/
TheMythoftheCreditSpreadPuzzlePeterFeldhutteryLondonBusinessSchoolSt TheMythoftheCreditSpreadPuzzlePeterFeldhutteryLondonBusinessSchoolSt

TheMythoftheCreditSpreadPuzzlePeterFeldhutteryLondonBusinessSchoolSt - PDF document

pasty-toler
pasty-toler . @pasty-toler
Follow
393 views
Uploaded On 2016-08-06

TheMythoftheCreditSpreadPuzzlePeterFeldhutteryLondonBusinessSchoolSt - PPT Presentation

WearegratefultotheQGroupfortheJackTreynorPrizeWearealsogratefulforvaluablecommentsandsuggestionsreceivedfromAntjeBerndtdiscussantHarjoatBhamradiscussantHuiChendiscussantMikeChernovDarrellD ID: 435158

WearegratefultotheQ-GroupfortheJackTreynorPrize.WearealsogratefulforvaluablecommentsandsuggestionsreceivedfromAntjeBerndt(discussant) HarjoatBhamra(discussant) HuiChen(discussant) MikeChernov DarrellD

Share:

Link:

Embed:

Download Presentation from below link

Download Pdf The PPT/PDF document "TheMythoftheCreditSpreadPuzzlePeterFeld..." is the property of its rightful owner. Permission is granted to download and print the materials on this web site for personal, non-commercial use only, and to display it on your personal computer provided you do not modify the materials and that you retain all copyright notices contained in the materials. By downloading content from our website, you accept the terms of this agreement.


Presentation Transcript

TheMythoftheCreditSpreadPuzzlePeterFeldhutteryLondonBusinessSchoolStephenSchaeferzLondonBusinessSchoolMay12,2017AbstractWeaskwhetherastandardstructuralmodel(BlackandCox(1976))isabletoexplaincreditspreadsoncorporatebondsand,incontrasttomuchoftheliterature,we ndthatthemodelmatchesthelevelofinvestmentgradespreadswell.Modelspreadsforspeculativegradedebtaretoolowandwe ndthatbondilliquiditycontributestothisunderpricing.Ouranalysismakesuseofanewapproachforcalibratingthemodeltoaveragehistoricaldefaultratesandweshowviasimulationthatthisleadstomuchmorepreciseestimatesofinvestmentgradedefaultprobabilities.Keywords:Creditspreadpuzzle,Structuralmodels,Black-Coxmodel,Corporatebondspreads,Defaultprobabilities;JEL:C23;G12 WearegratefultotheQ-GroupfortheJackTreynorPrize.WearealsogratefulforveryvaluablecommentsfromtheeditorandananonymousrefereeandsuggestionsreceivedfromAntjeBerndt(discussant),HarjoatBhamra(discussant),HuiChen(discussant),MikeChernov,DarrellDue,StefanoGiglio(discussant),JeanHelwege(discussant),RalphKoijen,DavidLando,ErikLoualiche(discussant),GustavoManso(discussant),RobertMerton,Jens-DickNielsen,LasseHejePedersen,ScottRichardson,BatchimegSambalaibat(discussant),andseminarparticipantsattheQ-GroupSpring2016meeting,NBERAssetPricing2015conference,UtahWinterFinanceConfer-ence2015,EFA2015,HKUSTFinanceSymposium2014,WFA2014,SFSCavalcade2014,ESSFM2014inGerzensee,FifthRiskManagementConference2014,UNC'sRoundtable2013,UCLAAn-dersonSchoolofManagement,UCSanDiego,FinancialConductAuthority,AQR,LondonBusinessSchool,CassBusinessSchool,ViennaGraduateSchoolofFinance,StockholmSchoolofEconomics,TilburgUniversity,DuisenburgSchoolofFinanceAmsterdam,NHHBergen,RotterdamSchoolofManagement,UniversityofSouthernDenmark,CopenhagenBusinessSchool,BrunelUniversity,SurreyBusinessSchool,HenleyBusinessSchool,BankofEngland,andUniversityofCambridge.WeareparticularlygratefulfortheresearchassistanceprovidedbyIshitaSen.yLondonBusinessSchool,Regent'sPark,London,NW14SA,pfeldhutter@london.eduzLondonBusinessSchool,Regent'sPark,London,NW14SA,sschaefer@london.edu 1.IntroductionThestructuralapproachtocreditrisk,pioneeredbyMerton(1974)andothers,representstheleadingtheoreticalframeworkforstudyingcorporatedefaultriskandpricingcorporatedebt.Whilethemodelsareintuitiveandsimple,manystudies ndthat,oncecalibratedtomatchhistoricaldefaultandrecoveryratesandtheequitypremium,theyfailtoexplainthelevelofactualinvestmentgradecreditspreads,aresultreferredtoasthe\creditspreadpuzzle".Papersthat ndacreditspreadpuzzletypicallymakeuseofMoody'shistoricaldefaultrates,measuredoveraperiodofaround30yearsandstartingfrom1970.1Ourstartingpointistoshowthattheappearanceofacreditspreadpuzzledependsstronglyontheperiodoverwhichhistoricaldefaultratesaremeasured.Forexample,Chen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009)usedefaultratesfrom1970-2001and ndBBB-AAAmodelspreadsof57-79bps(dependingonmaturity),whicharesubstantiallylowerthanhistoricalspreadsof94-102bps.If,instead,weuseMoody'sdefaultratesfor1920-2001modelspreadsare91-112bpsandinlinewithhistoricalspreads.Usingsimulations,wedemonstratetwokeypointsabouthistoricaldefaultrates.The rstisthat,oversampleperiodsofaround30yearsthataretypicallyusedintheliterature,thereisalargesamplingerrorintheobservedaveragerate.Forexample,ifthetrue10-yearBBBcumulativedefaultprobabilitywere5.09%2,a95%con dencebandfortherealizeddefaultratemeasuredover31yearswouldbe[115%1278%].Intuitively,thelargesampleerrorarisesbecausedefaultsarecorrelatedand31yearsofdataonlygiverisetothreenon-overlapping10-yearintervals.Asaresultofthelargesamplingerror,whenhistoricaldefaultratesareusedasestimatesofex-antedefaultprobabilities,thedi erencebetweenactualspreadsandmodelspreadsneedstobeverylarge{muchlarger,forexample,thanthatfoundfortheBBB-AAAspreadmentionedabove{tobeinterpretedasstatisticallysigni cantevidenceagainstthemodel.Second,andequallycrucial,distributionsofaveragehistoricalinvestmentgradedefault 1SeeforexampleLeland(2006),Cremers,Driessen,andMaenhout(2008),Chen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009)andHuangandHuang(2012)2ThisisthenumberreportedbyMoody'sfor1970-2001.1 ratesarehighlyskewed.Mostofthetimeweseefewdefaultsbutoccasionallyweseemanyandthismeansthatthereisahighprobabilityofobservingaratethatisbelowtheactualmean.Skewnessislikelytoleadtotheconclusionthatastructuralmodelunderpredictsinvestmentgradespreadsevenifthemodeliscorrect.Thereasonforthepresenceofskewnessisthatdefaultsarecorrelatedacross rmsasaresultofthecommondependenceofindividual rmvaluesonsystematic(\market")shocks.Toseewhycorrelationleadstoskewness,wecanthinkofalargenumberof rmswithadefaultprobability(oversomeperiod)of5%andwheretheirdefaultsareperfectlycorrelated.Inthiscasewewillseenodefaults95%ofthetime(and100%defaults5%ofthetime)sotherealizeddefaultratewillunderestimatethedefaultprobability95%ofthetime.Iftheaveragedefaultrateiscalculatedoverthreeindependentperiods,therealizeddefaultratewillstillunderestimatethedefaultprobability0953=8574%ofthetime.Weproposeanewapproachtoestimatedefaultprobabilities.Insteadofusingthehis-toricaldefaultrateatasinglematurityandratingasanestimateofthedefaultprobabilityforthissamematurityandrating,weuseawidecrosssectionofdefaultratesatdi erentmaturitiesandratings.WeusetheBlackandCox(1976)modelandwhattiesdefaultprob-abilitiesfor rmswithdi erentratingstogetherinthemodelisthatweassumethattheywill,nonetheless,havethesamedefaultboundary.(Thedefaultboundaryisthevalueofthe rm,measuredasafractionofthefacevalueofdebt,belowwhichthe rmdefaults).Thisisreasonablesince,ifthe rmweretodefault,thereisnoobviousreasonwhythedefaultboundarywoulddependontheratingthe rmhadheldpreviously.Weshowinsimulationsthatourapproachresultsinmuchmorepreciseandlessskewedestimatesofinvestmentgradedefaultprobabilities.Fortheestimated10-yearBBBdefaultprobability,forexample,thestandarddeviationandskewnessusingthenewapproachareonly16%and4%respectivelyofthoseusingtheexistingapproach.Theimprovedprecisionispartlytheresultofthefactthatwecombineinformationacross20maturitiesand7ratings.But,toasigni cantextent,itistheresultofcombiningdefaultinformationoninvestmentgradeandhighyielddefaults.Becausedefaultsoccurmuchmorefrequentlyinhighyielddebt,these rmsprovidemoreinformationonthelocationofthedefaultboundary.Sincetheboundaryiscommontoinvestmentgradeandhighyielddebt,whenwecombineinvestment2 gradeandhighyielddefaultdata,we\import"theinformationonthelocationofthedefaultboundaryfromhighyieldtoinvestmentgradedebt.Thereductioninskewnessisalsotheresultofincludingdefaultratesthataresigni cantlyhigherthanthoseforBBBdebt.Whilelowinvestmentgradedefaultratesproduceapositiveskewinthedistributionofdefaults,adefaultrateof50%producesasymmetricdistributionand,forevenhigherdefaultrates,theskewisactuallynegative.WeuseourestimationapproachandtheBlack-Coxmodeltoinvestigatespreadsovertheperiod1987-2012.Ourdatasetconsistsof256,698corporatebondyieldspreadstotheswaprateofnoncallablebondsissuedbyindustrial rmsandismoreextensivethanthosepreviouslyusedintheliterature.OurimplementationoftheBlack-Coxmodelisnewtotheliteratureinthatitallowsforcross-sectionalandtime-seriesvariationin rmleverageandpayoutratewhilematchinghistoricaldefaultrates.Wethenapplyourproposedestimationapproachandestimatethedefaultboundarysuchthataveragemodel-implieddefaultprobabilitiesmatchaveragehistoricaldefaultratesfrom1920-2012.IncalibratingthedefaultboundaryweuseaconstantSharperatioandmatchtheequitypremium,butoncewehaveimpliedoutthesingle rm-widedefaultboundaryparameterwecompute rmandtime-speci cspreadsusingstandard\risk-neutral"pricingformulae.We rstexplorethedi erencebetweenaveragespreadsintheBlack-Coxmodelandactualspreads.Theaveragemodelspreadacrossallinvestmentgradebondswithamaturitybetween3and20yearsis111bpswhiletheaverageactualspreadis92bps.Acon dencebandforthemodelspreadthattakesintoaccountuncertaintyindefaultprobabilitiesis[88bps;128bps],thusthereisnostatisticaldi erencebetweenactualandmodelinvestmentspreads.Forspeculativegradebonds,theaveragemodelspreadis382bpswhiletheactualspreadis544bpsandherethedi erenceisstatisticallyhighlysigni cant.Wealsosortbondsaccordingtotheactualspreadand ndthatactualandmodel-impliedspreadsaresimilar,exceptforbondswithaspreadofmorethan1000bps.Forexample,forbondswithanactualspreadbetween100-150bpstheaverageactualspreadis136bpswhiletheaveragemodel-impliedspreadis121bps.Importantly,theresultsaresimilarifwecalibratethemodelusingdefaultratesfrom1970-2012ratherthan1920-2012,thusresolvingtheproblemdescribedabovethatearlierresultsintheliteraturedependsigni cantlyonthehistorical3 periodchosentobenchmarkthemodel.Tostudythetimeserieswecalculateaveragespreadsonamonthlybasisand ndthatforinvestmentgradebondsthereisahighcorrelationof93%betweenaverageactualspreadsandmodelspreads.Notethatthemodel-impliedspreadsare\out-of-sample"predictionsinthesensethatactualspreadsarenotusedinthecalibration.Furthermore,foragiven rmonlychangesinleverageandthepayoutrate{calculatedusingaccountingdataandequityvalues{leadtochangesinthe rm'screditspread.Forspeculativegradebondsthecorrelationisonly40%,showingthatthemodelhasamuchhardertimematchingspreadsforlow-quality rms.Althoughaverageinvestmentgradespreadsarecapturedwellonamonthlybasis,themodeldoeslesswellattheindividualbondlevel.RegressingindividualinvestmentgradespreadsonthoseimpliedbytheBlack-CoxmodelgivesanR2ofonly44%,soattheindividualbondlevellessthanhalfthevariationininvestmentgradespreadsisexplainedbythemodel.ForspeculativegradespreadsthecorrespondingR2isonly13%.Wealsoinvestigatethepotentialcontributionofbondilliquiditytocreditspreads.Weusebondageasliquiditymeasureanddouble-sortbondsonliquidityandcreditquality.Forinvestmentgradebondswe ndnorelationbetweenbondliquidityandspreads,consistentwiththeabilityofthemodeltomatchactualspreadsandthe ndinginDick-Nielsen,Feldhutter,andLando(2012)thatoutsidethe nancialcrisis2007-2008illiquiditypremiumsininvestmentgradebondswerenegligible.Forspeculativegradebondswe ndastrongrelationbetweenbondliquidityandyieldspreadsandtheresultssuggestthatbondliquiditymayexplainmuchoftheunderpricingofspeculativegradebonds.InthispaperweusetheBlackandCox(1976)modelasalensthroughwhichtostudythecreditspreadpuzzle.TheresultsinHuangandHuang(2012)showthatmanystructuralmodelswhichappearverydi erentinfactgeneratesimilarspreadsoncethemodelsarecalibratedtothesamedefaultprobabilities,recoveryrates,andtheequitypremium.ThemodelstestedinHuangandHuang(2012)includefeaturessuchasstochasticinterestrates,endogenousdefault,stationaryleverageratios,strategicdefault,time-varyingassetriskpre-mia,andjumpsinthe rmvalueprocess,yetallgenerateasimilarlevelofcreditspread.Thus,our ndingthattheBlack-Coxmodelmatchesaverageinvestmentgradespreadsis4 alsolikelytoholdforawiderangeofstructuralmodelsonceourestimationapproachisusedtoestimatedefaultprobabilities.Thereisanextensiveliteratureontestingstructuralmodels.Leland(2006),Cremers,Driessen,andMaenhout(2008),Chen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009),Chen(2010),HuangandHuang(2012),Chen,Cui,He,andMilbradt(2016),Bai(2016),Bhamra,Kuehn,andStrebulaev(2010),andZhang,Zhou,andZhu(2009))usethehistoricaldefaultrateatagivenratingandmaturitytoestimatethedefaultprobabilityatthatmaturityandrating.Weshowthatthistestisstatisticallyweak.Eom,Helwege,andHuang(2004),Ericsson,Reneby,andWang(2015),andBao(2009)allowforheterogeneityin rmsandvariationinleverageratios,butdonotcalibratetohistoricaldefaultrates.Bhamra,Kuehn,andStrebulaev(2010)observethatdefaultratesarenoisyestimatorsofdefaultprobabilities,butdonotproposeasolutiontothisproblemaswedo.2AmotivatingexampleThereisatraditioninthecreditriskliteratureofusingMoody'saveragerealizeddefaultrateforagivenratingandmaturityasaproxyforthecorrespondingex-antedefaultprobability.Thissectionprovidesanexampleshowingthattheapparentexistenceornon-existenceofacreditspreadpuzzledependsontheparticularperiodoverwhichthehistoricaldefaultrateismeasured.Laterinthepaperwedescribeanalternativeapproachforextractingdefaultprobabilityestimatesfromhistoricaldefaultratesthatnotonlyprovidesmuchgreaterprecisionbutisalsolesssensitivetothesampleperiodchosen.TounderstandhowMoody'scalculatesdefaultfrequencies,considerthe10-yearBBBcumulativedefaultfrequencyof5.09%usedinChen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009).3ThisnumberispublishedinMoody's(2002)andisbasedondefaultdatafortheperiod1970-2001.Fortheyear1970,Moody'sidenti esacohortofBBB-rated rmsandthenrecordshowmanyofthesedefaultoverthenext10years.The10-yearBBBdefaultfrequencyfor1970isthenumberofdefaulted rmsdividedbythenumberinthe1970cohort.Theaverage 3Moody'sreporta10-yearBBBdefaultrateof5.09%(Exhibit32)whileChen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009)use4.89%.WeuseMoody'sreportednumber.5 defaultrateof5.09%iscalculatedastheaverageofthetwenty-two10-yeardefaultratesforthecohortsformedatyearlyintervalsovertheperiod1970-1991AlargepartoftheliteraturehasfocussedontheBBB-AAAspreadat4-yearand10-yearmaturities.Inourmainempiricalanalysis(Section4)westudyamuchwiderrangeofratingsandmaturitiesbutfornow,tokeepourexamplesimple,wealsofocusontheBBB-AAAspread.ForagivensampleperiodweusetheBBBandAAAaveragedefaultratesforthe4-yearand10-yearhorizonsreportedbyMoody's.Followingtheliterature(e.g.,Chen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009),HuangandHuang(2012)andothers)we rstbenchmarkamodeltomatchthesedefaultrates,oneatatime.Usingthebenchmarkedparameterswethencomputerisk-neutraldefaultprobabilitiesand,fromthese,creditspreads.FollowingEom,Helwege,andHuang(2004),Bao(2009),HuangandHuang(2012),andothersweassumethatifdefaultoccurs,investorsreceive(atmaturity)afractionoftheoriginallypromisedfacevalue,butnowwithcertainty.Thecreditspread,s,isthencalculatedas:s=yr=1 Tlog[1(1R)Q(T)](1)whereRistherecoveryrate,TisthebondmaturityandQ(T)istherisk-neutralde-faultprobability.ThroughoutouranalysisweemploytheBlack-Coxmodel(BlackandCox(1976));AppendixAprovidesthemodeldetails.Weuseouraverageparametervaluesfortheperiod1987-2012estimatedinSection4andChen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009)'sestimatesoftheSharperatioandrecoveryrate.Weestimatethedefaultboundarybymatchinganobserveddefaultfrequency.Thedefaultboundaryisthevalueofthe rm,measuredasafractionofthefacevalueofdebt,belowwhichthe rmdefaults.FollowingChen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009)andotherswecarrythisoutseparatelyforeachmaturityandratingsuchthat,conditionalontheotherparameters,themodeldefaultprobabilitymatchesthereportedMoody'sdefaultfrequency.Foreachmaturityandratingwethenusethebenchmarkeddefaultboundaryandcalculatethecreditspreadusingequation(1)above.ThesolidbarsinFigure1showestimatesoftheactualBBB-AAAcorporatebondcreditspreadfromanumberofpapers.Forboththe4-yearand10-yearmaturities,theestimated6 BBB-AAAspreadisintherangeof98-109basispointswiththenotableexceptionofHuangandHuang(2012)'sestimateofthe10-yearBBB-AAAof131basispoints.(HuangandHuangusebothcallableandnon-callablebondsintheirestimateofthespreadandthismayexplainwhyitishigher).UsingMoody'saveragedefaultratesfromtheperiod1970-2001,the4-yearand10-yearBBB-AAAspreadsintheBlack-Coxmodelare52and72basispointsrespectively.Thesemodelestimatesaresubstantiallybelowactualspreadsandthis ndingiswhathasbeencoinedthecreditspreadpuzzle.Figure1alsoshowsthemodel-impliedspreadsusingMoody'saveragehistoricaldefaultratesfrom1920-2002(defaultratesfrom1920-2001arenotavailable).Themodel-impliedspreadsusingdefaultratesfromthislongerperiodaresubstantiallyhigher:the4-yearand10-yearBBB-AAAspreadsare87and104basispointsrespectively.Thus,whenweusedefaultratesfromalongertimeperiodthepuzzlelargelydisappearsToemphasisethatthisconclusionisnotspeci ctotheBlack-Coxmodel,Figure1alsoshowsthefourspreadscomputedundertheMertonmodel(andusingtheparametersandmethodgiveninChen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009)).Thesespreadsareverysimilarto,andjustalittlehigherthan,theBlack-Coxspreads.Whatremainsunchangedisthe ndingthattheappearanceofacreditspreadpuzzledependsonthesampleperiod.IntheexamplewearecomparingcorporatebondyieldsrelativetoAAAyieldstobeconsistentwithCDGandothers.Inourlateranalysisweusebondyieldsrelativetoswaprates.Theaveragedi erencebetweenswapratesandAAAyieldsissmall:overoursampleperiod1987-2012theaverage5-yearand10-yearAAA-swapspreadis4bpsrespectively6bps.Weuseswapratesinourlateranalysis,becausethetermstructureofswapratesisreadilyavailableonadailybasiswhilethereareveryfewAAA-ratedbondinthelaterpartofoursampleperiodandwewouldnotbeabletocalculateaAAAyieldatdi erentmaturities.Insummary,realisedaveragedefaultratesvarysubstantiallyovertimeand,asaresult,whenthesearetakenasex-antedefaultprobabilitiesthehistoricalperiodoverwhichtheyaremeasuredhasastrongin\ruenceonwhetherornottherewillappeartobeacreditspreadpuzzle.Inthenextsectionweexplorethestatisticaluncertaintyofhistoricaldefaultratesinmoredetailandproposeadi erentapproachtoestimatingdefaultprobabilitiesthatexploits7 theinformationcontainedinhistoricaldefaultratesmoreecientlythanhasbeenthecaseintheliteraturesofar.3Estimatingex-antedefaultprobabilitiesTheexistingliteratureonthecreditspreadpuzzleandmorebroadlytheliteratureoncreditrisktypicallyusestheaverageex-posthistoricaldefaultrateforasinglematurityandratingasanestimateoftheex-antedefaultprobabilityforthissamematurityandrating.We rstexplorethestatisticaluncertaintyassociatedwiththeseestimatesandconcludethatitislarge.Wethenproposeanewapproachthatuseshistoricaldefaultratesforallmaturitiesandratingssimultaneouslytoextracttheex-antedefaultprobabilityforagivenmaturityandrating.Simulationsshowthatourapproachgreatlyreducesstatisticaluncertainty.3.1Existingapproach:extractingtheex-antedefaultprobabilityfromasingleex-postdefaultfrequencyIntheliteratureonthepricingofcorporatedebtthereisalongtraditionofusingMoody'saveragehistoricaldefaultrateforasinglematurityandratingasaproxyfortheex-antedefaultprobabilityforthatspeci cmaturityandrating.4Therearetwosigni cantreasonswhyanex-postrealizeddefaultfrequencymaybeanunreliableestimateoftheex-antedefaultprobability.The rstisthatthelowlevelofdefaultfrequency,particularlyforinvestmentgrade rms,leadstoasamplesizeproblemwithdefaulthistoriesasshortasthosetypicallyusedintheliteraturewhentestingstandardmodels.Thesecondisthat,eventhoughtheproblemofsamplesizeispotentiallymitigatedbythepresenceofalargenumberof rmsinthecross-section,defaultsarecorrelatedacross rmsandsothebene tofalargecross-sectioninimprovingprecisionisgreatlyreduced. 4ExamplesincludeChen,Cui,He,andMilbradt(2016),Gomes,Jermann,andSchmid(2016),Christof-fersenandElkamhi(2016),Bai(2016),Zhang,Zhou,andZhu(2009),Chen(2010),Leland(2006),Cremers,Driessen,andMaenhout(2008),Chen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009),Chen(2010),HuangandHuang(2012),Campello,Chen,andZhang(2008),andMcQuade(2013).8 Howseverearethesestatisticalissues?Weaddressthisquestioninasimulationstudyandbaseoursimulationparametersontheaverage10-yearBBBdefaultrateof5.09%over1970-2001usedinChen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009).Inaneconomywheretheexante10-yeardefaultprobabilityis5.09%forall rms,wesimulatetheexpostrealized10-yeardefaultfrequencyover31years.Weassumethatinyear1wehave446identical rms,equaltotheaveragenumberof rmsinMoody'sBBBcohortsovertheperiod1970-2001.IntheBlack-Cox(andMerton)model rmi'sassetvalueunderthenaturalmeasurefollowsaGBMdVit Vit=()dt+dWPit(2)whereisthedriftof rmvaluebeforepayoutofthedividendyieldandisthevolatilityof rmvalue.AsinSection2aboveweuseouraverageparametervaluesfortheperiod1987-2012estimatedinSection4:=1005%,=472%and=246%.WeintroducesystematicriskbyassumingthatWPit=p Wst+p 1Wit(3)whereWiisaWienerprocessspeci cto rmiWsisaWienerprocesscommontoall rms,andisthepairwisecorrelationbetweenpercentagechangesin rmvalue.AlltheWienerprocessesareindependent.The rmdefaultsthe rsttimeassetvaluehitsaboundaryequaltoafractiondofthefacevaluedebtF,i.e.the rsttimeVdF.Therealized10-yeardefaultfrequencyintheyear-1cohortisfoundbysimulatingonesystematicand446idiosyncraticprocessesinequation(3).Inyear2weformacohortof446new rms.The rmsinyear2havecharacteristicsthatareidenticaltothoseoftheyear1cohortatthetimeofformation.Wecalculatetherealized10-yeardefaultfrequencyoftheyear-2cohortaswedidfortheyear-1cohort.Crucially,thecommonshockforyears1-9fortheyear-2cohortisthesameasthecommonshockforyears2-10for rmsintheyear-1cohort.Werepeatthesameprocessfor21yearsandcalculatetheoverallaveragerealizedcumulative10-yeardefaultfrequencyintheeconomybytakinganaverageofthedefaultfrequenciesacrossthe21cohorts.Finally,werepeatthisentiresimulation25,000times.9 Toestimatethecorrelationparameterwecalculatepairwiseequitycorrelationsforratedindustrial rmsintheperiod1987-2012.Speci cally,foreachyearwecalculatetheaveragepairwisecorrelationofdailyequityreturnsforallindustrial rmsforwhichStandard&Poor'sprovidearating,andthencalculatetheaverageofthe26yearlyestimates1987-2012.Weestimatetobe20.02%.Tosetthedefaultboundaryweproceedasfollows.First,withoutlossofgeneralityweassumethattheinitialassetvalueofeach rmisequaltoone.Thismeansthatthe rm'sleverage,LF V=F,andwesetthedefaultboundary,dF(=dL)suchthatthemodel-implieddefaultprobabilitygiveninequation(12)intheAppendixmatchesthe10-yeardefaultrateof5.09%.5Panel(a)ofFigure2showsthedistributionoftherealizeddefaultrateinthesimulationstudyandtheblackverticallineshowstheexantedefaultprobabilityof5.09%.The95%con denceintervalfortherealisedaveragedefaultrateiswideat[1.15%;12.78%].Giventhatwesimulate9366 rmsoveraperiodof31years,itmightbesurprisingthattherealizeddefaultratecanbefarfromtheexantedefaultprobability.Thereasonissimplythepresenceofsystematicriskintheeconomywhichinducescorrelationindefaultsacross rms.Wealsoseethatthedefaultfrequencyissigni cantlyskewedtotheright,i.e.,themodalvalueofaround3%issigni cantlybelowthemeanof5.09%.Thismeansthatthedefaultfrequencymostoftenobserved{e.g.,theestimatefromtheratingagencies{isbelowthemean.Speci cally,thetrue10-yeardefaultprobabilityis5.09%,buttheprobabilitythattheobservedaverage10-yeardefaultrateover31yearsishalfthatlevelorlessis19.9%.ThisskewnessmeansthatthenumberreportedbyMoody's(5.09%)ismorelikelytobebelowthetruemeanthanaboveitand,inthiscase,ifspreadsre\rectthetrueexpecteddefaultprobability,theywillappeartoohighrelativetotheobservedhistoricallossrate.Moody'snowpublishdefaultratesstartingfrom1920and,otherthingsequal,alongertimeperiodoverwhichwemeasureaveragedefaultrateswillleadtoimprovedstatistical 5Wesimulate rmvaluesonaweeklybasis.Thereisasmalldownward-biasindefaultratesbecauseadefaultonlyoccursonaweeklybasisandnotcontinuouslyandweadjustforthisbiasbymultiplyingaveragedefaultratesineachofthe25,000simulationswith5.09%dividedbytheaverageofthe25,000averagedefaultrates.10 precision.However,evenifthedefaultrateismeasuredoveratimeperiodof92yearsthereremainssigni cantstatisticaluncertaintywhenestimatesofthedefaultprobabilityarebasedonasingleratingandmaturity.Keepingthedefaultprobability xedat5.09%andincreasingthesimulatedtimeperiodfrom31yearsto92years,leadstoa95%con denceintervalof[2.47%;8.95%].Thusevenwith92yearsofdefaultdatathereisstillsigni cantuncertaintyregardingthetrueexantedefaultprobability.3.2Anewapproach:extractingtheex-antedefaultprobabilityfromacross-sectionofex-postdefaultfrequenciesWenowdescribeamethodtoestimatedefaultprobabilitiesthatusesrealisedcumulativedefaultratesfromawiderangeofratingsandmaturities.Thecentralidea,asdescribedearlier,isthatbecauselowcreditqualitybondsdefaultmorefrequently,theyprovidemuchmoreinformationonthelocationofthedefaultboundarythanhighcreditqualitybondsandwecanthereforeobtainbetterestimatesofthedefaultprobabilityonthelatterwhenwealsoincludedefaultrateinformationontheformer.Chen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009) ndthedefaultboundaryparameterdsuchthatthemodel-implieddefaultprobabilitymatchesthehistoricaldefaultrateatasingleratingandmaturity.Whencalculatingthe10-yearBBBspread,andgivenestimatesofP,thisapproachamountsto ndingdLsuchthatthemodel-implieddefaultprobabilityP(dL;P;T)inequation(12)isequaltothehistorical10-yearBBBdefaultrate.Chen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009)thenusethisdefaultboundarytocalculatethe10-yearBBBspreadaccordingtoequation(1).Ourapproachissimilarbut,crucially,we ttothehistoricaldefaultratesonallavailableratingsandmaturities.Weestimatethedefaultboundaryparameterdbyminimisingthesumofabsolutedeviationsbetweenannualizedmodel-impliedandhistoricaldefaultrates:minfdgCXa=AAA20XT=11 T P(dLaP;T)^PaT (4)where^PaTisthehistoricalcumulativedefaultrateforratingaandmaturityT6 6Theremaybealternativeweightingpatternsthatareevenmoreecientbutinmakingthischoiceour11 Howmuchofanimprovementisthisapproachrelativetothestandardapproachdescribedintheprevioussection?Weanswerthisquestionbysimulatingcumulativedefaultratesandapplyingequation(4)inordertoobtainthedistributionoftheestimateddefaultboundary.Followingtheproceduredescribedintheprevioussection,wesimulateoveraperiodof31yearsbutnowforeachofthesevenmajorratingcategories.Weassumethatall rms,regardlessofrating,havethesameparametersand,thesamecorrelationstructure(giveninequation(3))andthesamecorrelationparameter,.Thedefaultboundaryforeachratingcategoryisset,asintheprevioussection,suchthatthehistorical10-yearcumulativedefaultrateismatched.Sincediscommonacrossall rms,itmeansthat rmsindi erentratingcategoriesdi eronlyintheirinitialleverage.Wethensimulate1,...,20yeardefaultrates.Wesetthenumberof rmsineachratingcohortequaltotheaveragenumberof rmsintheMoody'scohortsforthatratingcategoryintheperiod1970-2001.Wecarryoutthissimulation25,000timesandforeachsimulationwe rstestimatedaccordingtoequation(4)andthencalculatethe10-yearBBBcumulativedefaultprobabilityinequation(12).Panel(b)ofFigure2showsthedistributionoftheestimateddefaultprobability.Weseethatthedistributionofthe10-yearBBBdefaultprobabilityisbothmuchtighterandlessskewedthanwhentheestimateisbasedonsolelythe10-yearBBBdefaultrate.Thedistributionismuchtighterbecauseweusedefaultratesfromallmaturitiesandratings,inparticularfromlowratings,insteadofjustone.Theskewnessisreducedbecauseweincludedefaultratesintheestimationthataresigni cantlyhigherthanBBBdefaultrates.Toseewhythisisthecase,considertheexamplediscussedearlierofalargenumberof rmswithadefaultprobabilityof5%andwheretheirdefaultsareperfectlycorrelated.Inthiscasewewillseenodefaults95%ofthetimeandtherealizeddefaultratewillunderestimatethedefaultprobability95%ofthetimeandthedistributionwillexhibitpositiveskewness.Bythesamelogic,ahigherdefaultprobabilityreducestheskewnessandfordefaultprobabilitiesgreaterthan50%theskewnessisinfactnegative.Table1comparesthestandarddeviationoftheestimateddefaultprobabilitiesintheexistingapproachandourapproachforalltheratingsandmaturitieswestudyinthenextsection.Ourapproachresultsinasubstantialreductioninthestandarddeviation,except objectivehasbeentokeepourmethodsassimpleandtransparentaspossible.12 fortheshortestmaturitiesofthelowestratings.Forexample,thestandarddeviationfortheestimated10-yearBBBdefaultprobabilityis0.48%comparedto3.05%usingtheexistingapproach.Table2showsthatforinvestmentgraderatings,ourapproachalsoresultsinasubstantialreductionintheskewness.Overall,ourproposedmethodgreatlyreducesboththestandarddeviationandskewnessofestimatedinvestmentgradedefaultprobabilities.74.AnewperspectiveonthecreditspreadpuzzleIntheprevioussectionweproposedanewmethodtoestimatedefaultprobabilitiesbycombininginformationonhistoricaldefaultratesfromthecrosssectionofratingcategoriesandmaturitiesandshowedthat,comparedtotheexistingapproachofusingasingledefaultrate,itgreatlyimprovesstatisticalprecision.Inthissectionweapplyourmethodtoalargedatasetofbondquotesover1987-2012toshednewlightonthecreditspreadpuzzle.4.1DataFortheperiodJanuary1,1997toJuly1,2012,weusedailyquotesprovidedbyMerrillLynch(ML)onallcorporatebondsincludedintheMLinvestmentgradeandhigh-yieldindices.Thesedataareusedby,amongothers,SchaeferandStrebulaev(2008)andAcharya,Amihud,andBharath(2013).WeobtainbondinformationfromtheMergentFixedIncomeSecuritiesDatabase(FISD)andlimitthesampletoseniorunsecured xedrateorzerocouponbonds.Weexcludebondsthatarecallable,convertible,putable,perpetual,foreigndenominated,Yankee,havesinkingfundprovisions,orhavecovenants.8FortheperiodApril1987toDecember1996weusemonthlydatafromtheLehmanBrothersFixedIncomeDatabase. 7InoursimulationswematchMoody'shistorical10-yeardefaultratesover1970-2001forratingsAAA,...,C.IntheInternetAppendixweshowthatthedistributionofthedefaultboundaryparameterd{andthereforealsothedistributionofthedefaultprobability{issimilarifwematchMoody'sdefaultratesatothermaturitiesthan10year.8Forbondrating,weusethelowerofMoody'sratingandS&P'srating.Ifonlyoneofthetworatingagencieshaveratedthebond,weusethatrating.Wetrackratingchangesonabond,sothesamebondcanappearinseveralratingcategoriesovertime.13 ThisdataisusedbyamongothersDu ee(1998),HuangandHuang(2012),andAcharya,Amihud,andBharath(2013).WeincludeonlydatafromtheLehmandatabasethatareactualquotes(incontrasttodatabasedonmatrix-pricing).TheLehmandatabasestartsin1973,buttherearetworeasonswhywestartfromApril1987.First,therearefewnoncallablebondsbeforethemid-80s(seeDu ee(1998))andsecond,wecalculatecreditspreadsrelativetotheswaprateandwedonothavedataonswapratespriortoApril1987.Weuseonlybondsissuedbyindustrial rmsandrestrictoursampletobondswithamaturityoflessthan20yearstobeconsistentwiththematuritiesofthedefaultratesweuseaspartoftheestimation.9Intotalwehave256,698observations.WeshowintheInternetAppendixthatdealerquotesareunreliableforshort-maturitybondsduetoquotesbeingbidquotesandwhenwereportbondspreadswethereforeexcludebondswithamaturitylessthanthreeyears.Table3showssummarystatisticsforthecorporatebondsample.ThetableshowsthatthenumberofbondswithalowratingofBorCissmall;forexamplethereisonlyoneC-ratedbondinthematuritygroup13-20y.Thereasonforthisisthatspeculativegradebondsfrequentlycontaincalloptionswhichleadstotheirexclusionfromoursample(seealsoBooth,Gounopoulos,andSkinner(2014)).InthefollowingwereportresultsforratingsBandC,butwiththecaveatthattheseresults{particularlyforlongmaturities{arebasedonfewobservationsandthereforenoisy.TopriceabondintheBlack-Coxmodelweneedtheissuing rm'sassetvolatility,leverageratio,andpayoutratioalongwiththebond'srecoveryrate.Leverageratioiscalculatedasthebookvalueofdebtdividedby rmvalue(where rmvalueiscalculatedasbookvalueofdebtplusmarketvalueofequity).Payoutratioiscalculatedasthesumofinterestpaymentstodebt,dividendpaymentstoequity,andnetstockrepurchasesdividedby rmvalue.AnimportantparameteristheassetvolatilityandherewefollowtheapproachofSchaeferandStrebulaev(2008)incalculatingassetvolatility.Since rmvalueisthesumofthedebtandequityvalues,assetvolatilityisgivenby:2t=(1Lt)22E;t+L2t2D;t+2Lt(1Lt)ED;t(5) 9IntheInternetAppendixweshowthatourresultsaresimilarifweuseTRACEtransactionsdatafortheshorterperiod2002-2012.14 wheretisthevolatilityofassets,D;tvolatilityofdebt,ED;tthecovariancebetweenthereturnsondebtandequity,andLtisleverageratio.Ifweassumethatdebtvolatilityiszero,assetvolatilityreducestot=(1Lt)E;t.Thisisalowerboundonassetvolatility.SchaeferandStrebulaev(2008)(SS)computethislowerboundalongwithanestimateofassetvolatilitythatimplementsequation(5)infull.They ndthatforinvestmentgradecompaniesthetwoestimatesofassetvolatilityaresimilarwhileforjunkbondsthereisasigni cantdi erence.Wecomputethelowerboundofassetvolatility,(1Lt)E;t,andmultiplythislowerboundwithSS'sestimateoftheratioofassetvolatilitycomputedfromequation(5)tothelowerbound.Speci cally,weestimate(1Lt)E;tandmultiplythisby1ifLt025,1.05if025Lt035,1.10if035Lt045,1.20if045Lt055,1.40if055Lt075,and1.80ifLt&#x-333;&#x.094;075.10Thismethodhastheadvantageofbeingtransparentandeasytoreplicate.Foragiven rmwethencomputetheaverageassetvolatilityoverthesampleperiodandusethisconstantassetvolatilityforeverydayinthesampleperiod.All rmvariablesareobtainedfromCRSPandCompustatanddetailsaregiveninAppendixB.Summarystatisticsforthe rmsinoursampleareshowninTable4.Theaverageleverageratiosof0.13forAAA,0.14forAA,0.27forA,and0.37forBBBaresimilartothosefoundinotherpapers:HuangandHuang(2012)usealeverageratioof0.13forAAA,0.21forAA,0.32forA,and0.43forBBBwhileSchaeferandStrebulaev(2008) ndanaverageleverageof0.10forAAA,0.21forAA,0.32forA,and0.37forBBB.Averageequityvolatilityismonotonicallyincreasingwithrating,consistentwithaleveragee ect.TheestimatesaresimilartothoseinSSforA-AAAratings,whiletheaverageequityvolatilityforBBB rmsof0.38ishigherthanthevalueof0.33giveninSS.AssetvolatilitiesareslightlyincreasinginratingandbroadlyconsistentwiththeestimatesinSS.Wesettherecoveryrateto378%whichisMoody's(2013)'saveragerecoveryrate,asmeasuredbypost-defaulttradingprices,forseniorunsecuredbondsfortheperiod1982-2012.Finally,theriskfreerate,r,istheswaprateforthesamematurityasthebond.Traditionally, 10ThesefractionsarebasedonTable7inSSapartfrom1.80whichwedeemtobereasonable.ResultsareinsensitivetootherreasonablechoicesofvaluesforL�075.SeealsoCorreia,Kang,andRichardson(2014)foranassessmentofdi erentapproachestocalculatingassetvolatility.15 Treasuryyieldshavebeenusedasriskfreerates,butrecentevidenceshowsthatswapratesareabetterproxythanTreasuryyields.AmajorreasonforthisisthatTreasurybondsenjoyaconvenienceyieldthatpushestheiryieldsbelowriskfreerates(FeldhutterandLando(2008),KrishnamurthyandVissing-Jorgensen(2012),andNagel(2014)).TheconvenienceyieldisforexampleduetotheabilitytopostTreasuriesascollateralwithasigni cantlylowerhaircutthanother nancialsecurities,ane ectoutsidethescopeofthemodel.4.2EstimationofthedefaultboundaryInthissectionweestimatethedefaultboundary,asingleparameterthatwethenusetopricebondsacrossratingsandmaturities.Althoughestimatingthedefaultboundaryparameter,d,by ttingtohistorical(natural)defaultratesrequiresanestimateoftheSharperatio,whenwecomputeyieldspreadsweusestandard\risk-neutral"pricing.WefollowthemethodoutlinedinSection3.2.Speci cally,ifweobserveaspreadonbondiwithatime-to-maturityTissuedby rmjondatet,wecalculatethe rm'sT-yeardefaultprobabilityP(dLjtPjt;T)wherePjt=(jt;j;jt)usingequation(12).Here,jisthe rm'sconstantassetvolatility,Ljtjtandjtarethetime-testimatesofthe rm'sleverageratio,assetvaluedriftandpayoutrate.TocalculatejtweassumeaconstantSharperatiosuchthatjt=j+rTtjt,whererTtistheT-yearriskfreerate.WeuseChen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009)'sestimateoftheSharperatioof0.22.ForagivenratingaandmaturityT-roundeduptothenearestintegeryear-we ndallbondobservationsinthesamplewiththecorrespondingratingandmaturity.Foragivencalendaryearywecalculatetheaveragedefaultprobability Py;aT(d)andwethencalculatetheoverallaveragedefaultprobabilityforratingaandmaturityT PaT(d),bycomputingthemeanacrosstheNyears, PaT(d)=1 NPNy=1 Py;aT(d).Wedenoteby^PaTthecorrespondinghistoricaldefaultfrequencygivenbyMoody'fortheperiod1920-2012.Forallmajorratings(AAA,AA,A,BBB,BB,B,C)andhorizonsof1-20years(Moody'sonlyreportsdefaultratesforuptoahorizonof20years)we ndthevalueofdthatminimizesthesumofabsolutedi erencesbetweentheannualizedhistoricalandmodel-implieddefaultratesbysolvingminfdgCXa=AAA20XT=11 T PaT(d)^PaT (6)16 Usingthisapproachourestimateis^d=08944.4.3ThetermstructureofdefaultprobabilitieswiththeestimateddefaultboundaryOurestimateofdmatchestheaveragedefaultprobabilityof rmsissuingstraightcouponbulletbondstoaveragehistoricaldefaultratesandtheremaybeatleastthreeconcernswiththisapproach.First, rmsissuingstraightcouponbulletbondsmaybedi erentfromtheaverage rminMoody'ssample.Second,althoughtheaveragehistoricaldefaultrateacrossmaturitiesismatched,thetermstructureofdefaultratesmightnotbematchedaccurately.Third,theremaybesystematicdi erencesintheabilityofthemodeltomatchdefaultratesacrossratings.Toaddresstheseconcernsweusetheestimateddefaultboundarytocomputetheaveragedefaultprobabilitiesforallratedindustrial rmsinCompustat{amuchbroadersample{andcomparethesetoMoody'shistoricaldefaultrates.Speci cally,weextractfromCapitalIGtheissuerseniordebtratingassignedbyStandard&Poor's.Therearealmostnoratingobservationsbefore1985,sooursampleperiodis1985-2012.Table5givessummarystatisticsonthemainparameters{asinTable4{forthisnewsample.Comparedtothesampleof rmsusedtoestimatedthedefaultboundary(inTable4)thesampleis4.6timesaslargeandhasareasonablylargenumberofspeculativegrade rms.Wecomputeaveragemodeldefaultprobabilitiesforagivenratingainamanneranal-ogoustothewayMoody'scalculateshistoricaldefaultrates.Speci cally,onthe naldayofeachmonthwe ndall rmsforwhichwehavedataandthathaveratinga,andforthose rmsanddateswecalculatethetermstructureofdefaultprobabilities,i.e.defaultprobabilitiesforhorizonsof1,2,...,20-years.Wethencalculatetheaveragetermstructureofdefaultprobabilitiesforeachyear1985,...,2012and, nally,wecomputetheaveragetermstructureacrossyears.Weusethe10-yearTreasuryCMTrateastheriskfreeratebecausewedonothaveswapratesinthe rstyears.Figure3andTable6showtheaveragemodel-implieddefaultprobabilitiesandMoody'shistoricaldefaultratesfor1920-2012.Inboththe gureandtableweshow95%con dence17 bandsforthehistoricaldefaultrate.Thecon dencebandisobtainedbyfollowingthesim-ulationprocedureinSection3.1wherewesimulateover92yearsanduseMoody'shistoricaldefaultratesfortheperiod1920-2012asinput.InTable6,caseswherethemodel-implieddefaultprobabilityisoutsidethe95%and99%con dencebandareindicatedby`*'and`**'respectively.WeseethatintheBlack-Coxmodelthereisastatisticallysigni cantunderestimationof1-2yearAAandAdefaultprobabilitiesandoverestimationofshort-termspeculativegradedefaultprobabilities.Thetermstructureofmodel-implieddefaultprobabilitiesisclosetohistoricaldefaultratesforAbeyondthreeyearsandforBBBrated rms.TheseratingcategoriesaccountformorethanhalfoftheUScorporatebondmarketvolume(measuredbythenumberoftransactions).11ItmayseemsurprisingthattheBlack-CoxmodelcapturesthetermstructureofdefaultratesforBBB-ratedbondswellbecausethereareanumberofpapersshowingthat,forhorizonsbelow3-4years,structuralmodelsimplyessentiallyzerodefaultprobabilitiesforinvestmentgrade rms(Zhou(2001),Leland(2004),Leland(2006),Cremers,Driessen,andMaenhout(2008),Zhang,Zhou,andZhu(2009)andothers).WeshowinAppendixCthatresultsintheexistingliteraturedocumentingafailureofstructuralmodelstocaptureshort-termdefaultratesarestronglybiasedduetoa\convexitye ect"arisingfromJensen'sinequality.Thebiasariseswhenusingarepresentative rmwithaverageleverage(andaverageassetvolatilityandpayoutrate)tocalculateshort-termdefaultprobabilitiesbecausethedefaultprobabilityusingaverageleverageissubstantiallylowerthantheaveragedefaultprobabilitycalculatedusingthedistributionofleverage.Ourresultsshowthatoncewedealwiththeconvexitybiasbyusingdataonindividual rmstheBlack-Coxmodelcapturesshort-termdefaultratesmuchbetterthanpreviouslyreported4.4AveragecorporatebondcreditspreadsWecalculateaveragespreadsbyfollowingthecalculationsinDu ee(1998).Speci cally,wecalculateamonthlyaverageactualspreadforagivenratinga,maturityrangeM1toM2 11AccordingtoTRACEFactBook2012,53%ofallU.S.corporatebondtransactionvolumein2012wasinAorBBBratedbonds(TablesC24andC25).18 andmontht.Toeasenotation,weindexthecombinationofrating,maturityrangeandmonthbyh=(a;;M1M2;t).Foragivenh,we ndallNhbondobservationswithratingaandindividualbondmaturitiesTh1;Th2;:::;ThNh,whereM1ThiM2,observedondaysh1;h2;:::;hNhinmontht.Denotingthecorrespondingyieldobservationsasyh1;yh2;:::;yhNhandtheswapratesassw(h1;Th1);sw(h2;Th2);:::;sw(hNh;ThNh),theaverageyieldspreadforratinga,maturityrangeM1toM2,andmonthtissh=1 NhNhXi=1yhisw(hi;Thi)(7)Theaverageyieldspreadforagivenratingandagivenmaturityintervalisthentheaverageofthemonthlyvalues.Similarly,wecalculatemodel-impliedspreadsbyreplacingtheactualspreadyhisw(hi;Thi)withthespreads(^d;Qjhi;Ljhi;hi;Thi)impliedbytheBlack-Coxmodelgiveninequation(1),whereQjhi=(sw(hi;Thi);jhi;jhi;hi;R),jhiistheassetvolatilityof rmjthatissuedbondiLjhi;hiandjhi;hiaretheleverageratioandpayoutraterespectivelyof rmjondayhiR=378%istherecoveryrate,andthedefaultboundary^d=08944,asestimatedinSection4.2.Wecomputecon denceintervalsforthemodel-impliedspreadsinthefollowingway.InSection3.2wecalculatethedistributionofthedefaultboundary.WeredothiscalculationusingMoody'sdefaultratesfrom1920-2012.Thatis,wesimulateover92yearsandsettheleverageratiosforeachratingsuchthatthehistorical10-yearcumulativedefaultratesforAAA,AA,...,Cfortheperiod1920-2012arematchedanduseforeachratingtheaveragecohortsizefortheperiod1970-2012inoursimulation.Fortheestimateddefaultboundarydistributionwecalculatethe2.5%and97.5%quantiles,q2:5%andq97:5%.Sincethemodel-impliedspreadismonotoneinthedefaultboundary,wecalculatealowerandupperboundonthemodel-impliedspreadbycomputingspreadsusingq2:5%^dandq97:5%^drespectively.4.4.1SortingaccordingtoratingTable7showsactualandmodel-impliedbondspreadsinoursample,calculatedusingtheapproachjustdescribed.Weseethattheaverageactualinvestmentgradespreadacrossmaturityis92bpswhiletheaveragemodel-impliedspreadis111bpsandtakingintoaccount19 theuncertaintyofdefaultprobabilitiesthedi erenceisstatisticallyinsigni cant.Wealsoseethatthereisagoodcorrespondencebetweenmodel-impliedandactualinvestmentgradespreadswhenwelookattheindividualmaturities3-7,7-13and13-20years.Thus,theBlack-Coxmodelcapturesaverageinvestmentgradespreadswell.Turningtospeculativegradespreadsweseeanunderpredictionofspreadsacrossmaturitywithaverageactualspreadsat544bpsandaveragemodelspreadsat382bpswiththedi erencebeingstatisticallysigni cant.WhenwelookatindividualinvestmentgraderatingsinTable7theBlack-CoxmodelslightlyunderpredictsspreadsonAAA-andAA-ratedbonds(by13-15bps)andoverpredictsspreadsonA-ratedbondsby24bps.ForA-ratedbondstheaverageactualspreadacrossmaturityis61bpswhileitis85bpsinthemodel.TheaverageactualBBBspreadacrossmaturityis146bpswhiletheaveragemodel-impliedspreadis169bps.Thus,theaveragespreadofbondswheremosttradingtakesplaceintheUScorporatebonds{bondswitharatingofAorBBB{iscapturedwellbytheBlack-Coxmodel.Forspeculativegradebonds,underpredictionincreasesaswemovedowntheratingscale.ForBB-ratedbonds,thereisnosigni cantunderpredictionformaturitiesbelow13years,whilemodelspreadsaretoolowforlongermaturities.Overall,theaveragelevelofactualandmodel-impliedinvestmentgradespreadsarestatisticallynotdi erent.Incontrastwe ndthatthemodelunderpredictsspeculativegradespreads;here,theaveragespreadacrossmaturityis544bpsinthedataand382bpsinthemodelandthedi erenceisstatisticallysigni cant.4.4.2SortingaccordingtoactualyieldspreadTheliteraturehastraditionallycomparedmodel-impliedandactualcreditspreadswithinratingcategories.Thereareseveralreasonsforthis.First,Moody'sprovidesyielddataanddefaultratesfrom1920andthereisthereforealonghistoryofdefaultandyieldorganisedaccordingtorating.Infact,sofarweareaware,theonlypubliclyavailabledataonaggregatedefaultratesareorganisedbyrating.Second,spreadsorganisedaccordingtoratingshowalargevariationinthemean,withlowerrated rmshavinghigheraveragespreads;matchingaveragebondspreadsorganisedbyratinghasprovidedahardtestforstructuralmodels.Althoughaveragedefaultratesareavailableonlybyrating,wecanneverthelesssort20 bondsinotherwaysinordertocomparemodel-impliedandactualspreads.Ifthereisasubstantialdi erence,themodelismisspeci edinsomedimension.Sinceanyusefulsortshouldresultinsigni cantvariationinspreads,themostobviouschoiceistosortaccordingbyactualspreads.Table8showsmodelspreadssortedaccordingtothesizeoftheactualspread.Weseethatforspreadsbelow1,000bpsthereisnostatisticaldi erencebetweenmodelspreadsandactualspreadswhenaveragedacrossmaturity.Forexample,theactualspreadforbondswithspreadsbetween100-150bpsis121bpswhileitis136bpsinthemodel.However,forbondspreadsabove150bpswestarttoseeamodestunder-predictionatlongmaturitieswhichbecomesstrongonlywhenspreadsareabove300bps.However,above1000bpsthemodelunderestimatesspreadssubstantiallyandheretheaveragemodelspreadisonlyaroundhalfoftheaverageactualspread.Overall,theresultswhensortingbyactualspreadaresimilartothosesortedbyrating,namelythatspreadsforlowcreditrisk rmsarematchedwellwhilespreadsforthehighestcreditrisk rms,particularforbondswithlongmaturity,areunder-predicted.4.5TimeseriesvariationinyieldspreadsHavingestablishedthattheBlack-Coxmodelcanmatchtheaveragesizeofinvestmentgradecreditspreads,wenextexaminewhetherthemodelcanalsocapturetheirtimeseriesvariation.Ineachmonth,wecalculatetheaverageactualyieldspreadforagivenratingaccordingtoequation(7)(wherethespreadisrelativetotheswaprate)alongwiththecorrespondingmodel-impliedaveragespreadandinvestigatethemonthlytimeseries.Toprovideanoverallassessmentofthemodel'sabilitytocaptureinvestmentgradespreads,wegrouptogetherallinvestmentgradespreadsandallmaturitiesbetween3-20yearsandplottheactualandmodel-impliedspreadsinFigure4.Weseethatthemodel-impliedspreadtrackstheactualspreadwellwithacorrelationis93%TotestmoreformallytheabilityoftheBlack-Coxmodeltocapturethetimeseriesvariationinspreads,weregressthemonthlytimeseriesoftheactualspread,st,onthe21 model-impliedspread,^stst= + ^st+t(8)andreportthe andtheR2oftheregressioninTable9PanelA.Thetableshowsthat{forallbondswithmaturitiesbetween3-20years{theregressionofactualinvestmentgradespreadsonmodel-impliedinvestmentgradespreadsgivesaslopecoecientof0.88andanR2equalto87%showingthatonceinvestmentgradespreadsareaggregatedmodel-impliedspreadstrackactualspreadsverywell.TheR2'sfortheseparateaggregateregressionsforAandBBBspreadsarehighat70%and88%respectively.ForspeculativegradeandAAA/AAratingstheBlack-Coxmodel'sabilitytocapturethetimeseriesvariationismuchlower.Morenoiseduetofewerobservationsisonefactorcontributingtothedeteriorating t.PanelBshowstheregressioninchanges,st+1st= + (^st+1^st)+t+1(9)andweseethattheR2'saresubstantiallylower.Thisimpliesthatthereissigni cantvariationinmonthlychangesincreditspreadsthatisnotexplainedbytheBlack-CoxmodelandCollin-Dufresne,Goldstein,andMartin(2001)andFeldhutter(2012)linkthisvariationtosupply/demandshocks.4.6SpreadpredictionsonindividualbondsOurmainresultisthat,whencalibratedtomatchhistoricaldefaultrates,theBlack-Coxmodelwithaconstant1)Sharperatio,2)recoveryrate,and3)defaultboundary,andnopricedrisksbeyonddi usionriskcanmatchtheaveragespreadofinvestmentgradebonds.Thisresultdoesnotnecessarilyimplythatthemodelcanmatchspreadsonindividualbondswithahighdegreeofprecision,becauseaveragespreadsmaywellmasksigni cantindividualpricingerrors.Whileourinterestliesmainlyinaskingwhetherthemodelcancaptureaveragespreads,weneverthelesscarryoutanexploratoryanalysisontheabilityofthemodeltocapturethecross-sectionofspreads(foramoreextensiveanalysisseeBao(2009)).22 The rstcolumninTable10showstheR2'sfromregressingactualspreadsonmodel-impliedspreads(andaconstant)attheindividualbondlevel.ForinvestmentgradebondstheR2is44%,substantiallybelowtheR2of87%obtainedusingmonthlyaveragespreadsandreportedinTable9.Forspeculativegradebondstheexplanatorypoweroftheregressionattheindividualbondlevelisonly13%,showingthatthemodelhasonlylimitedabilitytopricespeculativegradebonds.Togiveanindicationonhowthemodelorparameterestimatesmightbeimproved,wecorrelatethepricingerror{thedi erencebetweentheactualandmodel-impliedspread{withvariablesusedintheestimation.Table10showstheresults.Thepricingerrorsforinvestmentgradebondshaveacorrelationof-0.45withleverageand-0.34withthepayoutrate.Thissuggeststhatestimatesforindividualbondscouldbeimprovedeitherbyestimatingleverageandpayoutrateinadi erentwayorindeedbychangestothemodel.Correlationsbetween(equityandasset)volatilitiesandpricingerrorsaremodestandrangefrom-0.14to0.12.Thismayindicatethatabettermeasurementofvolatilityand/orincorporationofstochasticassetvolatilityintothemodelmaybelessimportantinimprovingcrosssectionalaccuracy.4.7TheroleofbondilliquidityAnumberofpapersexaminetheimpactofilliquidityoncorporatebondspreads;theseincludeDick-Nielsen,Feldhutter,andLando(2012)(DFL),Bao,Pan,andWang(2011),Friewald,Jankowitsch,andSubrahmanyam(2012)andLin,Wang,andWu(2011).Thesepapersexaminetransactionsdatafromtherelativelyrecentpast,typicallyfrom2004,butsinceweusespreaddatastartingbackin1987,wecanprovideevidenceontheimpactofilliquidityoncreditspreadsoveralongerhistoricaltimeperiod.Thedrawbackofourlongertimeperiodisthatwecannotcalculatetransactions-basedmeasuresofilliquidity.Insteadweusebondageasameasureofbondilliquiditysinceageisknowntoberelatedtoilliquidity(seeBao,Pan,andWang(2011)andHouweling,Mentink,andVorst(2005)andthereferencestherein).InTable11we rstsortaveragecreditspreadresidualsintoquintilesaccordingtobondageandthenaccordingtowhetherthebondisinvestmentgradeorspeculativegrade.Thetablereportstheaveragecreditspreadresidual,de nedasthe23 di erencebetweenthemodel-impliedandactualcreditspread,andtestswhetherthisaverageisdi erentfromzero.Forinvestmentgradebondsthereisessentiallynorelationbetweentheaveragepricingerrorandbondilliquidity.Thisisconsistentwiththe ndingsinDFL,Friewald,Jankowitsch,andSubrahmanyam(2012)andLin,Wang,andWu(2011)thatthepotentialimpactofilliquidityonpricesofinvestmentgradebondsismuchsmallerthanforspeculativegrade.Incontrast,Table11showsastrongrelationbetweenpricingerrorsandbondilliquidityforspeculativegradebonds.Forliquidspeculativegradebondsthepricingerrorismodestlypositive,butaswemovetomoreilliquidbondsastrongmodelunderpredictionemergesandtheaveragepricingerrordi erencebetweenbondsintheleastandmostliquidquintilesis470bps.Themagnitudeofthepricingerrordi erenceacrossbondilliquiditysuggeststhatmuch,ifnotall,oftheunderpredictionofspeculativegradecreditspreadscanbeexplainedbybondilliquidity.Thisinturnsuggeststhattopricespeculativegradebondsinstructuralmodels,itisimportanttoincorporateilliquidityinthesemodels.Asaninterestingclassofsuchmodels,HeandMilbradt(2014)andChen,Cui,He,andMilbradt(2016)incorporatesearchfrictionsinastructuralmodelofcreditriskinsuchawaythatilliquidityismoreimportantforspeculativegradebonds.Duringthe2008-2009 nancialcrisisDFL ndanilliquiditypremiuminAAA,AA,A,BBB,andspeculativegradebondsof5bps,42bps,51bps,93bps,and197bpsrespectively.IfwerestricttheanalysisinSection4.4tothecrisisperiodidenti edinDFL(2007:Q2-2009:Q2),formaturitiesbetween3and20yearswe ndthattheaveragedi erencebetweenactualandmodel-impliedspreadsforAAA,AA,A,BBB,andspeculativegradebondsis18bps,63bps,-43bps,-33bps,and262bpsrespectively(whencalculatedasinTable7).ForAAAandAAratedbondsthemodelunderpredictioniscomparabletotheliquiditypremiumfoundinDFLandforspeculativegradebondstheunderpredictionisaround100basispointslarger.Onehastobecarefulininterpretingpointestimatesofaveragespreaddi erencesinbasispointsoverarelativelyshortperiodwherespreadswereatahistoricalhighandveryvolatile,butifwetakethemodeloverpredictionof43bpsand33bpsforAandBBBratedbondsatfacevalue,itsuggeststhepresenceofsomemodelmisspeci cationduringthe nancialcrisis.24 4.8Usingdefaultdatafrom1970-2012toestimatethedefaultboundaryWesawinSection2thatwhenthehistoricalBBBandAAAdefaultratesareusedone-at-a-timeasestimatesoftheBBBandAAAdefaultprobabilities,theappearanceofacreditspreadpuzzledependsstronglytimeperiodoverwhichhistoricaldefaultratesarecalculated.Toseewhetherourproposedmethodsu ersfromthesamedrawback,weestimatethedefaultboundaryasdescribedinSection3.2but ttingtoMoody'sdefaultratesfrom1970-2012ratherthanthan1920-2012asinthemainanalysis.Inthiscasethedefaultboundaryisestimatedtobe^d=09302andTable12showsaveragespreadsusingthisvalue.Thetableshowsthatthereareonlymodestchangesinthemodel-impliedspreads.Forexample,theaverageinvestmentgradeandspeculativegradespreadsare122bpsand420bpsrespectivelywhenusingdefaultratesfrom1970-2012comparedto111bpsand382bpsrespectivelywhenusingdefaultratesfrom1920-2012.Figure5showstheresults,usingourproposedapproach,inthesameformatasFigure1calibratedbothto1970-2012and1920-2012.Unliketheearlierresultsweseethatresultsareverysimilar.Indeed,giventhedi erencesweobserveinFigure1,thestabilityofthemodel-impliedspreadsisstrikingandsuggeststhatbyusingacross-sectionofdefaultratestocalibratethemodel,wecanprovideboth rmerandmorestableconclusions.5.ConclusionMuchoftheexistingliteratureontestingstructuralmodelsreliesheavilyonestimatesofdefaultprobabilitiesobtainedfromhistoricaldefaultfrequencies.One,muchusedapproachusesthehistoricaldefaultrateforasingleratingandmaturityasanestimateofthedefaultprobabilitywhencalculatingthespreadatthatmaturityandrating.We ndthattheoutcomeofthisapproachdependsstronglyonthehistoricalperiodfromwhichthedefaultfrequenciesareobtainedandweshowinsimulationsthatasinglehistoricaldefaultrateisaverynoisyestimatorofthedefaultprobability.Furthermore,thedistributionofthehistoricaldefaultrateforanyinvestmentgraderatingisskewed,implyingthattheobserved25 defaultratemostlikelyisbelowtheex-antedefaultprobability.Thisinturnimpliesthatwhentestinginvestmentgradespreadpredictionsofastructuralmodelcalibratedtothehistoricaldefaultrate,mostlikelythemodel-impliedspreadwillappeartoolowrelativetotheactualspreadevenifthestructuralmodelisthetruemodel.Weproposeanewmethodtocalibratestructuralmodelstohistoricaldefaultrates.Inthisapproachweextractthedefaultboundary{thevalueofthe rm,measuredasafractionofthefacevalueofdebt,belowwhichthe rmdefaults{byminimizingthedi erencebetweenactualandmodel-implieddefaultratesacrossawiderangeofmaturitiesandratings.Weshowthatthisapproachdramticallyimprovesthestatisticalpropertiesofestimatedinvestmentgradedefaultprobabilities,bothintermsofstandarddeviationandskewness.UsingourproposedapproachwetesttheBlack-CoxmodelusingUSdataonspreadsfromindividual rmsovertheperiod1987-2012.We ndthatmodelspreadsmatchaverageactualinvestmentgradecreditspreadswell.Inotherwordswedonot ndevidenceofa\creditspreadpuzzle".Goingbeyondtestingthepuzzle,we ndthatthetimeseriesofmodel-impliedinvestmentgradespreadstracksaverageactualinvestmentgradespreadswellwithacorrelationof93%.Incontrast,we ndthatthemodelunderpredictsspeculativegradespreadssigni cantly.Weexplorethepotentiale ectofbondilliquiditybysortingpricingerrors{thedi erencebetweenmodel-impliedandactualspreads{onbondage,aproxyforbondilliquidity.We ndnorelationbetweenpricingerrorsandbondilliquidityininvestmentgradebonds.How-ever,thereisastronglymonotonerelationbetweenaveragepricingerrorsandbondilliquidityinspeculativegradebonds,suggestingthattoalargeextentthemodelunderpredictionforspeculativegradebondsisduetoanilliquiditypremium.Ourresultsshowthatthecreditspreadpuzzle-theperceivedfailureofstructuralmodelstoexplainlevelsofcreditspreadsforinvestmentgradebonds-haslesstodowithde cienciesofthemodelsthanwiththewayinwhichtheyhavebeenimplemented.WefocusourattentionontheBlack-Coxmodel,butthemodelisonlyaconvenienttoolandourresultshaveimportantimplicationsforstructuralmodelsingeneral.TheresultsinHuangandHuang(2012)showthatmanystructuralmodelswhichappearverydi erentinfactgenerate26 similarspreadsoncethemodelsarecalibratedtothesamehistoricaldefaultrates,recoveryrates,andtheequitypremium.ThemodelstestedinHuangandHuang(2012)includefeaturessuchasstochasticinterestrates,endogenousdefault,stationaryleverageratios,strategicdefault,time-varyingassetriskpremia,andjumpsinthe rmvalueprocess,yetallgenerateasimilarlevelofcreditspread.Chen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009)pointoutthesigni canceofthis ndinganddiscusstherelationbetweenthepricingkernel,thedefaulttimeandLGDthatwouldresultinhigherspreads.Fromtheno-arbitragecondition,thepriceofacorporatebondcanbewrittenasP=1 rEEXscov(ms;Xs)(10)whereXsisthebondcash\rowinstatesmsisthepricingkernelandristherisklessrate.Calibratingdi erentmodelstothesamehistoricaldefaultrateandrecoveryratewillresultinthe rstterminequation(10)beingsimilaracrossmodels.FixingtheSharperatio,recoveryrate,anddefaultratewillresultinthesecondtermbeingsimilarifdi erentmodelsresultinsimilarvaluesoftheelasticityofthebondpricetothe rm'sassetvalue.TheimplicationofthestrikingresultsinHHisthatforthewiderangeofmodelstheyconsidered,theelasticitiesareindeedsimilar.Therefore,allthestructuralmodelsconsideredbyHuangandHuang(2012){and,possiblystillothersthatgeneratesimilarelasticities{thatarecalibratedtothesamehistoricalrecoveryrate,thehistoricalSharperatio,anddefaultprobabilitieswillgeneratespreadsthataresimilar,bothtoeachotherandtotheBlack-Coxmodel,andtherefore,aswehavefound,consistentwithhistoricalinvestmentgradespreads.27 ATheBlack-CoxmodelWeassumethata rm'sassetvaluefollowsaGeometricBrownianMotionunderthenaturalmeasure,dVt Vt=()dt+dWPt(11)whereisthepayoutratetodebtandequityholders,istheexpectedreturnonthe rm'sassetsandisthevolatilityofreturnsontheasset.The rmis nancedbyequityandasinglezero-couponbondwithfacevalueFandmaturityT.The rmdefaultsthe rsttimetheassetvalueisbelowsomefractiondofthefacevalueofdebt.Oneinterpretationofthedefaultboundaryisthatthebondhascovenantsinplacethatallowbondholderstotakeoverthe rmif rmvaluefallsbelowthethreshold.ThecumulativedefaultprobabilityintheBlack-CoxmodelattimeTis(seeBao(2009))P(dL;P;T)=Nh(log(dL)+2 2T p Ti+exp2log(dL)(2 2) 2Nhlog(dL)+2 2T p Ti(12)whereL=F V0istheleverageandP=(;;).Therisk-neutraldefaultprobability,Q,isobtainedbyreplacingwithrinequation(12).BFirmdataTocomputebondpricesintheMertonmodelweneedtheissuing rm'sleverageratio,payoutratio,andassetvolatility.ThisAppendixgivesdetailsonhowwecalculatethesequantitiesusingCRSP/Compustat.FirmvariablesarecollectedinCRSPandCompustat.Todosowematchabond'sCUSIPwithCRSP'sCUSIP.Intheorythe rst6digitsofthebondcusipplusthedigits`10'correspondstoCRSP'sCUSIP,butinpracticeonlyasmallfractionof rmsismatchedthisway.Evenifthereisamatchwecheckiftheissuing rmhasexperiencedM&Aactivityduringthelifeofthebond.Ifthereisnomatch,wehand-matchabondcusipwith rmvariablesinCRSP/Compustat.28 Leverageratio :Equityvalueiscalculatedonadailybasisbymultiplyingthenumberofsharesoutstandingwiththepriceofshares.DebtvalueiscalculatedinCompustatasthelatestquarterobservationoflong-termdebt(DLTTQ)plusdebtincurrentliabilities(DLCQ).LeverageratioiscalculatedasDebtvalue Debtvalue+EquityvaluePayoutratio :Thetotalout\rowtostakeholdersinthe rmisinterestpaymentstodebtholders,dividendpaymentstoequityholders,andnetstockrepurchases.Interestpaymentstodebtholdersiscalculatedasthepreviousyear'stotalinterestpayments(previousfourthquarter'sINTPNY).Dividendpaymentstoequityholdersistheindicatedannualdividend(DVI)multipliedbythenumberofshares.Theindicatedannualdividendisupdatedonadailybasisandisadjustedforstocksplitsetc.Netstockrepurchaseisthepreviousyear'stotalrepurchaseofcommonandpreferredstock(previousfourthquarter'sPRSTKCY).Thepayoutratioisthetotalout\rowtostakeholdersdividedby rmvalue,where rmvalueisequityvalueplusdebtvalue.Ifthepayoutratioislargerthan0.13,threetimesthemedianpayoutinthesample,wesetitto0.13.Equityvolatility :Wecalculatethestandarddeviationofdailyreturns(RETinCRSP)inthepastthreeyearstoestimatedailyvolatility.Wemultiplythedailystandarddeviationwithp 255tocalculateannualizedequityvolatility.Iftherearenoreturnobservationsonmorethanhalfthedaysinthethreeyearhistoricalwindow,wedonotcalculateequityvolatilityanddiscardanybondtransactionsonthatday.29 CConvexitybiaswhenusinga\representative rm"tocalculatedefaultprobabilitiesOur ndingintheSection4.3thattheBlack-CoxmodelmatchesdefaultprobabilitiesforBBB-rated rmsevenforhorizonsasshortasoneyearissurprising,sinceitisanestablishedstylizedfactintheliteraturethatshort-rundefaultprobabilitiesinstructuralmodelswithonlydi usion-riskaremuchtoolow.Papersshowingthatdefaultprobabilitiesatshorthori-zonsaretoolowincludeamongothersZhou(2001),Leland(2004),Leland(2006),Cremers,Driessen,andMaenhout(2008),Zhang,Zhou,andZhu(2009),andMcQuade(2013).Thereasonthatwearriveatadi erentconclusionisthatweallowforcross-sectionalvariationinassetvolatilityandbothcross-sectionalandtimeseriesvariationinleverageandpayoutrates.Incontrast,theexistingliteratureusesa\representative rm"withaverageassetvolatility,leverage,andpayoutratewithinagivenratingcategory.Usingarepresentative rmleadstoabiasduetoJensen'sinequalitybecausethedefaultprobabilityistypicallyconvexinassetvolatilityandleverage(whileitisclosetolinearinthepayoutrate).ThisconvexitybiasinthecaseofleverageisillustratedinFigureA1.Theconvexitybiaswhenusingarepresentative rmtocalculatespreadsisknowntotheliterature,butimportantlytheimpactoftheconvexitybiasontheshort-rundefaultprobabilitieshasnotbeenrecognizedintheliterature.12Todocumenttheimpactoftheconvexitybiasonshort-rundefaultprobabilitieswefocusonheterogeneityinleverageandcarryoutasimulationof100,000 rms.Foreach rmweuseanassetvolatilityof23%,apayoutrateof3.3%,andaSharperatioof0.22.The rmsdi eronlyintheirleverageratiosandwedraw100,000valuesfromanormaldistributionwithmean0.29andastandarddeviationof0.18.13ThechosenvaluesaremedianvaluesforBBB rmsandthestandarddeviationofleverageinthesimulationisequaltotheempiricalstandarddeviationofBBB rmsinthesample.Finally,theriskfreerateis5%.Foreach rmwecalculatethecumulativedefaultprobabilityfordi erentmaturities.PanelAinTable 12Bhamra,Kuehn,andStrebulaev(2010)presentastructural-equilibriummodelwithmacro-economicriskandsimulatedefaultratesover5and10yearsand ndthereisasubstantiale ectofallowingfor rmheterogeneity.Theydonotlookatdefaultprobabilitiesbelow veyears,ourmainfocus.13Ifasimulatedleverageratioisnegativewesetittozero.Thisimpliesthattheaverageleverageratioisslightlyhigherthan0.29,namely0.2937inoursimulation.30 A1showstheaveragedefaultprobabilityandthecorrectassetvolatilityof23%thatisusedforall rmsandatallmaturities.Zhou(2001),Leland(2004),Leland(2006),andMcQuade(2013)usevaluesofthelever-ageratio,payoutrate,andassetvolatilityaveragedovertimeand rmstocalculatemodel-implieddefaultprobabilitiesforarepresentative rmandthencomparethesewithhistoricalaverages.ToseetheextentoftheconvexitybiasintheBlack-Coxmodelwhenusingtheirapproach,wecalculatethetermstructureofdefaultprobabilitiesinPanelBofTableA1forarepresentative rmwithaleverageratioequaltothemeaninoursimulationof0.29.ThereisadownwardbiasindefaultprobabilitiesrelativetothecorrectvaluesgiveninPanelAandthebiasbecomesmorepronouncedatshortermaturities.Forexample,theone-yeardefaultprobabilityoftherepresentative rminPanelBis0.00%whilethetrueaveragedefaultprobabilityinPanelAis0.42%.Theaforementionedpaperscomparethedefaultprobabilityoftherepresentative rmwiththeaveragehistoricaldefaultrateandsincethehistoricaldefaultratere\rectstheaveragedefaultprobabilitiesinPanelA,theirresultsforparticularlyshort-maturitydefaultprobabilitiesarestronglybiased.Cremers,Driessen,andMaenhout(2008),Zhang,Zhou,andZhu(2009),andHuangandHuang(2012)letarepresentative rmmatchhistoricaldefaultratesbybackingoutassetvolatility.Toexaminehowtheconvexitybiasin\ruencestheimpliedassetvolatilityweproceedasfollows.Foragivenmaturity,wecomputetheassetvolatilitythatallowstherepresentative rmtomatchtheaveragedefaultprobabilityintheeconomyatthatgivenmaturity.PanelCshowstheimpliedassetvolatilitiesandweseethattherearetwoproblemswiththisapproach.The rstproblemisthatassetvolatilityisbiased:all rmsintheeconomyhaveanassetvolatilityof23%andyettheimpliedassetvolatilityrangesfrom27.0%atthe10-yearhorizonto43.3%attheone-yearhorizon.The ndingthatimpliedassetvolatilityinthedi usion-typestructuralmodelsistoohigh,particularatshorterhorizonshasbeenseenasafailureofthemodels,butthisexampleshowsthatthehighimpliedassetvolatilityarisesmechanicallyfromtheuseofarepresentative rm.Thesecondproblemisthatitisnotpossibletomatchthetermstructureofdefaultprobabilitieswithoutcounterfactuallychangingtheassetvolatilitymaturity-by-maturity.Cremers,Driessen,andMaenhout(2008)andZhang,Zhou,andZhu(2009)usearep-31 resentative rmtoimplyoutassetvolatilitybymatchinglong-termdefaultratesandthenusethisassetvolatilitytocalculatethetermstructureofdefaultprobabilities.Wereplicatethisapproachbyimplyingouttheassetvolatilitythatmakestherepresentative rm'sde-faultprobabilitymatchtheaveragedefaultprobabilityforthe10-yearbondintheeconomyandthencalculatethetermstructureofdefaultprobabilitiesforthisrepresentative rm.Theimpliedassetvolatilityis27.0%andthetermstructuresareinPanelD.Thedi erencebetweentheimpliedassetvolatilityof27.0%andthetruevalueof23%re\rectsamoderateconvexitybiasatthe10-yearhorizon,butsincethebiasbecomesmoresevereatshorterhorizons,thestrongdownwardbiasindefaultprobabilitiesreappearsasmaturitydecreases.Thus,thebiasinshort-termdefaultprobabilitiespersistswhenusingarepresentative rmandimputingassetvolatilitybymatchingalong-termdefaultrate14Insummary,weshowthatthetermstructureofdefaultprobabilitiesintheBlack-Coxmodelisdownwardbiased,andmoresoatshortmaturities,whenusingarepresentative rm.Thisislikelytobetrueforanystandardstructuralmodel:defaultprobabilitiesarestronglybiasdownwardsatshortmaturities.Existingevidence(showingthatdefaultprobabilitiesatshorthorizonsaremuchtoolow)inZhou(2001),Leland(2004),Leland(2006),Cremers,Driessen,andMaenhout(2008),Zhang,Zhou,andZhu(2009),andMcQuade(2013)issubjecttothisstrongbiasandthereforenotreliable. 14OurresultsclarifythoseinBhamra,Kuehn,andStrebulaev(2010).Withintheframeworkoftheirstructural-equilibriummodel,theycomparearepresentative rmwithacrosssectionof rmsand ndthattheslopeofthetermstructureofdefaultprobabilitiesis\ratterforthecrosssectionof rms.Intheirexperiment,thecrosssectionof rmshaveanaveragedefaultprobabilitythatismorethanthreetimesaslargeasthedefaultprobabilityoftherepresentative rm(theirTable3,PanelsBandC).Sincethetermstructureofdefaultprobabilitiesbecomes\ratterforarepresentative rmatthesametimeasdefaultriskincreases,itisnotclearifitiscrosssectionalvariationortheriseindefaultprobabilitythatdrivesthe\ratteningofthetermstructure.Sinceweholdthe10-yeardefaultprobability xedinPanelsAandD,itisclearinouranalysisthatthe\rattertermstructureisdrivenbycross-sectionalvariationinleveragealone.32 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 0.55 0.6 0 0.5 1 1.5 leverage ratiodefault probabilitiy in percent1-year default probability of a typical investment firm in the Black-Cox model low leverage high leverage average leverageodef prob of average leverage oaverage def prob Fig.A1ConvexitybiaswhencalculatingthedefaultprobabilityintheBlack-Coxmodelusingaverageleverageandcomparingittotheaveragedefaultprobability.Itiscommonintheliteraturetocomparehistoricaldefaultratestomodel-implieddefaultprobabilities,wherethelatterarecalculatedusingaverage rmvariables.Thisintroducesabiasbecausethedefaultprobabilityinstructuralmodelsisanon-linearfunctionof rmvariables.The gureillustratesthebiasincaseoftwo rmobservationswiththesamerating,onewithalowleverageratioandonewithahighleverageratio.Thetwoobservationscanbetwodi erent rmsatthesamepointintimeorthesame rmattwodi erentpointsintime.Assetvolatilityis5%,dividendyield3.7%,Sharperatio0.22,andriskfreerate5%.33 maturity12345678910 PanelA:Trueeconomy(thereisvariationinleverageratios) averagedefaultprobability0.130.591.241.982.753.504.234.925.586.20assetvolatility25.025.025.025.025.025.025.025.025.025.0PanelB:Representative rm(averageleverageratioused) defaultprobability0.000.000.050.200.490.891.371.902.463.03assetvolatility25.025.025.025.025.025.025.025.025.025.0PanelC:Representative rm,averagedef.prob.atbondmaturityismatched defaultprobability0.130.591.241.982.753.504.234.925.586.20impliedassetvolatility44.337.334.332.631.430.529.929.328.928.6PanelD:Representative rm,averagedef.prob.at10-yearbondmaturityismatched defaultprobability0.000.030.240.741.472.343.304.285.256.20impliedassetvolatility28.628.628.628.628.628.628.628.628.628.6TableA1ConvexitybiaswhencalculatingdefaultprobabilitiesintheBlack-Coxmodelusingtherepresentative rmapproach.Itiscommonintheliteraturetocompareaverageactualdefaultratestomodel-implieddefaultprobabilities,wheremodel-implieddefaultprobabilitiesarecalculatedusingaverage rmvariables.ThisintroducesabiasbecausethedefaultprobabilityandspreadintheMertonmodelisanon-linearfunctionof rmvariables.Thistableshowsthemagnitudeofthisbias.PanelAshows,formaturitiesbetweenoneand10years,theaveragedefaultprobabilityfor100,000 rmsthathavedi erentleverageratiosbutareotherwiseidentical.Theircommonassetvolatilityis25%andpayoutrate3.7%.Theirleverageratiosaresimulatedfromanormaldistributionwithmean0.28andstandarddeviation0.18(truncatedatzero).Theriskfreerateis5%.PanelBshowsthedefaultprobabilityofarepresentative rmwheretheaverageleverageratioisused.InPanelC,foreachmaturity{oneatatime{anassetvolatilityiscomputedsuchthat,forarepresentative rmwithaleverageratioequaltotheaverageleverageratio,thedefaultprobabilityisequaltotheaveragedefaultprobabilityintheeconomy(giveninthe rstrowinPanelAandagaininPanelC).Thisisdoneseparatelyforeachmaturity.Thepanelshowstheresultingimpliedassetvolatility.PanelDshowstheresultsofacalculationsimilartothatinPanelCexceptheretheassetvolatilityusedtocomputethedefaultprobabilityforeachmaturityisthevaluethatmatchestheaverage10-yeardefaultprobabilityintheeconomy.34 ReferencesAcharya,V.,Y.Amihud,andS.Bharath(2013).Liquidityriskofcorporatebondreturns:conditionalapproach.JournalofFinancialEconomics110(2),358{386.Bai,H.(2016).Unemploymentandcreditrisk.WorkingpaperBao,J.(2009).StructuralModelsofDefaultandtheCross-SectionofCorporateBondYieldSpreads.WorkingpaperBao,J.,J.Pan,andJ.Wang(2011).TheilliquidityofCorporateBonds.JournalofFinance66,911{946.Bhamra,H.S.,L.-A.Kuehn,andI.A.Strebulaev(2010).TheLeveredEquityRiskPre-miumandCreditSpreads:AUni edFramework.ReviewofFinancialStudies23(2),645{703.Black,F.andJ.Cox(1976).ValuingCorporateSecurities:SomeE ectsofBondIndentureProvisions.JournalofFinance31,351{367.Booth,L.,D.Gounopoulos,andF.Skinner(2014).Thechoicebetweencallableandnoncallablebonds.TheJournalofFinancialResearch37(4),435{459.Campello,M.,L.Chen,andL.Zhang(2008).Expectedreturns,yieldspreads,andassetpricingtests.ReviewofFinancialStudies21(3),1297{1338.Chen,H.(2010).Macroeconomicconditionsandthepuzzlesofcreditspreadsandcapitalstructure.JournalofFinance65(6),2171{2212.Chen,H.,R.Cui,Z.He,andK.Milbradt(2016).QuantifyingLiquidityandDefaultRisksofCorporateBondsovertheBusinessCycle.WorkingPaperChen,L.,P.Collin-Dufresne,andR.S.Goldstein(2009).Ontherelationbetweenthecreditspreadpuzzleandtheequitypremiumpuzzle.ReviewofFinancialStudies223367{3409.Christo ersen,P.andD.D.R.Elkamhi(2016).RareDisasters,Credit,andOptionMarketPuzzles.forthcoming,ManagementScience35 Collin-Dufresne,P.,R.Goldstein,andS.Martin(2001).TheDeterminantsofCreditSpreadChanges.JournalofFinance56,2177{2207.Correia,M.,J.Kang,andS.Richardson(2014).Assetvolatility.WorkingpaperCremers,M.,J.Driessen,andP.Maenhout(2008).Explainingthelevelofcreditspreads:Option-impliedjumpriskpremiaina rmvaluemodel.ReviewofFinancialStudies212209{2242.Dick-Nielsen,J.,P.Feldhutter,andD.Lando(2012).Corporatebondliquiditybeforeandaftertheonsetofthesubprimecrisis.JournalofFinancialEconomics103,471{492.Du ee,G.R.(1998).TheRelationBetweenTreasuryYieldsandCorporateBondYieldSpreads.JournalofFinance53(6),2225{2241.Eom,Y.H.,J.Helwege,andJ.-Z.Huang(2004).Structuralmodelsofcorporatebondpricing:Anempiricalanalysis.ReviewofFinancialStudies17(2),499{544.Ericsson,J.,J.Reneby,andH.Wang(2015).Canstructuralmodelspricedefaultrisk?Evidencefrombondandcreditderivativemarkets.QuarterlyJournalofFinance5(3).Feldhutter,P.(2012).Thesamebondatdi erentprices:identifyingsearchfrictionsandsellingpressures.ReviewofFinancialStudies25,1155{1206.Feldhutter,P.andD.Lando(2008).DecomposingSwapSpreadsJournalofFinancialEconomics88,375{405.Friewald,N.,R.Jankowitsch,andM.G.Subrahmanyam(2012).Illiquidityorcreditdete-rioration:astudyofliquidityintheUScorporatebondmarketduring nancialcrises.105,18{36.JournalofFinancialEconomics.Gomes,J.,U.Jermann,andL.Schmid(2016).StickyLeverage.forthcoming,AmericanEconomicReviewHe,Z.andK.Milbradt(2014).EndogenousLiquidityandDefaultableDebt.Economet-rica82(4),1443{1508.Houweling,P.,A.Mentink,andT.Vorst(2005).Comparingpossibleproxiesofcorporatebondliquidity.JournalofBankingandFinance29,1331{1358.36 Huang,J.andM.Huang(2012).HowMuchoftheCorporate-TreasuryYieldSpreadisDuetoCreditRisk?ReviewofAssetPricingStudies2(2),153{202.Krishnamurthy,A.andA.Vissing-Jorgensen(2012).TheAggregateDemandforTreasuryDebt.JournalofPoliticalEconomy120(2),233{267.Leland,H.(2004).PredictionsofDefaultProbabilitiesinStructuralModelsofDebt.JournalofInvestmentManagement2Leland,H.(2006).StructuralModelsofCorporateFinancialChoice.PrincetonLecturesinFinance,Lecture1Lin,H.,J.Wang,andC.Wu(2011).Liquidityriskandexpectedcorporatebondreturns.JournalofFinancialEconomics99,628{650.McQuade,T.J.(2013).StochasticVolatilityandAssetPricingPuzzles.WorkingPaper,HarvardUniversityMerton,R.(1974).OnthePricingofCorporateDebt:TheRiskStructureofInterestRates.JournalofFinance29,449{470.Moody's(2002).DefaultandrecoveryRatesofCorporateBondissuers-AStatisticalReviewofMoody'sRatingsperformance1970-2001.Moody'sinvestorsService,1{52.Moody's(2013).AnnualDefaultStudy:CorporateDefaultandRecoveryRates,1920-2012.Moody'sInvestorsService,1{64.Nagel,S.(2014).TheLiquidityPremiumofNear-MoneyAssets.WorkingpaperSchaefer,S.andI.Strebulaev(2008).Structuralmodelsofcreditriskareuseful:Evidencefromhedgeratiosoncorporatebonds.JournalofFinancialEconomics90,1{19.Zhang,B.Y.,H.Zhou,andH.Zhu(2009).ExplainingCreditDefaultSwapSpreadswiththeEquityVolatilityandJumpRisksofIndividualFirms.ReviewofFinancialStudies22(12),5101{5131.Zhou,C.(2001).Thetermstructureofcreditspreadswithjumprisk.JournalofBankingandFinance25,2015{2040.37 horizon(years)4567891011121314151617181920 AAA Newmethod0.000.010.020.030.050.070.090.110.140.160.180.200.220.240.260.280.29Existingmethod0.020.050.110.210.340.520.720.951.201.461.732.002.272.542.793.033.27Ratio10%14%15%15%14%13%13%12%11%11%10%10%10%10%9%9%9% AA Newmethod0.000.010.020.040.060.080.100.130.150.170.200.220.240.260.280.290.31Existingmethod0.010.050.110.220.370.560.781.031.291.561.852.132.412.682.943.193.44Ratio17%18%17%16%15%14%13%12%12%11%11%10%10%10%9%9%9% A Newmethod0.010.020.040.070.100.140.170.200.230.260.290.320.340.360.380.400.42Existingmethod0.030.100.220.400.640.911.231.571.912.262.622.973.303.633.944.234.51Ratio24%22%20%18%16%15%14%13%12%12%11%11%10%10%10%9%9% BBB Newmethod0.080.150.220.290.360.420.480.520.570.600.640.670.690.710.730.750.77Existingmethod0.240.530.931.401.922.473.053.634.194.725.255.766.226.667.067.447.78Ratio32%27%24%21%19%17%16%14%14%13%12%12%11%11%10%10%10% BB Newmethod0.981.171.311.401.471.521.551.581.591.601.611.611.621.621.611.611.61Existingmethod2.273.284.235.156.026.847.648.389.099.7610.4010.9911.5512.0612.5312.9413.32Ratio43%36%31%27%24%22%20%19%18%16%15%15%14%13%13%12%12% B Newmethod3.113.093.052.992.932.872.822.772.722.682.642.602.562.532.502.472.44Existingmethod5.356.277.067.778.419.019.5510.0610.5511.0211.4711.8912.2812.6512.9813.3013.59Ratio58%49%43%38%35%32%30%28%26%24%23%22%21%20%19%19%18% C Newmethod5.214.844.564.334.154.003.873.753.653.573.493.423.353.303.243.193.15Existingmethod5.155.455.725.986.236.456.676.877.097.297.497.687.868.038.198.368.50Ratio101%89%80%72%67%62%58%55%52%49%47%44%43%41%40%38%37%Table1Standarddeviationoftheestimateddefaultprobability.Thistableshowsthestandarddeviationoftheestimateddefaultprobability(inpercent)whentheestimateisbasedonaveragehistoricaldefaultratesover31years.Thetableisbasedon25,000simulationsofaveragedefaultratesover31years.`Existingmethod'referstothestandardapproachintheliteratureofusingtheaveragehistoricaldefaultrateforasingleratingandmaturityasanestimateoftheex-antedefaultprobability.`Newmethod'referstothemethodproposedinSection3.2wherethedefaultprobabilityestimateforasingleratingandmaturityisextractedusingtheBlack-Coxmodeland1,2,...,20yeardefaultratesforratingsAAA,AA,A,BBB,BB,BandC.`Ratio'isthethestandarddeviationofdefaultprobabilityestimatesusingthenewmethoddividedbythestandarddeviationofdefaultprobabilityestimatesusingtheexistingmethod.38 horizon(years)4567891011121314151617181920 AAA Newmethod0.510.360.250.180.120.070.040.01-0.02-0.04-0.06-0.07-0.09-0.10-0.11-0.12-0.13Existingmethod3.572.872.562.352.232.051.901.761.631.511.401.301.211.131.051.000.94Ratio14%12%10%8%5%4%2%0%-1%-3%-4%-6%-7%-9%-10%-12%-14% AA Newmethod0.500.350.240.170.110.070.030.00-0.02-0.04-0.06-0.08-0.09-0.10-0.11-0.12-0.13Existingmethod3.353.042.692.442.232.061.911.771.631.511.391.291.211.121.051.000.94Ratio15%11%9%7%5%3%2%0%-1%-3%-4%-6%-7%-9%-11%-12%-14% A Newmethod0.440.300.200.130.080.040.01-0.02-0.04-0.06-0.08-0.09-0.11-0.12-0.13-0.14-0.14Existingmethod2.892.562.362.172.001.871.731.601.491.381.281.191.111.040.980.920.87Ratio15%12%9%6%4%2%0%-1%-3%-5%-6%-8%-10%-11%-13%-15%-17% BBB Newmethod0.290.180.100.050.01-0.03-0.05-0.08-0.09-0.11-0.12-0.13-0.14-0.15-0.16-0.17-0.17Existingmethod1.751.631.541.481.401.341.281.211.151.091.020.950.900.840.790.740.69Ratio17%11%7%3%0%-2%-4%-6%-8%-10%-12%-14%-16%-18%-20%-23%-25% BB Newmethod0.080.00-0.05-0.08-0.11-0.13-0.14-0.16-0.17-0.18-0.19-0.19-0.20-0.20-0.21-0.21-0.22Existingmethod0.730.690.660.640.630.630.620.610.600.580.570.550.530.500.470.440.41Ratio10%0%-7%-13%-17%-20%-23%-26%-28%-30%-33%-35%-38%-41%-44%-48%-53% B Newmethod-0.08-0.12-0.15-0.17-0.19-0.20-0.21-0.21-0.22-0.22-0.23-0.23-0.24-0.24-0.24-0.24-0.24Existingmethod0.240.210.190.170.160.150.140.130.120.100.090.080.070.060.040.02-0.00Ratio-35%-60%-79%-99%-115%-132%-149%-170%-189%-215%-241%-278%-330%-404%-605%-1301%28766% C Newmethod-0.20-0.21-0.23-0.23-0.24-0.24-0.25-0.25-0.25-0.25-0.26-0.26-0.26-0.26-0.26-0.26-0.26Existingmethod-0.10-0.13-0.16-0.18-0.21-0.22-0.24-0.26-0.28-0.30-0.32-0.34-0.36-0.38-0.41-0.44-0.47Ratio195%159%142%129%116%109%102%95%89%85%80%76%72%68%64%59%56%Table2Skewnessoftheestimateddefaultprobability.Thistableshowstheskewnessoftheestimateddefaultprobability(inpercent)whentheestimateisbasedonaveragehistoricaldefaultratesover31years.Thetableisbasedon25,000simulationsofaveragedefaultratesover31years.`Existingmethod'referstothestandardapproachintheliteratureofusingtheaveragehistoricaldefaultrateforasingleratingandmaturityasanestimateoftheex-antedefaultprobability.`Newmethod'referstothemethodproposedinSection3.2wherethedefaultprobabilityestimateforasingleratingandmaturityisextractedusingtheBlack-Coxmodeland1,2,...,20yeardefaultratesforratingsAAA,AA,A,BBB,BB,BandC.`Ratio'isthetheskewnessofdefaultprobabilityestimatesusingthenewmethoddividedbytheskewnessofdefaultprobabilityestimatesusingtheexistingmethod.39 3-7-yearbondmaturity AAAAAABBBBBBCall Numberofbonds211093272891163614753Meannumberofbondsprmonth1.697.5422.3186.941.710.3758.4Meannumberofquotesprmonth1.68745.68105.7109.857.9913.314.497338.7Age2.054.735.195.894.373.072.505.08Coupon7.196.307.007.577.629.6111.727.36Amountoutstanding($mm)265329277321414300231322Time-to-maturity4.744.734.874.774.925.255.234.857-13-yearbondmaturity AAAAAABBBBBBCall Numberofbonds16942882761002611680Meannumberofbondsprmonth1.287.9820.918.15.040.930.354.4Meannumberofquotesprmonth1.91328.1967.370.5227.125.613.35204Age7.196.955.674.882.865.219.465.26Coupon7.217.297.307.847.769.239.957.64Amountoutstanding($mm)400308265294535222270317Time-to-maturity10.378.969.269.148.748.9410.149.1213-20-yearbondmaturity AAAAAABBBBBBCall Numberofbonds32181753091173Meannumberofbondsprmonth0.3072.068.286.262.090.4730.023319.5Meannumberofquotesprmonth3.732.0626.0417.945.4472.2430.4157.87Age14.632.407.745.649.6411.019.317.66Coupon8.298.048.178.258.417.289.228.19Amountoutstanding($mm)687208332218227157183297Time-to-maturity15.1916.7716.6115.8416.9517.2714.0716.33 Table3Bondsummarystatistics.Thesampleconsistsofnoncallablebondswith xedcouponsissuedbyindustrial rms.Thistableshowssummarystatisticsforthedataset.Bondyieldquotescovertheperiod1987Q2-2012Q2.`Numberofbonds'isthenumberofbondsthatappear(inaparticularratingandmaturityrange)atsomepointinthesampleperiod.`Meannumberofbondsprmonth'istheaveragenumberofbondsthatappearinamonth.`Meannumberofquotesprmonth'isthetotalnumberofquotesinthesampleperioddividedbythenumberofmonths.Foreachquotewecalculatethebond'stimesinceissuanceand`Age'istheaveragetimesinceissuanceacrossallquotes.`Coupon'istheaveragebondcouponacrossallquotes.`Amountoutstanding'istheaverageoutstandingamountofabondissueacrossallquotes.`Time-to-maturity'istheaveragetimeuntilthebondmaturesacrossallquotes.40 # rmsMean10th25thMedian75th90th Leverageratio AAA100.130.070.080.090.140.23AA530.140.070.100.130.170.23A1700.270.130.170.240.340.46BBB1970.370.170.250.360.480.58BB1000.460.180.290.470.610.73B400.520.210.320.480.730.83C60.760.600.700.800.920.96all3930.330.110.180.290.450.61Equityvolatility AAA100.190.150.170.180.200.24AA530.270.180.220.250.330.37A1700.300.200.240.300.360.41BBB1970.370.240.270.340.420.55BB1000.460.250.310.420.530.74B400.510.310.360.480.650.78C60.730.340.640.730.791.02all3930.350.210.250.320.400.54Assetvolatility AAA100.180.150.150.190.190.19AA530.230.190.220.230.250.28A1700.240.170.220.240.280.29BBB1970.250.170.190.240.280.36BB1000.270.170.230.250.280.40B400.280.160.220.250.390.42C60.260.170.180.220.260.42all3930.250.170.220.240.280.33Payoutratio AAA100.0360.0120.0170.0300.0490.071AA530.0410.0150.0270.0400.0530.066A1700.0470.0190.0300.0430.0580.079BBB1970.0500.0170.0270.0450.0650.098BB1000.0450.0200.0270.0400.0570.078B400.0460.0180.0290.0410.0610.077C60.0680.0370.0490.0560.0960.103all3930.0470.0180.0280.0430.0590.083Table4Firmsummarystatistics,industrial rmsinCompustatwithstraightbulletbondsoutstandingForeachbondyieldobservation,theleverageratio,equityvolatility,assetvolatility,andpayoutratioarecalculatedfortheissuing rmonthedayoftheobservation.Leverageratioistheratioofthebookvalueofdebttothemarketvalueofequityplusthebookvalueofdebt.Equityvolatilityistheannualizedvolatilityofdailyequityreturnsfromthelastthreeyears.Assetvolatilityistheunleveredequityvolatility,calculatedasexplainedinthetext.Payoutratioisyearlyinterestpaymentsplusdividendsplussharerepurchasesdividedby rmvalue.FirmvariablesarecomputedusingdatafromCRSPandCompustat.41 # rmsMean10th25thMedian75th90th Leverageratio AAA190.120.020.030.070.150.34AA950.150.040.070.110.180.29A3850.200.060.100.170.270.39BBB6500.280.080.150.250.370.51BB9980.390.130.230.370.540.70B10140.530.210.350.530.720.86C1620.720.380.580.770.890.95all20870.350.080.160.300.500.71Equityvolatility AAA190.260.170.210.260.300.35AA950.280.190.220.270.320.37A3850.310.210.250.300.360.42BBB6500.370.240.280.340.420.52BB9980.480.310.370.450.560.68B10140.650.380.480.610.770.94C1620.880.530.620.801.051.24all20870.450.240.300.400.550.72Assetvolatility AAA190.230.180.220.230.260.26AA950.240.200.210.240.260.29A3850.260.200.220.240.280.35BBB6500.280.200.220.270.320.38BB9980.320.210.250.300.380.44B10140.340.200.250.320.410.51C1620.330.180.250.310.400.50all20870.300.200.230.280.350.43Payoutratio AAA190.0270.0080.0140.0230.0350.050AA950.0260.0050.0110.0200.0340.053A3850.0320.0070.0140.0260.0430.067BBB6500.0370.0090.0160.0300.0490.078BB9980.0390.0090.0180.0330.0540.078B10140.0490.0100.0240.0440.0680.092C1620.0670.0220.0450.0680.0890.108all20870.0390.0080.0170.0320.0540.081Table5Firmsummarystatistics,industrial rmsinCompustatwitharating.Foreach rminCompustatforwhichthereisanS&PratinginCapitalIQ,theleverageratio,equityvolatility,assetvolatility,andpayoutratioarecalculatedonDecember31ineachyear1985-2012.Leverageratioistheratioofthebookvalueofdebttothemarketvalueofequityplusthebookvalueofdebt.Equityvolatilityistheannualizedvolatilityofdailyequityreturnsfromthelastthreeyears.Assetvolatilityistheunleveredequityvolatility,calculatedasexplainedinthetext.Payoutratioisyearlyinterestpaymentsplusdividendsplussharerepurchasesdividedby rmvalue.FirmvariablesarecomputedusingdatafromCRSPandCompustat.42 horizon(years)123456810121520 AAA Model0.010.040.100.160.220.280.410.540.670.871.18Actual0.000.010.030.090.170.250.520.871.161.381.7195%c.b.(NaN;NaN)(0.00;0.04)(0.00;0.09)(0.01;0.21)(0.04;0.38)(0.06;0.58)(0.16;1.17)(0.26;1.96)(0.34;2.69)(0.36;3.37)(0.37;4.52) AA Model0.010.080.190.310.450.590.871.161.451.892.58Actual0.070.220.350.540.831.171.832.503.344.525.8595%c.b.(0.03;0.13)(0.11;0.37)(0.17;0.62)(0.25;0.99)(0.39;1.54)(0.53;2.17)(0.79;3.48)(1.03;4.88)(1.34;6.59)(1.70;9.09)(2.0;12.3) A Model0.020.140.340.600.911.262.002.773.554.676.37Actual0.100.310.640.991.381.782.663.624.615.997.9395%c.b.(0.05;0.17)(0.17;0.51)(0.34;1.06)(0.51;1.69)(0.70;2.39)(0.88;3.16)(1.24;4.82)(1.62;6.69)(1.99;8.64)(2.4;11.5)(2.9;15.8) BBB Model0.300.951.782.703.644.576.378.049.5411.5314.24Actual0.290.861.542.293.103.905.467.118.7210.8713.7695%c.b.(0.18;0.44)(0.52;1.29)(0.92;2.38)(1.33;3.60)(1.75;4.95)(2.14;6.31)(2.87;9.01)(3.6;11.9)(4.3;14.8)(5.2;18.9)(6.2;24.5) BB Model2.235.618.7611.5413.9916.1519.7822.7225.1528.0931.74Actual1.353.275.467.759.9211.9715.7119.2722.4726.6532.0695%c.b.(0.95;1.83)(2.27;4.48)(3.73;7.58)(5.2;10.8)(6.6;14.0)(7.8;17.0)(10.1;22.6)(12.2;27.8)(14.2;32.6)(16.6;38.8)(19.4;47.0) B Model8.4316.4022.3927.0430.7833.8638.6542.2445.0548.3152.17Actual3.808.7113.7218.1622.0625.5431.4135.8939.5844.2249.1495%c.b.(2.93;4.78)(6.6;11.1)(10.4;17.6)(13.7;23.3)(16.5;28.4)(19.0;33.0)(23.3;40.6)(26.5;46.4)(29.0;51.3)(32.2;57.3)(35.3;63.9) C Model23.3236.1143.7949.0752.9956.0560.5763.8066.2469.0072.17Actual14.0223.8131.2136.8641.4044.7849.6353.8858.0263.7671.3495%c.b.(11.8;16.4)(19.9;28.1)(26.0;37.0)(30.6;43.8)(34.2;49.1)(36.9;53.2)(40.6;59.0)(44.0;64.0)(47.6;68.8)(52.8;74.8)(60.0;82.2)Table6AveragedefaultprobabilitiesintheBlack-Coxmodelandhistoricaldefaultrates.Wemerge rmdatafromCRSP/CompustatwithratingsfromStandard&Poorsandforevery rmandeveryyear1985-2012wecalculatea1-,2-,...,19-,20-yeardefaultprobabilityintheBlack-Coxmodel.`Model'showstheaveragedefaultprobabilities.`Actual'showsMoody'saveragehistoricaldefaultrates1920-2012.`95%c.b.'shows95%con dencebandsforthehistoricaldefaultratescalculatedfollowingtheapproachinSection3.1.`*'and`**'showwhenthemodel-implieddefaultprobabilityisoutsidethe95%and99%con dencebandrespectively.43 3-20y 3-7y7-13y13-20y InvActualspread 92 898787Modelspread 111(88;128) 107(82;127)107(87;121)88(76;96)Di erence 19(4;36) 18(8;38)20(0;34)1(11;9)Observations 294 294293244 SpecActualspread 544 560417461Modelspread 382(305;440) 376(289;443)392(336;429)314(279;337)Di erence 162(239;104) 184(271;117)25(81;12)147(182;124)Observations 289 276229141 AAAActualspread 16 4622Modelspread 3(2;4) 3(1;6)1(0;1)2(1;2)Di erence 13(14;12) 0(3;2)6(6;5)20(20;20)Observations 132 707091 AAActualspread 23 173426Modelspread 9(6;10) 2(1;3)14(11;17)19(15;22)Di erence 15(17;13) 15(16;14)20(23;17)7(11;4)Observations 289 27926493 AActualspread 61 506563Modelspread 85(67;99) 67(48;82)102(82;117)83(71;90)Di erence 24(6;38) 17(2;32)37(17;51)19(8;27)Observations 294 294293223 BBBActualspread 146 141141144Modelspread 169(134;195) 165(126;195)166(137;186)131(112;143)Di erence 23(12;49) 24(15;54)25(4;46)14(32;1)Observations 291 291257198 BBActualspread 377 370290398Modelspread 349(282;397) 320(247;374)337(285;372)255(223;277)Di erence 27(94;21) 51(124;4)46(5;82)142(175;121)Observations 259 240216114 BActualspread 675 723427445Modelspread 445(360;509) 480(376;560)441(376;485)323(294;342)Di erence 229(314;166) 243(347;163)15(51;59)122(150;103)Observations 243 20313482 CActualspread 1442 12111948661Modelspread 958(828;1041) 1097(920;1209)783(709;829)525(449;575)Di erence 484(615;401) 114(291;2)1165(1239;1119)136(212;86)Observations 96 65427 Table7Actualandmodelyieldspreads.Thistableshowsactualandmodel-impliedcorporatebondyieldspreads.Spreadsaregroupedaccordingtoremainingbondmaturityatthequotationdate.`Actualspread'istheaverageactualspreadtotheswaprate.`Modelspread'istheaverageBlack-Coxmodelspreadsofthebondsinagivenmaturity/ratingbucket.Theaveragespreadiscalculatedby rstcalculatingtheaveragespreadofbondsinagivenmonthandthencalculatingtheaverageofthesespreadsovermonths.`Di erence'isthedi erencebetweenthemodelspreadandtheactualspread.Inparenthesisare95%con dencebandscalculatedaccordingSection3.2;`*'impliessigni canceatthe5%leveland`**'atthe1%level.`Observations'isthenumberofmonthlyobservations.Thebondyieldspreadsarefromtheperiod1987-2012.44 3-20y 3-7y7-13y13-20y 20bpsActualspread 7 7810Modelspread 15(11;18) 14(9;18)18(14;22)19(16;22)Di erence 8(3;11) 7(2;11)10(6;13)9(5;12)Observations 279 279214138 20-40bpsActualspread 30 293031Modelspread 37(27;45) 30(20;39)54(41;63)36(30;41)Di erence 7(3;15) 1(9;10)23(11;32)5(1;9)Observations 279 272233165 40-70bpsActualspread 55 545556Modelspread 72(55;85) 69(49;85)84(66;98)56(47;62)Di erence 17(0;30) 15(5;31)29(11;42)0(9;7)Observations 284 277262191 70-100bpsActualspread 84 858484Modelspread 104(80;122) 115(81;142)118(94;135)87(74;96)Di erence 20(4;38) 30(4;57)34(10;50)3(10;12)Observations 281 264246170 100-150bpsActualspread 121 121120121Modelspread 136(105;160) 145(102;179)140(112;160)121(104;133)Di erence 15(16;39) 25(19;59)19(9;39)0(18;11)Observations 269 260254166 150-200bpsActualspread 172 172172171Modelspread 174(135;203) 167(120;204)188(153;213)144(123;158)Di erence 2(37;31) 5(52;32)15(20;40)27(48;13)Observations 252 222211120 200-300bpsActualspread 243 242243245Modelspread 257(202;297) 251(185;303)305(253;343)218(188;238)Di erence 14(40;54) 9(57;60)62(10;100)28(57;8)Observations 267 22222099 300-1000bpsActualspread 499 523456517Modelspread 507(414;573) 558(442;642)499(430;546)368(332;391)Di erence 8(85;74) 35(81;119)43(26;90)149(185;127)Observations 268 244221150 �1000bpsActualspread 1744 174617891166Modelspread 909(747;1026) 1004(806;1151)735(646;792)513(455;550)Di erence 835(997;718) 742(940;595)1055(1143;998)653(711;616)Observations 132 895915 Table8Actualandmodelyieldspreadssortedaccordingtoactualspread.Thistableshowsactualandmodel-impliedcorporatebondyieldspreads.Spreadsaregroupedaccordingtothesizeoftheactualspreadandtheremainingbondmaturityatthequotationdate.`Actualspread'istheaverageactualspreadtotheswaprate.`Modelspread'istheaverageBlack-Coxmodelspreadsofthebondsinagivenmaturity/ratingbucket.Theaveragespreadiscalculatedby rstcalculatingtheaveragespreadofbondsinagivenmonthandthencalculatingtheaverageofthesespreadsovermonths.`Di erence'isthedi erencebetweenthemodelspreadandtheactualspread.Inparenthesisare95%con dencebandscalculatedaccordingSection3.2;`*'impliessigni canceatthe5%leveland`**'atthe1%level.`Observations'isthenumberofmonthlyobservations.Thebondyieldspreadsarefromtheperiod1987-2012.45 PanelA:Regressioninlevels 3-20y 3-7y7-13y13-20y Inv 0:88(0:06) 0:81(0:08)0:82(0:09)0:79(0:13)R2 0.87 0.840.690.59 Spec 0:85(0:38) 0:82(0:41)0:80(0:19)1:55(0:20)R2 0.16 0.150.250.75 AAA 1:17(0:44) 1:40(0:14)1:63(0:22)R2 0.15 0.260.22 AA 1:07(0:58) 0:81(0:34)1:57(0:22)0:10(0:04)R2 0.22 0.030.620.08 A 0:65(0:08) 0:52(0:19)0:54(0:11)0:40(0:09)R2 0.70 0.470.570.41 BBB 0:82(0:07) 0:71(0:09)0:90(0:10)0:72(0:15)R2 0.88 0.810.740.62 BB 0:72(0:28) 0:70(0:31)0:64(0:14)1:66(0:28)R2 0.42 0.390.490.79 B 0:61(0:28) 0:64(0:30)0:31(0:19)1:14(0:23)R2 0.09 0.100.060.58 C 0:75(0:56) 0:34(0:56)R2 0.04 0.01PanelB:Regressioninchanges 3-20y 3-7y7-13y13-20y Inv 0:52(0:08) 0:47(0:08)0:37(0:09)0:62(0:10)R2 0.35 0.330.170.37 Spec 0:00(0:50) 0:42(0:49)0:76(0:22)1:30(0:24)R2 0.00 0.010.170.45 AAA 0:56(0:27) 0:54(0:49)0:57(0:41)R2 0.11 0.070.08 AA 0:25(0:11) 0:21(0:30)0:23(0:12)0:08(0:05)R2 0.06 0.010.060.11 A 0:37(0:07) 0:50(0:07)0:18(0:06)0:47(0:08)R2 0.27 0.440.100.36 BBB 0:46(0:08) 0:33(0:08)0:31(0:11)0:67(0:09)R2 0.32 0.200.110.54 BB 0:66(0:11) 0:61(0:12)0:68(0:10)1:33(0:30)R2 0.34 0.310.470.41 B 1:02(0:32) 0:92(0:33)0:18(0:26)1:39(0:37)R2 0.14 0.130.010.41 C 2:12(1:49) 2:37(2:28)R2 0.08 0.06 Table9Commonalityintimeseriesvariationofactualandmodel-impliedyieldspreads.Foragivenratingandmaturitygroupwecalculateamonthlyaveragespreadbycomputingtheaverageyieldspreadforbondswiththecorrespondingratingandmaturityobservedinthatmonth.Wedothisforbothmodel-impliedspreadsandactualspreads(totheswaprate)resultinginatimeseriesofmonthlyactualspreadss1;s2;:::;sTandimpliedspreadsfromtheBlack-Coxmodel^s1^s2;:::;^sTfortheperiod1987-2012.PanelAshowstheregressioncoecientintheregressionoftheactualspreadonthemodel-impliedspreadst= + ^st+t.Inparenthesisisthestandarderror,Newey-Westcorrectedwith12lagsand`*'impliesthat issigni cantlydi erentfromoneatthe5%leveland`**'atthe1%level.Insomemonthstheremaynotbeanyobservationsandiftherearelessthan100monthlyobservationswedonotreportregressioncoecients.PanelBshowsregressionresultsformonthlychanges,st+1st= + (^st+1^st)+t+1.InparenthesisistheOLSstandarderrorand`*'impliesthat issigni cantlydi erentfromoneatthe5%leveland`**'atthe1%leve46 correlationofpricingerrorwith R2 Ltetatt Investmentgrade 0.44 -0.45-0.140.12-0.34Speculativegrade 0.13 -0.02-0.03-0.020.00Table10Explainingindividualpricingerrors.The rstcolumnshowstheR2fromrunningaregressionofactualspreadsonindividualbondsontheimpliedspreadsfromtheBlack-Coxwhereweusealltransactionsinthedatasample,separatedintoinvestmentgradeandspeculativegrade.Thenextcolumnsshowthecorrelationbetweenthepricingerror,de nedasthedi erencebetweentheactualspreadandmodel-impliedspread,andvariablesthatmaycontributetopricingerrors.Ltistheleverageratioonthedayofthetransaction,etistheestimatedequityvolatilityonthedayofthetransaction,atistheissuing rm'sassetvolatilitywhenestimatedday-by-day,tisthepayoutrateonthedayofthetransaction.Thebondyieldspreadsarefromtheperiod1987-2012. (1)(2)(3)(4)(5) Inv 18(4;35)8(11;23)19(5;37)5(32;15)30(5;48) [28320][26855][26546][30998][31125]Spec 88(34;125)56(9;101)114(203;51)356(424;306)382(430;350) [7425][8940][9321][4865][4782]Table11Creditspreadresidualssortedonbondage.We rstsortallbondspreadobservationsforbondswithamaturitybetween3-20yearsintoquintilesbasedonthetimesincethebondwasissued.Forinvestmentgraderespectivelyspeculativegradebondswethencalculatetheaveragedi erencebetweenthemodel-impliedandactualspread.Thetableshowsthisaveragedi erenceinbasispoints.Inparenthesisare95%con dencebandscalculatedaccordingSection3.2;`*'impliessigni canceatthe5%leveland`**'atthe1%level.Thenumberofobservationsareinsquarebrackets.47 3-20y 3-7y7-13y13-20y InvActualspread 92 898787Modelspread 122(91;150) 120(85;154)116(90;140)93(78;106)Di erence 30(1;59) 31(4;65)30(3;53)7(9;20)Observations 294 294293244 SpecActualspread 544 560417461Modelspread 420(315;517) 420(301;535)417(344;476)329(284;364)Di erence 124(229;27) 140(259;24)0(73;59)132(177;97)Observations 289 276229141 AAAActualspread 16 4622Modelspread 4(2;6) 5(1;11)1(0;1)2(2;3)Di erence 12(14;10) 1(2;7)6(6;5)20(20;19)Observations 132 707091 AAActualspread 23 173426Modelspread 10(7;13) 2(1;4)16(11;21)21(16;26)Di erence 14(17;11) 14(15;13)18(23;13)5(10;0)Observations 289 27926493 AActualspread 61 506563Modelspread 94(69;117) 77(51;103)112(85;136)88(73;100)Di erence 33(8;56) 27(1;53)46(19;70)24(10;37)Observations 294 294293223 BBBActualspread 146 141141144Modelspread 186(139;230) 185(131;236)180(141;213)139(115;158)Di erence 40(7;83) 43(10;94)39(0;72)6(29;14)Observations 291 291257198 BBActualspread 377 370290398Modelspread 381(291;460) 356(256;448)360(292;416)270(228;303)Di erence 5(85;84) 15(114;78)70(2;126)128(170;95)Observations 259 240216114 BActualspread 675 723427445Modelspread 487(371;594) 532(390;670)471(385;540)336(299;364)Di erence 187(303;80) 190(333;53)44(42;113)109(146;81)Observations 243 20313482 CActualspread 1442 12111948661Modelspread 1014(846;1136) 1173(946;1339)814(720;881)559(460;635)Di erence 429(596;306) 39(265;128)1134(1228;1066)102(201;25)Observations 96 65427 Table12Actualandmodelyieldspreadswhenusingdefaultratesfrom1970-2012tocalibratethemodelInthemainanalysisthedefaultboundaryisestimatedusingMoody'sdefaultratesfrom1920-2012.ThistableshowsresultswhenthedefaultboundaryisestimatedusingMoody'sdefaultratesfrom1970-2012.Thetableshowsactualandmodel-impliedcorporatebondyieldspreads.Spreadsaregroupedaccordingtoremainingbondmaturityatthequotationdate.`Actualspread'istheaverageactualspreadtotheswaprate.`Modelspread'istheaverageBlack-Coxmodelspreadsofthebondsinagivenmaturity/ratingbucket.Theaveragespreadiscalculatedby rstcalculatingtheaveragespreadofbondsinagivenmonthandthencalculatingtheaverageofthesespreadsovermonths.`Di erence'isthedi erencebetweenthemodelspreadandtheactualspread.Inparenthesisare95%con dencebandscalculatedaccordingSection3.2;`*'impliessigni canceatthe5%leveland`**'atthe1%level.`Observations'isthenumberofmonthlyobservations.Thebondyieldspreadsarefromtheperiod1987-2012.48 Fig.1Actualandmodel-impliedBBB-AAAcorporatebondyieldspreadswhenusingexistingapproachintheliterature.This gureshowsactualandmodel-impliedBBB-AAAspreadsbasedondi erentestimatesofactualandmodel-impliedspreads.TheactualBBB-AAAyieldspreadsareestimatesfromDu ee(1998)[Duf],HuangandHuang(2012)[HH],Chen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009)[CDG]andCremers,Driessen,andMaenhout(2008)[CDM].TheblacksolidlinesshowspreadsintheBlack-CoxmodelbasedonMoody'sdefaultratesfromtheperiod1920-2002and1970-2001respectively.TheblackdashedlinesshowspreadsintheMertonmodelbasedonMoody'sdefaultratesfromtheperiod1920-2002and1970-2001respectively.49 Fig.2Distributionofestimated10-yearBBBdefaultprobabilitywhenusingdefaultratesmeasuredover31years.Theexistingapproachintheliteratureistouseanaveragehistoricaldefaultrateforaspeci cratingandmaturityasanestimateforthedefaultprobabilitywhentestingspreadpredictionsofstructuralmodels.OneexampleisChen,Collin-Dufresne,andGoldstein(2009)whousethe10-yearBBBdefaultrateof5.09%realizedovertheperiod1970-2001asanestimateforthe10-yearBBBdefaultprobability.Panel(a)showsthedistributionofthe10-yearBBBdefaultprobabilitywhenusinga31yearshistoryofthe10-yearBBBdefaultrateasanestimate.Besidesthisdistribution,Panel(b)alsoshowsthedistributionoftheestimated10-yearBBBdefaultprobabilitywhenextractedusingtheproposedapproachinSection3.2.Speci cally,thedefaultprobabilityisestimatedusingtheBlack-Coxmodeland1,2,...,20yeardefaultratesforratingsAAA,...,Caveragedover31years.50 05101520 0246default prob (percent) AAA Black-Cox model Historical 95pct confidence band 05101520 051015 AA 05101520 05101520 A 05101520 0102030 BBB 05101520 0204060 BB 05101520 020406080 B 05101520 050100 C Fig.3AveragedefaultprobabilitiesintheBlack-Coxmodelandhistoricaldefaultrates.Wemerge rmdatafromCRSP/CompustatwithratingsfromStandard&Poorsandforevery rmandeveryyear1985-2012wecalculatea1-,2-,...,19-,20-yeardefaultprobabilityintheBlack-Coxmodel.The gureshowstheaveragedefaultprobabilitiesalongwiththeaveragehistoricaldefaultrate1920-2012calculatedbyMoody's.95%con dencebandsforthehistoricaldefaultratesarecalculatedfollowingtheapproachinSection3.1.51 Jan90Jan92Jan94Jan96Jan98Jan00Jan02Jan04Jan06Jan08Jan10Jan12 0100200300400500600spread in basis points Actual spread Model spread 95% confidence band Fig.4Timeseriesvariationininvestmentgradespreads.Thisgraphshowsthetimeseriesofactualandmodel-impliedinvestmentgradecorporatebondspreads.Eachmonthalldailyyieldobservationsinbondswithaninvestmentgraderatingandwithamaturitybetween3-30yearsarecollectedandtheaverageactualspread(totheswaprate)andtheaveragemodel-impliedspreadintheBlack-Coxmodelarecomputed.Thegraphshowsthetimeseriesofmonthlyspreads.A95%con dencebandforthemodel-impliedspreadiscalculatedfollowingtheapproachinSection3.2.52 Fig.5Actualandmodel-impliedcorporatebondyieldspreadswhenusingdefaultratesfrom1970-2012and1920-2012.This gureshowsaverageactualandmodel-impliedcorporatebondyieldspreadsestimatedusingdefaultratesfromeither1970-2012or1920-2012.Model-impliedspreadsarecalculatedaccordingtoourproposedmethodwheremanydefaultratesacrossmaturityandratingareusedinthecalibrationofthemodelandthe gureshowsresultswhendefaultratesfromeither1970-2012or1920-2012areusedinthecalibration.Con dencebandstakeintoaccountuncertaintyaboutexantedefaultprobabilities.SpreadsarefromTables7and12.Actualbondyieldspreadsareaveragespreadstotheswapratefromnoncallablebondsissuedbyindustrial rmsandfromtheperiod1987-2012.53

Related Contents


Next Show more