroetal.2004).Speci cally,theexperimentresultsfromanewlawgoverningemployeedismissalsintroducedin1989,underwhich ringconstraintswerereducedforall rms.However, rmsemploying20orfeweremployees(unlikelarger rms)wereexemptedfromanumberofadministrativerestrictionsregardingdismissalsforcause.Moreover,sinceuntilthentherewasnodi erentiationin ringconstraintsacross rmsintermsoftheirsizeorothercharacteristics,onecansetupadi erence-in-di erencesanalysis,bycontrastingtheoutcomesof`smaller'and`larger' rms,beforeandafter1989.Aswecandrawonparticularlydetailedpaneldata,wealsoconductadi erence-in-di erencespropensityscorematchinganalysis,inordertominimiseanybiasdrivenbyun-observeddi erencesandbydi erencesinthecommonsupportacrossthetwo rmtypesandtheirworkers(Heckmanetal.1998).Thisisthe rststudyintheEPLliteraturethatadoptsthisspeci cempiricalapproach.Finally,weprovideanexhaustiveanalysisoftheimpactsofthenewlaw,byconsidering 3Onecanarguethatthestringencyanddetailofthelegalproceduressurroundingdismissalsforcausealsodetermine,albeitindirectly,theminimumlevelofe ortthatemployeesneedtoexerttokeeptheirjobs.3 Itisimportanttounderlinethatifanyformalaspectofthistime-consumingadministrativeprocedurewerenotpursuedandifthedismissedworkersubsequentlychallengedthelegalityofhis/herdismissal,thenthecourtwouldmostlikelydeclarethedismissalasillegal.Inthatcase,thecourtwouldalsoorderthe rmtoreinstatetheworkerandtopayhim/herallwagescorrespondingtotheperiodsincetheworkerwasunlawfullydismisseduntiltheworkerwasreinstated.Evenifthedismissalwasdeemedlegalorifthelegalityofthedismissalwasnotchallengedbytheemployee,the rmwasstillalwaysobligedtopayseverancebene ts.Thesebene tswereconsiderable,astheycorrespondedtoonemonthofpayperyearoftenure,withaminimumofthreemonthsofpay.Afterabouttenyearsofrelativeeconomicstagnationthatfollowedthe1974coupd'etat,Portugueseeconomicpolicyeventuallybecamemoremarketfriendly.Underthegovernmentsofthemid-andlate-1980s,severalreformsenvisagingmore exibleproductandfactormarketswereintroduced.Moreover,in1986,thecountrybecameamemberoftheEuropeanCommu-nity,afterwhichcapitalin owsincreasedsubstantially.Underthispositiveeconomiccontext,anewemploymentlawsoughttorevertor,atleast,attenuatetheveryrestrictiveconditionsgoverningtheterminationofpermanentcontractsdescribedabove.Afteraperiodofheatedpoliticaldebate,publicdemonstrations(includingageneralstrike),anddetailedscrutinybytheconstitutionalcourt-alleventswhichgeneratedconsiderableuncertaintyaboutwhethertheintendedreformswouldindeedcomethrough-anewlaw,Decreto-Lei64-A/89, nallycameintoforceattheendofMayof1989.4Thisnewlawsoftenedconsiderablythedismissalconstraintsfacedby rms,namelybywideningtherangeofcircumstancesinwhicha rmcould reaworkeremployedunderapermanentcontract.Unlikeundertheoldlaw,itbecamepossiblefor rmsto reaworkerbecauseofstructural,technologicalorbusiness-cyclereasons.However,whilethebenchmarkadministrativeprocedurerequiredfordismissalsforcauseremainedlengthyandcomplex,thenewlawallowedsmall rms(de nedasthose rmsemploying20orfewerworkers)tofollowamuchsimplerprocedure.Inparticular,outofthe12speci crulesthatlarger rmsneededtofollow(eachruleoutlinedinaseparateparagraphofarticle10ofthe1989law),onlyfourofthoserulesneededtobeconsideredbysmaller rms(article15).5Thisdi erentiation 4CavacoSilva(1995)providesananalysisofthisandotherreformsintroducedinPortugalfromthemid-1980stothemid-1990s.5Theonlyexceptiontothisstreamlinedprocedureforsmaller rmswaswhentheworkerbeingdismissedwasaunionleader.Inthiscase,thebenchmark,12-paragraph-longprocedureapplied.5 relationshipsthanbefore1989)andtheeaseningofcollectivedismissals.Othernewlegaldiplomasinemploymentlawcoveredchildwork,healthandsafetypracticesandstrikes.Unlikewithdismissalsforcause,thetightertemporarycontractsdidnotchangeinadi erentwayfor rmsofdi erentsizes.However,itisnotimpossiblethatsmaller rmshadadi erentpercentageoftheirworkforcesmadeupoftemporarycontractsandthatmayconfoundtheassessmentofthemainreform.Ontheotherhand,collectivedismissalswereeasenedinaslightlydi erentwayfor rmsofdi erentsizes.Firmsemployinglessthan50employeeswerefrom1989allowedtoconductacollectivedismissalinvolvingonlytwoemployees,whilefor rmsemploying50ormoreemployeesacollectivedismissalrequiredthatatleast veworkerswerelaid-o .Inordertominimiseanybiasinourresultsrelatedtothechangesintemporarycontractsorcollectivedismissals,wefocusouranalysisoftheimpactofthecostsofdismissalonlyon rmsemployinganumberofworkers`suciently'closetothe rmsizethresholdofinterest(20).Moreover,weonlyconsider rmswhichare`relatively'farfromthethresholdthatappliedforcollectivedismissals(50).Speci cally,inourbenchmarkresults,weconsideronly rmsemployingbetween10and30workersuptoMay1989(whenthenewdismissalslawcameintoforce).Thisrelativelynarrowrangeof rmsizesalsoimpliesthatanybiasesrelatedtodi erencesintheshareoftemporarycontractsacrossthetwotypesof rmsarelikelytobesmall.Moreover,ouruseofmatchingtechniques-describedbelow-alsohelpsouridenti cationinthisregard,byrestrictingourcomparisonto rmsthataree ectivelycomparablealongalargesetofobservablevariables.Finally,therestrictionupontherangeof rmsizesweconsiderisalsoimportantinitself,eveniftherewerenoasymmetricchangesincollectivedismissals.Infact,theassumptionofcommontrendsforthetreatmentandcontrolgroupsislesslikelytoholdforawiderrangeof rmsizes.Thisandothermethodologicalissuesaredescribedinamoreformalwayinthenextsection.3Identi cationLetYDitbethepotentialoutcomeofinterestforindividuali(a rm,inourcontext)attimethadtheybeeninstateD,whereD=1ifexposedtothetreatment(a rmemployinglessthan20workers)and0otherwise.Lettreatmenttakeplaceattimet(fromMay1989,inourcase).Thefundamentalidenti cationproblemliesinthefactthatwedonotobserve,attime7 t,individualiinbothstates.Therefore,wecannotcomputetheindividualtreatmente ect,Y1it�Y0it.Onecan,however,ifprovidedwithaconvenientcontrolgroup,estimatetheaveragee ectofthetreatmentonthetreated.Oneapproachisadi erence-in-di erences(D-in-D)estimator(seeMeyer(1995)),inwhichoneusesanuntreatedcomparisongrouptoidentifytemporalvariationintheoutcomethatisnotduetothetreatment.However,inordertoachieveidenti cationofthegeneralD-in-Destimatorweneedtoassumethattheaverageoutcomesfortreatedandcontrolswouldhavefollowedparallelpathsovertimeiftherehadbeennotreatment.Thisisknownasthetime-invarianceassumption,E[Y0it�Y0it0jD=1]=E[Y0it�Y0it0jD=0];(1)wheret0isatimeperiodbeforetheprogramimplementation.Theassumptionstatesthat,overtime,theoutcomevariableoftreatedindividuals(D=1),intheeventthattheyhadnotbeenexposedtothetreatment,wouldhaveevolvedinthesamefashionasactuallyobservedfortheindividualsnotexposedtothetreatment(D=0).Ifassumption(1)holds,theD-in-Destimateoftheaveragetreatmente ectonthetreatedcanbeobtainedbythesampleanalogsofb D-in-D=fE[YitjD=1]�E[YitjD=0]g�fE[Yit0jD=1]�E[Yit0jD=0]g:(2)Theexpressionabovesimplystatesthattheimpactoftheprogramisgivenbythedi er-encebetweenparticipantsandnonparticipantsinthebefore-afterdi erenceinoutcomes.Apotentialproblemwiththisapproachisthatthetime-invarianceassumptioncanbetoostringentifthetreatedandcontrolgroupsarenotbalancedincovariatesthatarebelievedtobeassociatedwiththeoutcomevariable(seeAshenfelter(1978)).Inthiscase,theD-in-Dsetupcanbeextendedtoaccommodateasetofcovariates,somethingwhichisusuallydonelinearly,takingintoaccounteligibilityspeci ce ectsandtimeoraggregatee ects.Inthefollowingmodel,basedonasampleoftreatmentandcontrolunits:Yit=D+t+0Zit+ DDt+"it;(3)whereDisasbeforeandrepresentstheeligibility-speci cintercept,tcapturestimeor8 aggregatee ects,andZisavectorofcovariatesincludedtocorrectfordi erencesinobservedcharacteristicsbetweenindividualsintreatmentandcontrolgroups,b DwouldcorrespondtotheD-in-Destimate.Thisestimatorcontrolsforbothdi erencesintheZsandfortime-speci ce ects,butitdoesnotimposecommonsupportonthedistributionoftheZ0sacrossthecellsde nedbytheD-in-Dapproach.InordertoaddressthispossibleshortcomingofthestandardD-in-Dmethod,wecomple-mentitwithamatchingframework(Rosenbaum&Rubin1983),resultinginadi erence-in-di erencesmatching(DDM)estimator(Heckmanetal.1997,1998).DDMhasbeenrecentlyreviewedandcomparedwithothermethodsbySmith&Todd(2005)andhasbeenshowntohavethepotentialbene tofeliminatingsomesourcesofbiaspresentinnon-experimentalset-tings,improvingthequalityofevaluationresultssigni cantly.Moreover,DDMisparticularlyappropriateforouranalysisaswecandrawuponarichsetofcovariates,alldataarecompiledbythesameagencyandwecanalsousedataforcomparisongroupsfromthesamelocallabormarket(Heckmanetal.1997).Ingeneral,thefeasibilityofthematchingstrategyreliesonarichsetofobservableindividualcharacteristics,X,sothatthedistributionoftheindividualcharacteristicsimportanttotheevaluationexerciseisthesameinthedi erence-in-di erencescells.Thematchingprocessthenmodelstheprobabilityofparticipationandmatchesindivid-ualswithsimilarpropensityscores.Moreover,thetimeinvarianceassumptionfortheDDMestimatorisnowE[Y0it�Y0it0jp;D=1]=E[Y0it�Y0it0jp;D=0];(4)wherep=Pr(D=1jX)isthepropensityscore.Whenestimatingthemeanimpactofthetreatmentonthetreated,thematchingestimatorrequiresaconditionalmeanindependenceassumption,EY0itjX;D=1=EY0itjX;D=0=EY0itjX;(5)andalsorequiresthatthereisanonparticipantanalogueforeachparticipant,implyingthatPr(D=1jX)1.TheDDMestimatortakestwoforms,dependingonthenatureofthedata,namelyre-peatedcross-sectionsandpaneldata.Inthelattercase,theoneemployedinthispaper,theestimatorinvolves rstcalculatingthedi erencesovertimeinthedependentvariableforeach9 observationandthenmatchingtreatmentandcontrolunitsusingpropensityscoreestimatesbasedon`before'-periodcharacteristics.Formally,b DDM=Eh(Y1t�Y1t0)�bE�Y0t�Y0t0jPi;(6)wherebE(YjP)representstheexpectedoutcomeofindividualsinthecontrolgroupmatchedwiththoseinthetreatmentgroup.4DataThedatausedinthispaperarederivedfrom`QuadrosdePessoal'(QP),aparticularlyrichannualcensusofall rmsthatoperateinPortugalandthatemployatleastoneworker.Undertheregulationsofthiscensus,whichisadministeredbytheMinistryofEmployment,each rmislegallyrequiredtoprovideextensiveinformationaboutitselfandalsoabouteachoneofitsworkersthatareemployedatthecensusreferencemonth(thereferencemonthisMarchupto1993andOctoberfrom1994onwards).Giventheextensivecoverageofthedata,theonlygroupsofworkersnotpresentinthedataaretheself-employedandthepublicsectoremployees,besidestheunemployed.Moreover,theperiodcoveredbythedataisalsorelativelylong,asthecensushasbeenongoingsince1982.8Thelonglistofvariablesavailableinthedataincludesuniqueidenti ersforeach rm,foreachestablishmentandforeachemployee.Theseidenti ersallowustofollowworkersovertime,eveniftheymovebetween rms.Other rm-levelvariablesaretheeconomicsector/industry(measuredatthe ve-digitlevel),region(upto400di erentunits),numberofemployees(constructedfromtheworker-leveldata), rmage,typeofownership(public,private/domesticorforeignowned),sales,andequity.Attheworker-level,thedatamakeavailableinformationaboutschooling,age(monthandyearwhentheworkerwasborn),gender,tenure(monthandyearwhentheworkerwashiredbythe rm),occupation( ve-digitcode),wages,hoursworked,joblevel(atwo-digitvariable,comparableacross rmsandovertime)andpromotions(monthandyearwhentheworkerwaslastpromotedinthe rm).Experienceisconstructedasage�education�6. 8Therehavebeentwodiscontinuitiesoverthisperiod:thereisonlyemployer-leveldatafortheyearof1990;thecensusdata(bothattheemployer-andtheemployee-level)arenotavailablefor2001.Overall,onaverage,between1982and2004,thereareapproximately2.5millionworkersandmorethan200,000 rmsperyear.10 employees(seeSection2).Wealsodrop rmsemployingexactly20workers,thethresholdlevelinthenewdismissalslaw,asitmayhavebeenunclearifsuch rmsbelongedtothetreatmentorthecontrolgroups(although,strictlyspeaking, rmswith20employeeswouldbeinthe`treatment'group).Furthermore, rmsizewillalsotypically uctuateovertime,evenifonlyslightly,whichwouldpossiblymakeitriskytoassign rmswith20employeestothecontrolortothetreatmentgroups.Ourde nitionofsizeisbasedonlyonpaidemployees,excludingothertypesofworkers(employers,unpaidfamilyworkersandotherresidualcategories).Oneconcernwhenselectingthesampleofinterestismeanreversionorthe`regressionfalacy'(Davisetal.1996a,b),asselecting rmsintothetreatmentorcontrolgroupsbaseduponsizeinasingleyearonlycouldbiasourresults.Infact,suchassignmentwouldprobablyimplythatsome rmsinthesmall(large)sizecategorywouldcorrespondto rmsthataretypicallyofalarger(smaller)sizebutthathadhadarelativelybad(good)yearinthatperiod.These rmswouldthereforebelikelytoswitchbacktotheir`permanent'sizeafter1989,thuspotentiallydistortingouranalysis.Inordertoaddressthisproblem,weconstructasamplemadeupof rmsthatarelikelytohavereachedtheir`permanent'sizeby1989.Speci cally,werestrictoursampleto rmsthatremaininthesamesizecategory,between10and19workersorbetween21and30workers,overaperiodofthreeyearsupto1989.Initially,we nd16,267 rmsthatemploy10-19or21-30workersin1987,whilein1988and1989,theequivalentnumbersof rmsare17,565and18,964,respectively.Whenrestrictingthesampleto rmspresentinthedatainallthreeyearsandthatremaininthesamesizecategoryovertheperiod(i.e.thatarealways`small'or`large'from1987to1989),weobtain7,480di erent rms,ofwhich5,863are`small'.10Intermsoftheirobservablecharacteristics,somenoteworthydi erencesbetweenthetwogroupsof rmsincludeworkerreallocationrates(anaverageof0.37forsmaller rmsandof0.33forlarger rmsinthe1989data)andhourlypay(2.76eurosperhourforsmaller rmsand2.96forlarger rms,againinthe1989data)-seeTableA.1foralistofdescriptivestatisticsforeachtypeof rms.The7,480 rmsconsideredemployed122,062individualsin1989.Thisisalsotheyearinwhichthetotalnumberofemployeesofthoseselected rmspeaks,althoughtheequivalentnumbersfor1987and1988areverysimilar(119,401and121,561,respectively)-seeTable 1044%ofthese rmsarepresentinallyearsfrom1986to1999,theperiodwecoverinourdata.Thatisalsobyfarthemostcommontimepatterninthedata,asthesecondmostcommonpattern,comprising rmsthatarepresentfrom1986to1993,includesonly4%ofall rms.12 Table1presentstheresultsconcerningthebalancingofcovariatesacrossthetreatmentandcontrolgroups,beforeandaftermatching.Wedisplaytheresultsforthemainvariablesmeasuredin1989andtheirlags,butnotthevaluesforthesquaredandcubictermsorforthelegaltype,regionandsectordummyvariables(resultsavailableuponrequest).Exceptfortwovariables(schoolingandhours),allvariablesindicateconsiderablereductionsintheabsolutevalueofbias,from50%to90%,aftermatching.Moreover,mostofthosevariablesalsoresultinthenon-rejectionoftestsofequalityoftheiraveragevalues,betweenthetreatedandthecontrolgroups,aftermatching.12Furthermore,wealso ndthattheimpositionofthecommonsupportisnottoorestrictive,asonly22 rmsareleftoutfromtheanalysisasaconsequenceofthatconstraint.Thedistributionsofthepropensityscoresacrossthecontrolandtreatmentgroupsarealsoverysimilar,althoughwe ndtheexpectedgreaterdensityofcontrolobservationsatlowerlevelsofthepropensityscorewhencomparedtotreatmentobservations.Thepseudo-R2'sfromprobitestimationsofthepropensityscoreonallthevariablesbeforeandaftermatching(Sianesi2004)alsoindicatethatthematchedsampleisconsiderablymorehomogeneousafterthematching(thepseudo-R2fallsfrom0.068to0.019).Overall,ourviewisthatthereisstrongevidencethatthematchingisofparticularlygoodstandards.5.2Jobandworker owsAfterestimatingthepropensityscoreandevaluatingthequalityofthematching,wenowassesstheimpactofthenewlawintermsofdi erent rmoutcomes.Inthecaseofjob ows,theorydoesnoto erclearpredictions,ashiringsmaybegreaterorsmallerthanseparations.However,worker ows(hiringsand/orseparations)areexpectedtoincrease.Giventhatthecostsofdismissalsforcausefall,someworkersthatexhibitpoorlevelsofperformancebutthathavebeenemployeduntilthenduetotheprotectiono eredbythelawmaybedismissedoncethenewlawisinforce.Atthesametime,employerscanalsobeexpectedtohiremore,assuchmatcheswillnolongerbeasdiculttoterminateasbeforethe1989law.However,itisalsopossiblethatworkersthatexhibitpoorlevelsofperformancechangetheirbehaviourunderthenewcircumstancescreatedbythenewlaw,sothatseparationsdonotnecessarilyincrease.Thispossibilitycouldalsoweakentheexpectedincreaseinhirings.Ontheother 12Thecaseofschoolingisnotparticularlyimportantasthetestofequalityofitsaveragesisstillnotrejected.Theperformanceofhoursislessgood,asthebiasincreasesaftermatchingandtheequalitytestisrejected.However,theeconomicdi erenceinthemeansisverysmall.14 hand,thee ectsofthelawmaybe`toomicro'tobecapturedatthe rmlevelanalysisif,forinstance,onlyoneortwoworkersper rmtendtobehaveinsuchawaythattherearegroundsforadismissalforcause.Inordertotestthesedi erentpredictions,weconsidertwoversionsofthenetjobcreationvariable,the rstincludingtheyearof1990(forwhichonly rm-leveldataareavailable)andthesecondnotincludingthatyear(i.e.computingnetjobcreationin1991basedonacomparisonbetween1989and1991).Hiringsandseparationsratesalsoignore1990:sincethereisnoworkerdataforthatyear,onecannotdecomposethenetjobcreationratein1990intermsofhiringsandseparations.Forinstance,hiringsin1991correspondtoallworkershiredafterMarch1989thatarestillemployedinthe rmbyMarch1991.From1992onwards,thetwoversionsofnetjobcreationcoincide(forinstance,netjobcreationin1992correspondstothedi erencein rmsizebetween1992and1991).Inourresults,we ndevidencethatsmall rms,thosesubjecttoagreaterdecreaseintheir ringcosts,experiencehighernetjobcreationgrowthratesin1990,the rstyearaftertheintroductionofthenewlaw(seeTable2).TheATTstatisticforthisyearis0.034(t-ratioof4.3).However,thishighernetjobcreationratewaspartiallyreversedin1991,whentheATTstatisticisequalto-0.025(t-ratioof-2.8).Allremainingt-ratiostendtobelessthan2inabsolutevalue,exceptfor1993and1997,whenthenetjobcreationratesarealsopositive(ATTstatisticsof0.019and0.028,respectively).13ThesecondblockofestimatesinTable2referstothemeasureofnetjobcreationinwhichthecomparisonin1991takes1989asthebaseperiod(not1990asinthe rstblock).Inotherwords,theinformationavailablefor1990isignoredforthesakeofgreatercomparabilitywiththevariablesforwhichthereisno1990data(e.g.hiringsandseparations).Inthiscase,we ndthattherewasnosigni cantdi erencebetweenthetwotypesof rms(ATT=-0.001;t-ratio=-0.1).Thisresultisnotsurprisingasintheprevioussetofestimatesthevaluesfor1990and1991wereofoppositesignandofsimilarmagnitudes.14Finally,Table2alsoreports 13Weconsiderinthistableall rmsthatarepresentinthedataforatleastoneyearintheperiod1990-1999.Those rmsarealsopresentinallyearsinthe`before'period,1987-1989,byconstructionofoursample.Thefactthatsome rmsexitthemarketwhile,byconstruction,nonew rmsareaddedintooursampleexplainswhythenumberof rmsfalls,inourcasefromapproximately3,900to2,900(treatmentgroup)orfrom1,200to900(controlgroup).Moreover,each owrateisconstructedasacomparisonbetweenadjacentyears(e.g.of1993withrespectto1992)inthe`after'periodand1989withrespectto1988(forthe`before'period),notasthe owfrom1989toeachyearfrom1990onwards(e.g.thesumofthe owfrom1989to1993),whileno owsareregisteredfor rmsthatleavethedata.14Theresultsfortheremainingyears(1992-1999)underthesecondtypeofnetjobcreationvariablearenotreported,astheyare,byconstruction,preciselythesameasthoseforthe rstnetjobcreationvariable.15 resultsforthehiringsandseparationsrates.Acrossthenine-yearperiodcoveredandforeachoneofthetwoworker owvariables,we ndalmostnoevidenceofsigni cantdi erencesbetweenthetwotypesof rms.Theonlysigni cantestimateindicateslowerseparationsratesforsmaller rmsin1993(ATT=-0.019;t-ratio=-2.2).Resultsfortheremaining owvariables(jobreallocation,workerreallocationandchurning)arenotreportedastheyarealsoinsigni cant.Overall,ourconclusionfromtheresultsdisplayedinTable2isthatthereisonlysomemoderateevidenceofaslightincreaseinjobcreationinsmaller rms.Strikingly,thereisnorobustevidenceofincreasedworker ows(hiringsorseparations),unlikewhattheorypredicts.However,therearesomeissuesandcaveatsthatneedtobetakenintoaccountwheninterpretingthese ndings,ontopoftheargumentdescribedaboveaboutthepossibleparticularlymicronatureofthee ects.Onecaveatisthatourdataaremeasuredannually,afrequencythatmaynotbesucientlyhightocapturetheworker- owadjustmentscarriedoutby rms(Blanchard&Portugal2001).Thisproblemiscompoundedbythefactthatthereisnoinformationonhiringsorseparationsfor1990,althoughonlyifsuchmatchesareterminatedbeforeMarch1991.Anothercaveatisthatchangesinthevaluesinthedataaredriven,inpart,bybothvoluntaryandinvoluntaryseparations-andperhapsanincreaseinthelatter,assuggestedbytheory,coincideswithadeclineoftheformer.Thistrade-o couldariseifthoseworkersthatbeforethenewlawwouldhaveleftnowbelievetheywillbemoreeasily redattheprospectivenewjobandprefernottomove.Moreover,asinBaueretal.(forthcoming),ourstudycannotcontroldirectlyfordi erencesacross rmsintheirnumbersoftemporaryworkers.Itcouldbethatsmaller rmstendtoemployagreatershareoftemporaryworkersandarethuslessa ectedbythereform.15However,aswecontrolcarefullyforthetenurelevelofeach rms'workforce,webelievethispotentialproblemisnotseriousinourcase.Furthermore,thisexplanationwouldalsobeatoddswiththe ndingsreportedinsubsection5.4(seebelow).Finally,thereisoneadditionale ectthatmayin uencetheabsenceofanyincreasesinworkerreallocation.Thise ectconcernsthenatureofthereformitself:ifa rmexpandsabovethe20-employeethreshold,the rmwillthenbecomesubjecttothemorecostlydismissal 15Moreover,someevidencebasedonsubjective,cross-sectiondatasuggeststhatmedium-size rmsaremorenegativelya ectedbyEPLthansmaller rms(Pierre&Scarpetta2006).Takingthisresultatfacevalue,thenanyincreasedlevelsofworkerreallocationinsmaller rmsinducedbytheeight-paragraphdi erencemayhavebeenjustcancelledoutbysuchgreatersensitivityoflarger rmswithrespecttoEPL.16 long-termemploymentrelationship,workerswilltendto nditlessadvantageoustoinvestin rm-speci cskills,leadingtoadeteriorationin rmperformance.However,ifworkersearnrentsattheircurrentjobs,thenworkere ort(andtherefore rmperformance)mayinsteadincreasewhen ringcostsfall.Asitbecomeslessunlikelythatworkerswilllosetheircurrentwagepremiums,ife ortisobservablebyemployers,thene ortwillincreaseand rmperformancewillimprove(seealsothediscussioninAutoretal.(2007)).Similarly,improvementsinpersonnelmanagementwarrantedbythegreater exibilityofthenewlawcanalsobeexpectedtoleadtobetterperformance.Firmperformancemayincreasenotonly(ornotnecessarily)becauseworkersexertmoree ortbutalso(orsimply)becauseuncooperativeorevendisruptiveworkersare red.InordertoshedlightonthesecontrastingviewsabouttheroleofEPL,weexaminedi erentmeasuresof rmperformancethatcanbeconstructedfromourdata(seethelastthreeblockofestimatesinTable3).Inour rstmeasure,weconsiderthelogarithmoftotalsales(2004prices)astheoutcomevariable,againinaDDMapproach.We ndthatallestimates,acrossthenine-yearperiodconsidered,arepositive,andfourofthemaresigni cant.Thosesigni cantestimatesarealsoparticularlylarge,rangingbetween8.3pp(1995)and12.8pp(1998),whiletheestimateswitht-ratiosbelow2rangefrom3.7ppand6pp.Moreover,thepatternofresultsisrelativelyunchangedwhenconsideringinsteadthelogarithmofsalesperworkerastheoutcomeofinterest(secondblockofestimates).Now veoutofthenineestimateshavet-ratiosabove2,indicatinge ectsbetween5.2ppand10.5pp.Weconsideroneadditionalmeasureofperformance,`surplusperworker',whichisde nedasthedi erencebetweentotalsalesandthewagebillofeach rm.Thewagebilliscomputedbysummingallindividualwages,andmultiplyingthatsumby14(thenumberofmonthsofpayduetoeachworkerperyear,accordingtoPortugueselaw)andby1.2(correspondingtoemployerpayrolltaxesofapproximately20%).Wethentakeasourdependentvariablethelogarithmoftheratioofthesurplusbythenumberofworkers.Theresults(seethebottomofTable3)areagainconsistentwiththeprevious ndings,indicatingthattreated rmsunderwentapositiverelativeincreaseintheirperformance.Fouroutofthenineyearsproducelargeandsigni cantincreasesinsurplus,whiletheremainingestimatesarealsopositiveand,inmostcases,marginallysigni cant.1994isayearwhichneverexhibitsasigni cantdi erenceacrossthethreesetsofestimatesbut,asmentionedabove,thismaybe19 andthendisappearfromthesample(possiblybecausetheybecomebankrupt),consequentlybeingignoredintheresults.Byconsideringnowonly rmsthatarealwayspresentinourdataset,weruleoutsuchcensoringbias.Wepresentthe ndingsforthismorerestrictivesampleselectioninTable4(jobandworker ows)andTable5(wagesand rmperformance).First,weobservethatthenumberof rmsdeclinesfrombetween5114in1990and3816in1999,whenconsideringall rm-years,to1671,whenonlyconsidering rmspresentinallyears,from1987to1999,indicatingthatthesampleof rmsusedforeachyearbeforecanvaryreasonably.Second,andmoreimportant,theresultsindicatethatourbenchmark ndingsarerobust.Therearenoqualitativedi erencesintermsofjoborworker ows(includingthe1990spike,whichisstilldiscernible)whencomparedtothebenchmarkresultsofTables2and3.Moreover,wagesalsodecreasesigni cantlyand rmperformancealsoundergoesasigni cantincrease,atverysimilarmagnitudes,althoughinthelattercasetheprecisionoftheestimatesfalls.Whilethedecreaseinprecisionmayinpartindicatethat rmselectionmatters,webelieveamoreimportantreasonisthesmallersamplesize.Inanycase,itisimportanttounderlinethatthequalitativeresultsareunchangedandthatseveralpointestimatesremainstatisticallysigni cant.Inoursecondrobustnesstest,wereestimatethemain rm-levelresultsbutusingadi erentmatchingalgorithm.Insteadofkernelmatching,wenowconsidernearestneighbourmatching( venearestmatches).Theresults(jobandworker owsinTable6andwagesand rmperformanceinTable7)areagainverysimilartothoseobtainedinthemainestimates,bothinqualitativeandinquantitativeterms.Asbefore,we ndinsigni cantdi erencesin ows(exceptfortheyearof1990),asigni cantdecreaseinwagesandasigni cantincreaseinourdi erentproxiesof rmperformance.Ourthirdrobustnessanalysisisbasedonconsideringan`arti cial' rmsizethresholdabovetheonedeterminedbythelaw(20employees).Theconcernthisstrategyseekstoaddressisthatthe ndingsreportedabovemaybedrivenbydi erencesin rmsizeonly,insuchwaythattheyarenotrelatedtoanyrealimpactofthelaw.Forinstance,althoughmostresearchdocumentsaverystrongpositiverelationshipbetween rmsizeandwagelevels(seeOi&Idson(1999)forasurvey),itisalsopossiblethatwagegrowthishigheratbigger rms.Suchpossibilitycouldexplainour ndingsaboutwages,astheyarebasedoncontrastingwagegrowthovertimebetweentwogroupsof rmswofdi erentsizes.21 Weimplementthisfalsi cationexercisebycreatinganewdataset,includingonly rmsthatemploy,intheperiod1987-1989,eitherbetween20-29workers(thenew`treatment'group)or31-40workers(thenew`control'group),i.e.assumingthatthesizethresholdin-dicatedbythelawwas30.Intheresultsbasedonthisnewdataset,we nd,asbefore,thatthereisaspikeinjobcreationin1990,althoughtherearenosigni cantdi erenceswhenconsideringonlythedi erencebetween1991and1989(seeTable8).Theresultsforhiringsandseparationsarealsoverysimilartothoseobtainedwhenconsideringthecorrect rm-sizethreshold(20).Theseresultsthereforesupportourpreviousconclusionthattherearenosigni cantdi erencesinducedbythelawregardingemploymentandjobandworker ows(andthatthe1990spikeisspurious).However,whenexaminingthee ectsintermsofwagesand rmperformance(seeTable9),wenowfailtoobserveanysigni cantdi erencesbetween`small'and`large' rms.Thiscontrastsdramaticallywiththe ndingsbasedonthethresholdestablishedinthelaw(20employees),fromwhichwedocumentedsigni cantdecreasesinwagesandsigni cantincreasesin rmperformance.Thedi erencesbetweenthetwosetsofresultsareparticularlyclearinthecaseof rmperformance,inwhichmanypointestimatesareevennegativewhenconsideringthearti cialthreshold.Thecontrastbetweenthetwosetsof ndingsthereforelendsadditionalcredibilitytoourresultsinSection5andtheirinterpretationascausale ectsofthelawreform.Finally,weaddressthepossibilitythatbyMarch1989(thereferenceperiodinourdata)some rmswerealreadyrespondingtothereform,implyingthat1989cannotbeconsideredasthelastyearofthe`before'period.Asmentionedbefore,wedonotbelievethistobethecase,astherewasstillgreatuncertaintyatthetimeconcerningthespeci ccontentoftheemploymentlaw,nottomentionifanyreformwouldgoaheadatall.Inanycase,inordertoexaminethispossibility,weconsider1988asthelastyearofthe`before'periodandkeep1990and1991asthe rstyearsofthe`after'period.Againweobtainthesamequalitativeresultsasinthebenchmarkcase,althoughtheresultsabout rmperformancetendtobeslightlylesssigni cantinthe rstyears(resultsavailableuponrequest).18 18Wehavealsoreplicatedourmainanalysisbuttrimmingtherangeof rmsizescovered,inthespiritofaregression-discontinuityapproach(Hahnetal.2001).Whenconsideringonly rmsemployingbetween15and19workersin1987-1989and rmsemployingbetween21and25workersinthesameperiod,we ndthesamequalitativeresultsasthosepresentedinSection5.However,asthesamplesizebecomesconsiderablysmaller(lessthan700treated rmsandlessthan400control rms)and,inrelativeterms,thescopeformisclassi cationincreases(e.g. rmsemploying19workersinMarch1989maybeemploying21workersinJune),theestimatestendtobesomewhatlesssigni cantthaninthebenchmarkresults(resultsavailableuponrequest).22 isalsolikelytotransferbargainingpowerfromemployeestotheiremployers,whichwouldexplainthedeclineinwagesfoundinourresults.ReferencesAcemoglu,D.&Angrist,J.D.(2001),`Consequencesofemploymentprotection?ThecaseoftheAmericanswithDisabilitiesAct',JournalofPoliticalEconomy109(5),915{957.Ashenfelter,O.(1978),`Estimatingthee ectoftrainingprogramsonearnings',ReviewofEconomicsandStatistics60(1),47{57.Autor,D.H.(2003),`Outsourcingatwill:Thecontributionofunjustdismissaldoctrinetothegrowthofemploymentoutsourcing',JournalofLaborEconomics21(1),1{42.Autor,D.H.,Donohue,J.J.&Schwab,S.J.(2006),`Thecostsofwrongful-dischargelaws',ReviewofEconomicsandStatistics88(2),211{231.Autor,D.,Kugler,A.&Kerr,W.(2007),`Doemploymentprotectionsreduceproductivity?EvidencefromU.S.states',EconomicJournal117(June),F189{F217.Bauer,T.K.,Bender,S.&Bonin,H.(forthcoming),`Dismissalprotectionandworker owsinsmallestablishments',Economica.Bertola,G.(1990),`Jobsecurity,employmentandwages',EuropeanEconomicReview34(4),851{879.Bertola,G.&Rogerson,R.(1997),`Institutionsandlaborreallocation',EuropeanEconomicReview41(6),1147{1171.Besley,T.&Burgess,R.(2004),`Canlaborregulationhindereconomicperformance?evidencefromindia',QuarterlyJournalofEconomics119(1),91{134.Bewley,T.(1999),WhyWagesDon'tFallDuringaRecession?,HarvardUniversityPress,Cambridge.Blanchard,O.&Portugal,P.(2001),`Whathidesbehindanunemploymentrate:ComparingPortugueseandU.S.labormarkets',AmericanEconomicReview91(1),187{207.Blanchard,O.&Tirole,J.(2003),Contoursofemploymentprotectionreform,MITWP03-35.24 Kugler,A.&Pica,G.(forthcoming),`E ectsofemploymentprotectiononworkerandjob ows:Evidencefromthe1990Italianreform',LabourEconomics.Kugler,A.D.&Saint-Paul,G.(2004),`Howdo ringcostsa ectworker owsinaworldwithadverseselection?',JournalofLaborEconomics22(3),553{584.Lazear,E.P.(1990),`Jobsecurityprovisionsandemployment',QuarterlyJournalofEco-nomics105(3),699{726.Leonardi,M.&Pica,G.(2007),Employmentprotectionlegislationandwages,IZADP2680.Leuven,E.&Sianesi,B.(2004),`PSMATCH2:StatamoduletoperformfullMahalanobisandpropensityscorematching,commonsupportgraphing,andcovariateimbalancetesting',StatisticalSoftwareComponentss432001.Marinescu,I.(2007),Shorteningthetenureclock:TheimpactofstrengthenedU.K.jobsecuritylegislation,UniversityofChicago,Mimeo.Martins,P.(2007),Dismissalsforcause:Anindividual-levelanalysisofdisplacementandwagee ects,QueenMary,UniversityofLondon,Mimeo.Meyer,B.D.(1995),`Naturalandquasi-experimentsineconomics',JournalofBusiness&EconomicStatistics13(2),151{162.OECD(2004),Employmentprotectionregulationandlabourmarketperformance,in`Em-ploymentOutlook2004',OECD,Paris.Oi,W.Y.&Idson,T.L.(1999),Firmsizeandwages,inO.Ashenfelter&D.Card,eds,`HandbookofLaborEconomics',Vol.3ofHandbookofLaborEconomics,Elsevier,chap-ter33,pp.2165{2214.Oyer,P.&Schaefer,S.(2000),`Layo sandlitigation',RANDJournalofEconomics31(2),345{358.Pierre,G.&Scarpetta,S.(2006),`Employmentprotection:Do rms'perceptionsmatchwithlegislation?',EconomicsLetters90(3),328{334.Rosenbaum,P.&Rubin,D.(1983),`Thecentralroleofthepropensityscoreinobservationalstudiesforcausale ects',Biometrika70(1),41{55.26 Table1:Analysisofbalancingproperties( rm-levelanalysis) Mean%reductt-testVariableSampleTreatedControl%biasbiastp�[t] SchoolingUnmatched5.61685.6442-1.5-0.480.633Matched5.61625.6674-2.9-87.2-1.30.193ExperienceUnmatched23.4624.104-9.5-2.90.004Matched23.44323.4160.495.80.170.866TenureUnmatched7.53018.5899-23.4-7.290Matched7.54247.37353.784.11.740.082FemaleUnmatched0.339580.34491-1.8-0.560.577Matched0.339590.337180.854.80.370.71PayUnmatched2.7192.9566-16.7-5.370Matched2.71082.781-4.970.5-2.480.013HoursUnmatched168.98168.750.90.290.769Matched169.01166.719.5-911.14.130JoblevelUnmatched5.72595.650211.23.350.001Matched5.7285.7405-1.983.4-0.810.42ForeignUnmatched0.009370.01178-2.4-0.760.445Matched0.009410.008470.961.10.460.645FirmageUnmatched1970.51965.919.57.040Matched1970.51970.7-0.995.3-0.580.56LagschoolingUnmatched5.58615.57120.80.250.801Matched5.58725.6554-3.7-357.8-1.670.096LagexperienceUnmatched23.25723.914-9.8-3.010.003Matched23.23422.8485.841.22.60.009LagtenureUnmatched7.30988.3859-23.7-7.410Matched7.31987.12964.282.31.950.051LagfemaleUnmatched0.334370.33799-1.2-0.380.706Matched0.334160.333280.375.70.140.893LagpayUnmatched2.63142.8861-17.9-6.040Matched2.63232.7078-5.370.4-2.760.006LaghoursUnmatched170.94170.760.70.230.816Matched170.95168.878.4-10273.620LagjoblevelUnmatched5.74035.657123.610Matched5.74165.7577-2.380.6-1.020.308 Notes:Source:Author'scalculationsbasedonQuadrosdePessoal.TreatmentandControlindicatesthenumberof rmsinthetreatmentandcontrolgroupsrespectively( rmswith10to19employeesin1989areinthetreatmentgroup; rmswith21to30employeesin1989areinthecontrolgroup).Allvariablesare rm-levelaveragesbasedonthecharacteristicsof rmsin1989(lagscorrespondto1988information).28 Table3:E ectsonwagesand rmperformance( rm-levelanalysis);Matchingmethod:kernel VariableYearATTt(ATT)TreatedControl Wages1991-0.016-2.0399112111992-0.022-2.2401011981993-0.024-2.4396611991994-0.015-1.4398012071995-0.011-1.1381311521996-0.024-2.1363310801997-0.035-2.9356710791998-0.033-2.9339910221999-0.012-1.033601001Totalsales19910.0451.7333698719920.0461.7332098119930.0902.8327298019940.0371.1313694519950.0832.3295387319960.0571.5283283919970.0601.4272481219980.1282.9267379019990.1072.52635791Salesperworker19910.0461.8333698719920.0522.0332098119930.0622.1327298019940.0020.1313694519950.0652.0295387319960.0431.4283283919970.0250.7272481219980.1052.9267379019990.0872.52635791Surplusperworker19910.0692.2322295719920.0852.6319895919930.0571.7312893319940.0130.3301291019950.0681.8285084519960.0541.4272180619970.0330.8262978219980.1673.8257975719990.1503.42546770 Notes:Source:Author'scalculationsbasedonQuadrosdePessoal.ATTreferstotheaveragetreatmentonthetreatedintermsoftheoutcomevariablesconsid-eredandattheyearunderanalysis.t(ATT)denotest-ratiosbasedonanalyticalstandarderrors.Theoutcomevariableismeasuredbythedi erencebetweenthevalueofthevariableintheyearunderanalysisandthebaseyear,1989.Seemaintextfortheformalde nitionofeachvariable.TreatmentandControlindicatesthenumberof rmsinthetreatmentandcontrolgroupsrespectively( rmswith10to19employeesin1989areinthetreatmentgroup; rmswith21to30employeesin1989areinthecontrolgroup).30 Table5:Robustness-E ectsonwagesand rmperformance( rm-levelanalysis;onlycontinuing rms);Matchingmethod:kernel VariableYearATTt(ATT)TreatedControl Wages1991-0.013-0.912454191992-0.040-2.012484191993-0.024-1.312474181994-0.023-1.312454191995-0.036-2.012444141996-0.050-2.312394131997-0.039-1.812434161998-0.073-3.812414181999-0.064-3.51241419Totalsales19910.0871.9110236819920.0671.5109837019930.0761.5110836919940.0581.2110037219950.0571.1109937219960.0571.1109936719970.0821.4109436319980.0841.4109736719990.1171.71034355Salesperworker19910.0791.8110236819920.0902.0109837019930.0691.4110836919940.0491.0110037219950.0491.0109937219960.0761.5109936719970.0951.8109436319980.1112.1109736719990.1132.01034355Surplusperworker19910.0971.8106836019920.0991.7105636319930.0731.3105635519940.0631.1105436419950.0661.1105336819960.1071.9105535619970.1001.5105335519980.1612.4105335919990.1302.0996348 Notes:Source:Author'scalculationsbasedonQuadrosdePessoal.ATTreferstotheaveragetreatmentonthetreatedintermsoftheoutcomevariablesconsid-eredandattheyearunderanalysis.t(ATT)denotest-ratiosbasedonanalyticalstandarderrors.Theoutcomevariableismeasuredbythedi erencebetweenthevalueofthevariableintheyearunderanalysisandthebaseyear,1989.Seemaintextfortheformalde nitionofeachvariable.TreatmentandControlindicatesthenumberof rmsinthetreatmentandcontrolgroupsrespectively( rmswith10to19employeesin1989areinthetreatmentgroup; rmswith21to30employeesin1989areinthecontrolgroup).32 Table7:Robustness-E ectsonwagesand rmperformance( rm-levelanalysis);Matchingmethod: venearestneigh-bours VariableYearATTt(ATT)TreatedControl Wages1991-0.021-2.3387011831992-0.028-2.5389711701993-0.029-2.6385411701994-0.021-1.7387211781995-0.014-1.2370411241996-0.032-2.4353010541997-0.048-3.5346410521998-0.040-3.132979951999-0.018-1.43261975Totalsales19910.0541.7325996719920.0431.3324296419930.0942.5319796219940.0451.2306292819950.0852.0287785419960.0851.9276182019970.0851.7265879319980.1392.8261277419990.1242.62574778Salesperworker19910.0491.6325996719920.0401.3324296419930.0511.5319796219940.0050.1306292819950.0611.6287785419960.0641.8276182019970.0340.9265879319980.1152.8261277419990.0982.52574778Surplusperworker19910.0591.7315393719920.0721.9312594219930.0511.3305891619940.0160.4294489319950.0671.5278082819960.0791.8265478719970.0420.9257076419980.1713.4252374419990.1713.42491757 Notes:Source:Author'scalculationsbasedonQuadrosdePessoal.ATTreferstotheaveragetreatmentonthetreatedintermsoftheoutcomevariablesconsid-eredandattheyearunderanalysis.t(ATT)denotest-ratiosbasedonanalyticalstandarderrors.Theoutcomevariableismeasuredbythedi erencebetweenthevalueofthevariableintheyearunderanalysisandthebaseyear,1989.Seemaintextfortheformalde nitionofeachvariable.TreatmentandControlindicatesthenumberof rmsinthetreatmentandcontrolgroupsrespectively( rmswith10to19employeesin1989areinthetreatmentgroup; rmswith21to30employeesin1989areinthecontrolgroup).34 Table9:Robustness-E ectsonwagesand rmperformance-Arti cialthreshold( rm-levelanalysis,20-40employeesin1989);Matchingmethod:kernel VariableYearATTt(ATT)TreatedControl Wages1991-0.008-0.712124941992-0.005-0.411984891993-0.027-1.911924821994-0.048-3.112134991995-0.021-1.511514791996-0.013-0.810904491997-0.019-1.210774501998-0.018-1.110194341999-0.026-1.5999422Totalsales19910.0150.4100641819920.0080.29984171993-0.090-2.199941719940.0140.396840719950.0280.689737919960.0250.585936819970.0390.682736219980.0140.28073451999-0.031-0.5806352Salesperworker19910.0060.210064181992-0.012-0.39984171993-0.087-2.29994171994-0.016-0.49684071995-0.018-0.48973791996-0.021-0.585936819970.0020.08273621998-0.043-0.88073451999-0.077-1.6806352Surplusperworker19910.0401.09764121992-0.020-0.59744061993-0.113-2.59523981994-0.059-1.29293911995-0.054-1.18693641996-0.031-0.58273581997-0.016-0.37943461998-0.018-0.37773371999-0.151-2.6783342 Notes:Source:Author'scalculationsbasedonQuadrosdePessoal.ATTreferstotheaveragetreatmentonthetreatedintermsoftheoutcomevariablesconsid-eredandattheyearunderanalysis.t(ATT)denotest-ratiosbasedonanalyticalstandarderrors.Theoutcomevariableismeasuredbythedi erencebetweenthevalueofthevariableintheyearunderanalysisandthebaseyear,1989.Seemaintextfortheformalde nitionofeachvariable.TreatmentandControlindicatesthenumberof rmsinthetreatmentandcontrolgroupsrespectively( rmswith10to19employeesin1989areinthetreatmentgroup; rmswith21to30employeesin1989areinthecontrolgroup).36