/
Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der ArbeitInstitute for the Study of La Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der ArbeitInstitute for the Study of La

Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der ArbeitInstitute for the Study of La - PDF document

liane-varnes
liane-varnes . @liane-varnes
Follow
398 views
Uploaded On 2016-07-23

Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der ArbeitInstitute for the Study of La - PPT Presentation

How Do Voters Respond to InformationEvidence from a Randomized CampaignIZA DP No 7340Chad KendallTommaso NanniciniFrancesco Trebbi How Do Voters Respond to Information Evidence from a Randomized Ca ID: 416405

How Voters Respond

Share:

Link:

Embed:

Download Presentation from below link

Download Pdf The PPT/PDF document "Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbei..." is the property of its rightful owner. Permission is granted to download and print the materials on this web site for personal, non-commercial use only, and to display it on your personal computer provided you do not modify the materials and that you retain all copyright notices contained in the materials. By downloading content from our website, you accept the terms of this agreement.


Presentation Transcript

Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der ArbeitInstitute for the Study of Labor How Do Voters Respond to Information?Evidence from a Randomized CampaignIZA DP No. 7340Chad KendallTommaso NanniciniFrancesco Trebbi How Do Voters Respond to Information? Evidence from a Randomized CampaignChad KendallUniversity of British ColumbiaTommaso Nannicini IZA Discussion Paper No. April BSTRACTHow DoVoters Respond to Information?Evidence from a Randomized CampaigRational voters update their subjective beliefs about candidates’ attributes with the arrival of information, and subsequently base their votes on these beliefs. Information accrual is, however, endogenous to voters’ types and difficult to identify in observational studies. In a large scale randomized trial conducted during an actual mayoral campaign in Italy, we expose different areas of the polity to controlled informational treatments about the valence and ideology of the incumbent through verifiableinformative messages sent by the incumbent reelection campaign. Our treatments affect both actual vote shares at the precinct level and vote declarations at the individual level. We explicitly investigate the process of belief updating by comparing the elicited priors and posteriors of voters, finding heterogeneous responses to information. Based on the elicited beliefs, we are able to structurally assess the relative weights voters place upon a candidate’s valence and ideology. We find that both valence and ideological messages affect the first and second moments of the belief distribution, but only campaigning on valence brings more votes to the incumbent. With respect to ideology, crosslearning occurs, as voters who receive information about the incumbent also update their beliefs about the opponent. Finally, we illustrate how to perform counterfactual campaigns based upon the structural model.JEL Classification:D72, D83Keywordsvoting, information, beliefs elicitation, randomized controlled trialCorresponding author:Tommaso NanniciniDepartment of EconomicsBocconi UniversityVia Roentgen 120136 MilanItalymail: tommaso.nannicini@unibocconi.it We would like to thank Matilde Bombardini, David Green, Andrea Mattozzi, Jim Snyder, and seminar participants at Alicante, Bank of Italy, Bocconi, Carlo Alberto Turin, EIEF Rome, Harvard, LSE, MILLS workshop, MIT, Petralia workshop, Rotterdam, SciencesPo Paris, UBC, UK Leuven, and Warwick for useful comments. Federico Cilauro, Francesco Maria Esposito, Jonathan Graves, Nicola Pierri, and Teresa Talò provided outstanding research assistance. A large number of people were instrumental in implementing our experimental design: the mayor of Arezzo, Giuseppe Fanfani, and his 2011 reelection campaign, in particular Claudio Repek, were extremely cooperative throughout the entire process; Massimo Di Filippo, Fabrizio Monaci, and the team of “IPR Feedback” showed tremendous expertise in conducting the surveys. Nannicini acknowledges financial support from the European Research Council (under grant No. 230088). Remaining errors are ours and follow a random walk. alsoshowthat,althoughonlyvalencetreatmentsweree ectiveinchangingvotes,ourinformationaltreatmentsalongboththevalenceandideologicaldimensionhadlargee ectsonvoters'beliefs,mov-ingboth rstandsecondmomentsofthebeliefdistributionsforthetwomaincandidates.Indeed,campaigninformationa ectednotonlyvoters'beliefsaboutthecandidateoriginatingthemessage,butalsotheirbeliefsabouttheopponent.Intuitively,inBayesiansignalinggames,receivingnomessageisvaluableinformationandourevidenceoncross-learningappearsfullyconsistentwithupdatinginthecontextofaBayesianpoliticalsignalinggame.Thefullcharacterizationoftheindividualbeliefdistributionsweproposeisthecombinationofacarefuldesignofoursurveysandstructuralestimationofarandomutilityvotingmodel.Thelattercomponentofourmethodologydeliverspreciseestimatesofutilityweightsinvoters'preferencesforacandidate'svalenceandideology.Wereportautilityweightonvalenceroughlyequaltothatonideologicallossesawayfromavoter'sblisspoint.Interestingly,wealsoshowthatthepreferenceweightsareheterogeneousinthepopulationanddependonthepoliticalstanceofthevoter,withvotersontherightplacinglessemphasisonthevalencedimension.Finally,weshowthattheideologicallossfunctionawayfromthevoter'sblisspointisconcaveindistance,notconvex(e.g.,quadraticlosses)ascommonlyassumedintheliterature.TherandomutilitymodelweusefollowsthemethodoutlinedinthetheoreticalpaperofRamalhoandSmith(2012)toaccountfornon-randomnessinvoters'willingnesstodisclosetheirvotes.Whilenon-responseinsurveydataisoftenassumedtoberandom,wedemonstratetheimportanceofaccountingforitsendogeneityandsuggestthatthismethodshouldbemoreoftenutilizedinempiricalstudiesinwhichsurveyresponsesarereliedupon.Weconcludeouranalysisbysimulatingcounterfactualelectoralcampaignstoassessthee ectsofspeci cblanketortargetedelectoralcampaignsonvoteoutcomes.We ndablanketcampaignofvalencemessagestobethemostvaluableinpersuadingvoters,whichisconsistentwithvoterslackingpriorinformationonthequalityofcandidates.Thispaperisrelatedtoseveralstrandsoftheliterature.Thee ectivenessofelectoralcampaignsinmaturedemocraciesisthesubjectofalargeliterature,includingAnsolabehereetal.(1994),AnsolabehereandIyengar(1995),GerberandGreen(2000),GreenandGerber(2004),Gerber,Green,andShachar(2003),Nickerson(2008),andDewan,Humphreys,andRubenson(2010).Typicallythefocusofthesepapersiseitheronself-declaredoutcomesforvotechoicesoronactualoutcomesforturnout.Methodologically,thesepapersrelyoneithersmall-scaleexperimentsforpartisanadsoronrandomizednon-partisancampaignsforturnout.Ourpapercomplementsthisliteraturebyfocusingonactualelectoraloutcomesinalargescale eldexperiment.Wemustclarify2 thatourpaperisnotthe rstinstanceofalargescalerandomizedpartisancampaign.Gerberetal.(2011)lookatrandomizationoverintensityofTVads(withnocontroloverthemessagecontent)onself-declaredchoicesduringthe2006RepublicanprimaryfortheTexasgubernatorialelection.They ndlarge,butshort-lived,e ectsofsuchTVads,inconsistentwithBayesianupdating.Unliketheirapproach,werandomizethecontentofpartisanadsandalsoevaluatetheirimpactonactualvoteshares.Ourpaperalsocomplementsthisliteraturefromamethodologicalstandpointbyaugmentingthereducedformapproachwithstructuralestimation.Albeitinthecontextoflessmaturedemocracies,theliteratureindevelopmenteconomicshasalsoexperimentedwithinformationalcampaigning.RelevantcontributionsincludeWantchekon(2003)andFujiwaraandWantchekon(2013),exploringpoliticalclientelisminBenin,Vicente(2013),andBanerjee,Green,andPande(2012).Banerjeeetal.(2011)focusonnon-partisaninformationalcampaignsinIndiaandshowthatinformationaboutthequali cationsofcandidatesmattersforturnout,voteshares,andtheincidenceofvotebuying.Thispaperisrelatedtoavastliteratureoncandidate'svalence,initiatedbyStokes(1963)andincludingEnelowandHinich(1982),AnsolabehereandSnyder(2000),Groseclose(2001),Scho eld(2003),AragonesandPalfrey(2002)amongothers.Morerecently,AshworthandBuenodeMesquita(2009),KartikandMcAfee(2007),andBernhardt,Camara,andSquintani(2011)provideinter-estingtheoreticalstudiesofstrategicelectoralcompetitionwithcandidatesdi erentiatedalongboth(ideological)policyplatformandvalencedimensions.GalassoandNannicini(2011)studytheinterplaybetweencandidates'valenceandthecontestabilityofelectoraldistricts.Finally,thispapercontributestothegrowingliteraturefocusedontheelicitationandquan-ti cationofsubjectivebeliefs.ElicitationofpriorsisthesubjectofDominitzandManski(1996),Manski(2004),Blass,Lach,andManski(2010),GillandWalker(2005),andDu yandTavits(2008)amongothers.Tothesecontributions,whichmostlyfocusontheelicitationofexpectationsofeconomicoutcomes,ourworkprovidesausefuladditioninthecontextoftheelicitationofmul-tivariatebeliefs.Inparticular,weshowhowtodecoupleinformationaboutmarginalbeliefsandtheirdependenceusingacopulafunctionapproach.Webelievethisapproachmaybeofuseoutsidethepolitico-economicapplicationinourstudy.Therestofthepaperisorganizedasfollows.Section2presentstheempiricalmodel.Section3describestheexperimentalsetting.Section4discussesthereducedformresultsonvotechoices.Section5focusesonthestructuralestimatesofthemodelandSection6ontheexperimentale ectsonvoters'beliefs.Section7presentsourcounterfactualsanddiscussestheimplicationsoftheheterogeneousresponsetoinformationonthepartofvoters.Section8concludes.3 2EmpiricalModel2.1VotersandCandidatesConsideranelectoralracebetweentwocandidates,A,theincumbent,andB,thechallenger.LetthesetofvotersbeN,withjNj=N.Avoteriischaracterizedbyanidealpolicypointdistributedovera niteanddiscretepolicyspace,,whichiscommonacrossallvoters,withpoliciesP2.Thediscretenessassumptionismeanttocaptureanempiricalfeatureofthesurveydataemployedinthesubsequentanalysis.Votersareheterogeneous,withblisspointsq2,andreceivedisutilityfromapolicychoiceawayfromtheirblisspoint.TheyalsoreceiveutilityfromthelevelofvalenceoftheelectedcandidateV2,wherethesetis niteanddiscrete.Whenpolicypisimplementedbycandidatejofvalencev,theutilityforvoterioftypeqisassumedtobe:U(v;p;q)= v�u(q�p)�u(q�p)v+"i;jwheretheutilityfunctionincludesadeterministicportionandacandidate-speci crandomutilitycomponent"i;j,independentofVandP.Theparameter indicatestherelativepreferenceweightofvalenceversusthepolicystance.Weassumeu(0)=0,u0(x)0forx�0,andu0(x)0forx0.Forexample,aquadraticlossawayfromvoteri'sblisspoint,(qi�p)2, tsthissetofassumptions.1However,weassumethemoregeneralformu(x)=jxjwith0.Thepolicystanceofthepolitician,p;a ectsvotersheterogeneouslydependingupontheirownidealposition,q,butcandidatesofhigherqualityvarefavoredbyallvoters.Wealsoallowforinteractionsbetweenvalenceandpolicypositionsthataregovernedby.Therandomutilitycomponent"i;jofvoteri'spreferencesforcandidatejcapturesthepersonalappealofjtoi.ItisnotimportantforourpurposestospecifywhetherthetwocandidatesAandBimplementtheirrespectiveidealpolicypositionPonceinoce(seeAnsolabehere,Snyder,andStewart,2001;Lee,Moretti,andButler,2004)orstrategicallycatertheirpolicytovoters(e.g.,asinastandardDownsiansetting).Weareinterestedinthevoters'utilitiesatthetimetheyplacetheirvote,whichonlydependupontheirbeliefsabouteachcandidate'sposition,andnotonhowthepolicypositioncameaboutorwhetherornotitisactuallyimplemented.Ingeneral,ourapproachisrobusttothedetailsoftheelectoralcompetitionstructure.Allvotersparticipateintheelection(votingiscompulsoryinourempiricalsetting).VoteriisassumedtohaveajointpriordistributionfunctionoverVandP,fi;jV;P(v;p),forj=A;B,evaluatedatpoint(v;p)andde nedoverthesupport.WedonotprecludeVfrombeingpotentiallycorrelatedwithPandweallowpriorstodi erbaseduponi'scharacteristicsoridealpointq. 1Quadraticlossfunctionsarestandardintheliterature(e.g.,seeAnsolabehereandSnyder,2000).4 Ourexperimentaltreatmentsinducearandomizedchangeintheinformationsetsofvoters,whichwedescribeindetailinSection3.Thediscretenessoftheexperimentalstrategyinducesa nitesetofinformationaltypesofvoters.Type1:ReceivingamessageaboutV;butnotP;ofA:Type2:ReceivingamessageaboutP;butnotofV;ofA:Type3:ReceivingamessageaboutbothVandPofA:Type4:ReceivingnomessageaboutVorPofA:Forsimplicity,a\message"indicateshaving(randomly)receivedacampaigninformationtreat-ment,H2f1;:::;4g.LetusindicateasT(h)thesetofvoterstreatedwithinformationtypeH=handletfi;AV;P(v;pjH=h)indicatesthesubjectiveposteriorprobabilitythatvoteri,treatedbymessageh,assignstotheeventthatcandidateAhasvalenceV=vandpositionP=p.Theprocessofupdatingbeliefstypicallyre ectsthecharacteristicsofthegameplayedbetweenvotersandpoliticalcandidates(e.g.,asignalinggame).Ourapproachallowstoleavethenatureofsuchstrategicinteractionunspeci ed.TheexpectedutilityfromtheelectionofAforvoteri,treatedbyhandwithidealpointq,is:EUiA(h;qi)=XpXvfi;AV;P(v;pjH=h)U(v;p;qi)+"i;A.If,instead,Biselected,theexpectedutilityforvoteroftype(h;qi)is:EUiB(h;qi)=XpXvfi;BV;P(v;pjH=h)U(v;p;qi)+"i;B.Theprobabilitythatioftype(h;q)supportscandidateAisgivenby:PrEUiA(h;qi)EUiB(h;qi).(1)GiventheprobabilitythatavotersupportscandidateA,wecanconsiderastandard,conditionallogitmodel,assuming"ijtobei.i.d.acrossvotersanddistributedwithaTypeIextreme-valuedistributionwithcumulativedistributionfunctionF("ij)=exp(�e�"ij).Providedinformationonthechoiceofitovoteforj,Yi=j,weobtaintheloglikelihood:lnL()=NXi=1XjdijlnPr(Yi=j)=NXi=1XjdijlneEUij(h;qi) PleEUil(h;qi)wheredijis1ifivotesforj,and0otherwise.Notethatthevectorofparametersofinterest,,includesbothpreferenceparameters[ ;;]andtheparametersofthejointbeliefsfi;jV;P(:),whichwede neinthefollowingsubsection.5 Onepotentialproblemwiththestandardlogitmodelinasettingemployingvotedeclarationsasopposedtoactualvotesisthatvoters,whensurveyed,mayprefernottodisclosetheirvote.Ifthesampleofvoterswhodonotdisclosetheirvoteiscompletelyrandom,onecanapplythelogitmodeltothesubsampleofresponders.Thisistheapproachtypicallyfollowedintheliterature,oftenwithoutdiagnosticsinsupportofthecrucial\missingcompletelyatrandom"assumption,requiredforanunbiasedestimate.WeprovideevidenceinSection5thatindicatesthatthesubsampleofvotersthatchoosenottodisclosetheirvotesispredictable,soestimationofthestandardlogitmodelwouldleadtobiasedestimatesinoursetting.Wethereforeapplyanovelchoice-basedapproachsuggestedbyRamalhoandSmith(2012)thatallowsfornon-randomnon-responseunderweakassumptions.Themodelassumesthat,conditionalonthevoter'sactualvote,theprobabilitywithwhichavoterchoosestorespondtothesurveyisconstant,butthatthisprobabilitycandependontheirvote.Underthisassumption,wecande netheloglikelihoodas:lnL()=NXi=10@oiXjdijln jeEUij(h;qi) PleEUil(h;qi)+(1�oi)ln0@1�Xj jeEUij(h;qi) PleEUil(h;qi)1A1Awhereoiis1ifidisclosesthevote,and0otherwise.Theadditional jparametersaretheprobabil-itieswithwhichavoterdisclosesthevoteforj.The rsttermoftheloglikelihoodistheprobabilitythatavotervotesforjanddisclosesthevote.Thesecondtermre ectstheprobabilitythatthevotervotesforoneofthecandidates,butchoosesnottodisclosethevote.Notethatwhen j=1forallj,suchthatthevoteisalwaysobserved,weobtainthestandardlogitmodelasaspecialcase.OurresultsinSection5reject j=1forallj,meaningthatwearejusti edinaccountingforthepossibilityofnon-randomnon-response.2.2Voters'SubjectiveUpdatingHere,wespecifytheprocessbywhichvoters'subjectivebeliefsareupdatedinthepresenceofcampaignadvertising.Forillustrativepurposes,considerthefollowingtimeline. 6 Our rstassumptionisthatvotersconsiderthecampaigninformationtobetruthful.SucientfreedomofthepressintheItalianelectoralcontextguaranteesthatsuchanassumptionmaybevalidinthecaseoffactualadvertising,asweemployinourexperimentalsetup.Allmessagesarefactualandcanbeindependentlyvalidated.Secondly,weassumerationalBayesianvoters.2Werefrainfromimposingdistributionalas-sumptionsonpriors,posteriors,andonthedistributionofsignals.Instead,weadopttheoptionofelicitingsubjectivepriorsandposteriorsfromspeci callydesignedsurveys.Thisisanimportantstepfortwomainreasons.First,elicitationallowsustoassessquantitativelyhowthemessagingstrategyweemployedexperimentallyoperatesinthe eld.Indeed,votersarenotawareoftheran-domizationprocessandupdatetheirbeliefs\asif"themessagesweredirectlysentbythecandidate.Thisisnotanassumption,butpartoftheexperimentaldesign.UndertheassumptionofBayesianvoters,beliefupdatingaboutcandidateAimplies:fi;AV;P(v;pjH=h)=Pri;A(H=hjV=v;P=p) Pri;A(H=h)fi;AV;P(v;p)forh=1;2;3,wherethesubjectiveupdatingtermPri;A(H=hjV=v;P=p) Pri;A(H=h)canberecovereddirectlyfromthedataafterelicitationoffi;AV;P(v;pjH=h)andfi;AV;P(v;p).Second,ourapproachallowsforgeneralstrategicelectoralcommunicationbetweencandidatesandvotersinthebackground.WearenotrequiredtomodelorrestrictthevotinggameplayedamongN,A,andB.AnystrategicsignalingiscapturedbytheupdatingtermPri;A(H=hjV=v;P=p) Pri;A(H=h),whichweestimate,notmodel.3Bayesianupdatingincasethevoterreceivesnomessagefromthecandidaterequiresfurtherdiscussion.ConsiderthecaseofafullyrationalBayesianvoterthatreceivesnocampaignadvertisingfromacandidate,butknowsthatsuchactionwasavailable.Insuchacase,asChappell(1994)states,\absenceofamessageprovidesinformationwhichshouldbeusedinBayesianupdating"withtheresultthatsubjectiveposteriorsprobabilitiesaredi erentfrompriorsevenabsentanymessagehavingreachedthevoter.InthecaseofposteriorsaboutcandidateB,forinstance,thisrequiresthatvoteriupdatespriorsbasedonabsenceofanHmessagefromB.Formally:fi;BV;P(v;pjH=h)6=fi;BV;P(v;p)forh=1;2;3,(2)whichisjusti edfromvoterihavingobservedatleastoneextracampaignmessagefromAwithoutanycorrespondingcounter-messagefromB. 2Notethat,whileweneedvoterstoberationalandvotesincerely,theassumptionofBayesianupdatingissimplyconvenientfortheexposition,asourempiricalframeworkallowsustoidentifybeliefupdatinginmoregeneralterms.3Adynamicrepeatedelectionmodelwithbothideologicalandvalenceconsiderationsthatwould tourproblemis,forinstance,proposedinBernhardt,Camara,andSquintani(2011).7 Thedegreeofrationalityembeddedincondition(2)cannotbeextended,however,totheexper-imentalcontrolgroupH=4,whichdoesnotreceiveanytypeofinformationaltreatmentbyeitherAorBandhencehasnopossibilityofknowingthatsuchspeci cmessageswouldbeavailablebutwerenotemployed.ThefundamentalassumptionofourexperimentaldesignmirrorsaStableUnitTreatmentValueAssumption(SUTVA,seeCox,1958;Rubin,1978),asitrequiresthepotentialoutcomeofacontrolunittobeuna ectedbythetreatmentassignmentoftheotherunits.Absentcommonshocks,weshouldassumeforH=4thattheposteriordistributionisidenticaltothepriordistribution,thatis,foreveryi2T(4),fi;jV;P(v;pjH=4)=fi;jV;P(v;p)forj=A;B.Moregenerally,weconsideraprocessofBayesianupdatingwhichaccommodatescommonshocksacrossvoters,underthe(testable)assumptionthatthesubjectiveprobabilitiesonsuchshocksareidenticalacrossalli2NandindependentofH.Consider,forinstance,thecaseofposteriorselicitedafteracommoninformationalshock,W,whichcanbethoughtofasthegeneralcampaigncarriedoutbythecandidatesbesidestheinformationalmessagesfromAthatwerandomizeatthemargin.Withrespecttocandidatej,voteriwillbecharacterizedbythefollowingposteriors.Assumption1(SUTVA):fi;jV;P(v;pjH=h;W)=Pri;j(H=hjV=v;P=p) Pri;j(H=h)Prj(WjV=v;P=p) Prj(W)fi;jV;P(v;p)forh=1;2;3;j=A;Bandfi;jV;P(v;pjH=4;W)=Prj(WjV=v;P=p) Prj(W)fi;jV;P(v;p)forj=A;B.ThecredibilityofAssumption1cruciallyrestsontheexperimentaldesigndescribedinSection3andisempiricallyvalidatedinSection4.Finally,theelicitationofmultivariatebeliefs,evenonexpertsubjects,isnotanobviousexercise(KadaneandWolfson,1998;Garthwaiteetal.,2005)andistheobjectofavastliteratureborderingstatisticsandpsychology(datingatleastasbackasSavage,1971).Weoutlineourapproachnext.2.3ElicitationofMultivariateBeliefsElicitationofbeliefsandpriorsisincreasinglycommonineconomicsandpoliticalscience,andisstandardinpsychologyandstatistics.4Wedescribeatransparentprotocolofelicitationwedesignedtoberobusttothebehavioralandtechnologicalconstraintsweface.Speci cally,wesampledalargenumberofvotersandneedtoelicitmultivariatebeliefsfromeach. 4Forrecentexamplesineconomics,seeDominitzandManski(1996);Manski(2004);Blassetal.(2010);andZafar(2009).SeeGillandWalker(2005)andDu yandTavits(2008)forapplicationsinpoliticalscience.8 Foreachmaincandidatej=A;Bandeachvoteri,jointvalenceandideologysubjectivepriorsfi;jV;P(v;p)andposteriorsfi;jV;P(v;pjH=h)arede nedover.Intheremainderofthissubsection,letusfocusforbrevityontheelicitationofsubjectivepriors,withtheunderstandingthatthesameprocessappliestoposteriors.Intheempiricalanalysiswewill xthecardinalityofbothandtosmallinteger gures,basedonMiller(1956),andalargebodyofcognitivepsychologysuggestingthatindividualscanbequitepreciseinevaluatingchoicesonrelativelycoarseunidimensionalsupports,butdisplayhardlyanyprecisionon nersupports.Speci cally,forreasonsexplainedbelow,weassumethecardinalityoftobeequalto5andthecardinalityoftobeequalto10.Itisevident,however,thatevenforjj=5andjj=10,\bruteforce"elicitationforbothcandidateswouldrequireeachrespondertoanswer5102=100di erentquestionsonthesubjectivelikelihoodofeachspeci c(v;p)realization,ane ortwhichwouldlikelyfrustratepoliticalexperts,letaloneregularvoters.Garthwaite,Kadane,andO'Hagan(2005)presentaninsightfuldiscussiononthedicultyofelicitationformultivariatepriors.Tothisissue,thereaderversedinelicitationmayaddtheproblemofe ectivelytrainingtelephoneinterviewersintheconsistentelicitationofjointprobabilities.5Therefore,wefollowanalternativeroute.2.3.1MarginalBeliefDistributionsWe rstfocusoninformationmoreeasilyelicitablefromvoters:theunivariatemarginalsfi;jV(v)andfi;jP(p).Eveninthiscase,fullelicitationofmarginalswouldrequirealargesetof(jj+jj)2=30questions.Westreamlinetheprocessinordertomaintainfeasibilitywithoutexcessivesacri ceofaccuracy.Westartbyimposingasimpleregularityassumptiononthedistributionofbeliefs.Assumption2:Subjectivebeliefdistributionsareunimodal.Althoughrestrictive,thisassumptionmakestheinterpretationoftheelicitedprobabilitiesmoredirect.Allofourremainingdistributionalassumptionscanbeillustratedusingthequestionsinoursurveysbywayofexample.WefocusonlyonAforbrevityandconsider rsthisideologicalpositionP.Weenquireaboutthecentraltendencyofthemarginalprioronideologyasfollows.Q1:Howwouldyoumostlikelyde necandidateA'spoliticalposition?Left(1);Center-Left(2);Center(3);Center-Right(4);Right(5);Don'tKnow(�999). 5Whiletheuseoftelephoneinterviewsisnotgenerallynecessary,inourcontextitiswasrequiredtoensuretimelyelicitationofalargesampleofthevotingpopulationascloseaspossibletoelectionday.9 Areasonableinterpretationoftheanswer,withminimalconfusionfortherespondent,isthatthemodeiselicited.Inparticular,weallowthemode,^p;tobeonlyoneofthese vecategories.Assumption3:=f1;:::;5g:Ananswerof\Don'tKnow/Don'tKnowA"implies atpriors,orfi;AP(p)=1=jj=0:2foreveryp.Ourchoiceofthesetfollowstheestablishedresultincognitivepsychologythatindividualsarewellversedinchoicesoverdiscretesetsoflimiteddimensionality(jj10),butthatthiscapacitydeterioratessharplywhenthenumberofoptionsrisesabovesmallintegers(Miller,1956).Suchanassumption,however,hascosts,asemphasizedinManskiandMolinari(2010).Conditionalonnon- atpriors,wefurtherenquireaboutthedispersionaroundthemode.6Q2:HowlargeisyourmarginofuncertaintyaroundcandidateA'spoliticalposition?Certain(1);Ratheruncertain,leaningleft(2);Veryuncertain,leaningleft(3);Ratheruncertain,leaningright(4);Veryuncertain,leaningright(5).Weindicatethelevelofincreasingtightnessofthepriorswiths2=f1;:::;4g,wheres=1ismaximaldispersion,i.e.,thecaseof atpriors;s=2indicatessubstantialuncertainty(answers3or5toQ2);s=3indicatesintermediateuncertainty(answers2or4toQ2);ands=4ismaximaltightness,whichcoincideswithadegeneratepriorspikingat^p(answer1toQ2).Q2alsoelicitsinformationabouttheskewofthebeliefs.Whilewedonotallowexplicitlyforananswerofsymmetricdispersionfors=2;3,nottooverloadtheresponder,theestimationbelowallowsforsymmetricbeliefdistributions.7Letusindicatewithz2f�1;1ganegative(i.e.,totheleft/lowervalues)orpositive(i.e.,totheright/highervalues)asymmetryinQ2.Letusde nethemodalprobabilitymasswithP=fi;AP(p=^p).Intuitively,weassumetheprobabilitymassatthemodefi;AP(p=^p)islowerthehigherthelevelofuncertainty.WeallowPtovarywithsandestimateP;s,fromthedatafors=2;3,imposingthebounds:Assumption4:1=jjP;2P;31:Wefurtherassumetheo -modemass,1�P;s,tobeallocatedasymmetricallyaroundthemodedependingontheindicatedasymmetry,z.Weassumetheo -modemassdecaysproportionally 6Interviewersweretrainedduringpilotinterviewstoexplaintovotersthatthisquestionentaileduncertaintyaboutsubjectiveevaluationsonthecandidates,andshouldnotbeinterpretedasaright-or-wrongquestion.7Inoursurveys,weactuallyincludedapossibleanswer\uncertain"toassesstheshareofrespondentsindicatingsymmetricdispersionaroundthemode.Theshareofrespondentsinthatcategorywassolowforideology(andactuallynoneforvalence)thatweomititfromexposition.10 tothedistancejp�^pjfromthemodeataconstantrate,asdictatedbyafunctiong(x1;x2):f1;:::;jj�1g[0;1]![0;1]withgx1(x1;x2)0andgx2(x1;x2)0.Insynthesis,weimpose:Assumption4':fi;AP(p6=^p)=8:1=jjg(P;s;z(p�^p))0fors=1fors=2;3fors=4:Concerningg(:),weallocate P(1�P;s)massinthedirectionoftheasymmetryimposingthat P2[1=2;1],andallocate(1� P)(1�P;s)intheoppositedirection,assumingalineardecayoftheo -modemassinbothdirections.Thisspeci cationofgallowsforavery exible,butparametricallyparsimoniousmarginaldistribution.ConcerningthevalencedimensionV,weagainenquireaboutthemodalbelief.Q3:Settingasidehis/herpoliticalposition,howwouldyoumostlikelygradecandidateA?From1(minimumcompetence)to10(maximumcompetence)orDon'tKnow(�999).Thesetisthenassumedtobeasfollows:Assumption5:=f1;:::;10g.ThisparticularformatofQ3wasdrivenbythefamiliarityofItalianvoterswithprimaryandsecondaryeducationgradescoringrules,with10indicatingthebestpossiblemarkinaschoolassignmentandfailinggradesbeingbelow6.ThedispersionaroundthevalencemodeandtheskewnessofvalencebeliefsaremodeledsimilarlytoAssumptions4and4'withreplacingintheconstructionoffi;AV(v).Weomittheirdescriptionforbrevity.Forillustrativepurposes,Figure1providesanexampleofthemodeledpriorbeliefsaboutthevalenceofAforoneparticularvoter.Thedistributioninthe gureisbaseduponthevoter'sreportedmode(^p=7)anduncertainty(s=2)andtheestimatesweobtainfortheparametersgoverningthedistribution.Finally,wemustemphasizethatweonlyelicitthebeliefsaboutvalenceandideologyfortheincumbentcandidate,A,andhismainchallenger,B,duetotheinfeasibilityofelicitingbeliefsaboutallminor,third-partycandidatesparticipatingintheelection.InourestimationinSection5,weassumethatthebeliefsofallnon-incumbentcandidatesarethesameasthoseelicitedforthemainchallenger,B.Whilethisisastarkassumption,wejustifyitbythefactthatthemainnon-incumbentcandidateswereideologicallysimilarandtheirqualitieswererelativelyunknown( atbeliefsalongthevalencedimensionarequitecommonfornon-incumbentcandidates).8 8Themainthird-partychallengerwasalsoaright-wingcandidate,likeB,butwassidelinedbytheirpartyduetopendinglegallitigationrelatedtohispreviousstintinoce.SeeSection3formoreinstitutionaldetails.11 2.3.2JointBeliefDistributions:ACopula-BasedApproachHavingderivedtheunivariatemarginals,wenowderivethejointdistributionsforallvoters.Givenanytwo(univariate)marginals,itispossibletoconstructajoint(bivariate)distributioninin niteways.Copulas,introducedbySklar(1959),areusefuldevicesforprovidingarepresentationofamultivariatedistributionfunctionintermsofitsunivariatemarginaldistributions.Droppingthesuperscripts,givencumulativemarginals,FV(v)=Pr(Vv)andFP(p)=Pr(Pp),acopulafunctionCsatis esFV;P(v;p)=C(FV(v);FP(p))whereFV;P(v;p)=Pr(Vv;Pp)isthejointcumulativedistributionfunction.Cisuniqueforcontinuousdensities.Fordis-cretedensities,asinoursetting,typicallythesamejointdistributioncanberepresentedbydi erentcopulas,butaspeci ccopulauniquelyidenti esajointdistribution.Themarginaldistributionscarryalloftheinformationrelatedtothescalingandshapeofthejointdistributionfunction,whilethecopulafunctionincorporatestheinformationconcerningthedependencerelationshipamongtherandomvariables.Forparsimony,wewillfocusoncopulafamiliescharacterizedbyonedepen-denceparameter.Notice,however,thatthedependenceparameterdoesnotcoincidewithalinearcorrelationparameter;nonlineardependenceisaccommodatedaswell.Weinvestigatethreepopulartypesofcopulas,allowingfordi erentdegreesofassociationbetweenVandP.First,independencebetweenVandPproducestheintuitivecopulaFV;P(v;p)=FV(v)FP(p).Second,weallowforcommondependenceacrosssurveyedvoters,givenbyassociationparameter�11,employingtheFarlie-Gumbel-Morgensen(1960)familycopula,FV;P(v;p)=FP(p)FV(v)(1+(1�FP(p))(1�FV(v))),where�0impliespositivedependenceand0negativedependence.Potentially,couldbemadevoter-typedependent(e.g.,allowingforadi erentforleftandright-wingvoters),butnotvoter-speci c.TheFGMfamilyis exible,butallowsonlysmalldeparturesfromindependence.ThethirdtypeofcopulafamilyweconsideristheFrankfamily,FV;P(v;p)=1=log(1+D()),withD()=(eFP(p)�1)(eFV(v)�1)=(e�1)and=�.TheFrankfamilyallowslargerdeparturesfromindependenceandrequires6=0.Indeed,theFrankcopulaiswellsuitedtomodeloutcomeswithstrongpositiveornegativedependence.Thedependenceparameterisnotelicitedfromthesurvey,butcanbeestimatedfromthedata.Recallthatweobservevotedecisionsandsuchdecisionsarefunctionofthevoters'posteriors.Givenacopulafamily,wecanestimateadependenceparameteraspartofthevectorofparameters,,bymaximizingthelikelihoodofobservingthosevotesasinequation(1).Onecanfurtheremploystandardgeneralizedlikelihoodratioteststoassesstherelativequalityoftheassumptionsonthecopulafamilyandselectthepreferredfamily.Wefollowthisapproach.12 Tosummarize,oursetofparametersofinterestis=[ A; B; ;;;0]withbeliefparameters0=[P;2;V;2;P;3;V;3; P; V;A;B],whereweallowtheassociationparametertobedi erentforAandB.Estimating0fromvotedecisionsisonlyfeasiblefortheposteriorjointdistribution.Thepriorjointdistributioncanbefullycharacterizedunderanadditionalassumption.Assumption6:Subjectivebeliefdistributionshaveconstant0.Inparticular,whileweallowmarginalstobea ectedbyourinformationaltreatment,weassumethatthedependencebetweenideologyandvalenceofthecandidateisconstant.Forexample,assumingthatamoderatepolicystanceispositivelycorrelatedwithsmartercandidates,informationthatmovessubjectivepriorstowardhigherlevelsofvalenceVisallowedtohaveanimpactonthepolicystanceP,pushingittowardamoremoderatestance,butitisnotallowedtochangetheassociationbetweenPandV.9Figure2andFigure3provideanexampleofthejointdistributionsforaparticularvoter'sbeliefsaboutcandidateApriortotheelectioncampaignandafterreceivingthevalencemessagetreatment.Eachjointdistributionisdeterminedassumingindependenceofthemarginalsandbasedontheestimatesoftheparametersgoverningthemarginaldistributions.Forthisparticularvoter,receivingthevalencemessageincreasedhisbeliefaboutthevalenceofAandalsoreducedtheuncertaintyalongbothdimensions.InSection6,wewillseethatsuchchangesinbeliefsarerepresentativeofvotersreceivingthevalencemessagetreatment.3ExperimentalDesignInMay2011,incollaborationwiththereelectioncampaignoftheincumbentmayorintheItaliancityofArezzo,weimplementedtheexperimentalstrategyembeddedintheaboveempiricalmodelduringthemayor'sactualelectoralcampaign.Speci cally,wedividedthecityintofourareas,randomizingattheprecinctlevel,andtheincumbentsentdi erentcampaignmessagesbothbymailandbyphonecalltovotersintheseareas.Inthissection,wedescribetheinstitutionalsetting,aswellasthenatureofthe(randomized)campaignmessagesandtools.3.1InstitutionalSettingInItaly,mayorsofcitieswithmorethan15,000inhabitantsaredirectlyelectedunderapluralitysystemwithruno ,thatis,inthe rstroundthecandidatewhoobtainsmorethan50percentofthe 9AsanalternativetoAssumption6,onecouldcalibratejforthepriordistributionatspeci cvaluesandobservethesensitivityoftheresults.Anaturalrangeofvaluescouldbethecon denceintervalofthedependenceparameterfortheposteriors.Wedonotpursuethisavenuehere.13 votesiselected,otherwisethetwocandidatesreceivingthemostvotescompeteinasecondroundwhichtakesplacetwoweekslater.Mayoralcandidatesaresupportedbyoneormorepartylists,butvoterscancastseparatevotesforacandidateandapartylistsupportinganothercandidate.Theycanalsovoteonlyforamayoralcandidate,withoutexpressinganypreferenceforpartylists,buttheoppositeisnotallowed,becausevalidvotesforapartylistareautomaticallyattributedtothecandidateformayorsupportedbythatparty.Electedmayorsservea ve-yeartermandaresubjecttoatwo-termlimit.Italianmunicipalitiesareinchargeofawiderangeofservices,fromwatersupplytowastemanagement,frommunicipalpolicetocertaininfrastructures,andfromhousingtowelfarepolicies.Mayorsarethekeypoliticalplayersatthelocallevel,astheycanalsoappointtheexecutiveocersanddismissthematwill.Thecitycouncil,whichactsasthelegislativebody,canforcethemayortoresignwithanocon dencevote,butinthiscasethecouncilisalsodissolved.Becauseofthisinstitutionalsetting,municipalelectionshavehighsalienceandturnoutisusuallyveryhigh.ArezzoisaprovincialcapitalcityinthecenterofItaly,locatedintheprovinceofthesamename.In2011,ithad100,455inhabitantsand77,386eligiblevoters.Forelectoralpurposes,thecityisdividedinto95precincts(thesmallestelectoralunitwhichusuallycoincideswithaclusterofstreets),whichvotein42pollingplaces(e.g.,schools,publicbuildings).Fromapoliticalpointofview,thecitywascontestable.GiuseppeFanfani,theincumbentmayorelectedin2006whoacceptedrandomizationofapartofhisreelectioncampaign,belongedtothecenter-leftcoalition,butbeforehis rstelectionthecenter-rightcoalitionwonfortwotermsinarow.In2011,hismainchallengerwastheocialcandidateofthecenter-rightcoalition,GraziaSestini,aformerviceministeratthenationallevel.Sixother(minor)third-partycandidateswerealsopresentintheballot.Themainthird-partycandidatewasaformermayorofthecenter-rightcoalition,LuigiLucherini,sidelinedbyhispartyduetopendinglegaltrouble.10LocalpoliticalcampaignsarenotverysophisticatedinItaly,andtheymostlyrelyonpublicrallies,directmailing,andTVappearances(butnoads).Phonebanksarerarelyused,anddoor-to-doorcanvassingalmostneveroccurs. 10Themayoracceptedourproposaltorandomizehiscampaignbecauseofthepossibilityofreceivingpotentiallyusefulinformation.Asthecenter-rightcoalitionwassplitbetweenamainchallenger(Sestini)andalesscompetitiveone(Lucherini),heexpectedeithertowininthe rstroundortogototheruno .Therefore,ourrandomizedtrialcouldprovidehimwithane ectivestrategyforcampaigninginthetwoweeksbetweenthe rstandsecondround.14 3.2RandomizedCampaignTooperationalizeourinformationaltreatments,westudiedthecampaignmaterialsoftheincumbentandassembledrelevantinformationsoastoisolateslogansbasedoneitherhiscompetenceascitymanager(valencemessage)orhispoliticalstance(ideologymessage).Becausewewantedtostayawayfromthestrategicgamebetweenhim,theothercandidates,andthevoters(thatis,wewantedtorandomizehisactualcampaign),weactuallydevisedtwodi erentideologicalmessages:oneleaningtowardtheleftandoneleaningtowardthecenterofthepoliticalspectrum.Wethenallowedhimtochoosebetweenthetwoandheselectedtheleftistmessage.Furthermore,althoughourtreatmentofinterestcoincideswithpartisancampaignmessagesdeliveredbyoneofthecandidates,asopposedtonon-partisaninformation,wewantedourinforma-tionaltreatmentstobefactualandnon-emotional,astypicalforcheaporcostlysignalinggames.11Forthisreason,wematchedthemainsloganswithbulletpointsbasedonveri ableinformationabouttheincumbent'sperformanceandpolicychoicesduringhis rstterminoce.Futureresearchshouldextendtoemotionalmessagesaswell,butwedidnotexplorethisavenuehere.AppendixFiguresA1andA2showthemail yerscontainingthetwomessages.12Thevalence yerisbuiltaroundtwokeywords:competenceande ort.Theimplicitmessageisthatvotersshouldreelecttheincumbentbecausehewascompetentande ectiveascitymanager.ThefactualinformationprovidedreferstothefactthatArezzodevelopedanurbandevelopmentplanthatwasranked rstbytheregionalgovernmentandreceivedextrafundingbecauseofitsquality.Theextrafundingwasusedtorebuildmonuments,roads,andparkingslotsinthecitycenter.Theideology yerisbuiltaroundtwokeywords:awarenessandsolidarity.TheimplicitmessageisthatvotersshouldreelecttheincumbentbecausehesharesvaluesthatarecommonlyassociatedwiththeItalianleft.Thebulletpointsfurtherreinforcetheleftisttoneastheypointto\public"services,suchaschildcareandfoodfacilitiesforthepoor,thatwereexpandedduringhis rstterminoce.13Noticethatthetwomail yersareidenticalinsize,layout,colors,fonts,numberofwords,andphotoofthecandidate;onlythecontentofthecampaignmessagedi ers. 11Themarketingandadvertisingliterature(seeLiuandStout,1987)hasexploredsubjectiveresponsestofactualversusemotionalornonfactualmessages,indicatingsystematicdi erences.Asaninterestingcounter,Gerberetal.(2011)presentarandomizedtrialinvolvingnonfactualcampaignmessages.12IntheAppendix,wealsoreporttheEnglishtranslationofthetextofthetwo yers.Additionalmaterialsrelatedtoourrandomizedcampaigncanbefoundonthewebsite:www.igier.unibocconi.it/randomized-campaign.13Tovalidateouroperationalizationofthetwoinformationaltreatmentsexante,werandomlyassignedthetwo yersto50universitystudentsatBocconiUniversity(inMilan)whodidnotknowthemayorofArezzo.Wethenaskedthemtogivetheirsubjectiveassessmentofthepolitician'svalenceandideologyusingthesamequestionsdescribedinSection2.Forthe25studentswhoreceivedthe rstmessage,theaveragevalenceevaluationwas6.650(s.d.0.963)andtheaverageideologyevaluationwas3.100(s.d.0.700).Forthe25studentswhoreceivedthesecondmessage,thesevalueswere5.450(s.d.0.973)and2.050(s.d.0.669),respectively.15 Thetwocampaignmessages|valenceandideology|weresuppliedtovotersintwoways,throughdirectmailingandphonecalls.Therandomizationdesignwasimplementedasfollows.Weran-domlydividedthe95precinctsintofourgroups:(i)24precinctsreceivedthevalencemessage;(ii)24precinctsreceivedtheideologymessage;(iii)24precinctsreceivedbothmessages;(iv)23precinctsreceivednomessage(controlgroup).Furthermore,werandomlysplitthe rstthreegroupsintotwosubgroups:inthe rst,thetreatmentwasadministeredbybothdirectmailandphonecalls(12precincts);inthesecond,bydirectmailonly(12precincts).14AppendixTableA1reportstheex-antebalancetestsofpredeterminedvariablesattheprecinctlevel.Theavailablevariablesincludethenumberofeligiblevotersenlistedineachprecinct,thecity-wideneighborhoodeachprecinctbelongsto,andpastelectoraloutcomesofnational,regional,European,andmunicipalelections.Asprecinctswerereshuedinthelastdecade,someoutcomesarenotavailableforall95precincts.Allofthepredeterminedvariablesarebalancedacrosstreat-mentgroups.Onlythenumberofeligiblevotersdisplaysacoecientsigni cantatthe10percentlevel,becauseofthepresenceofafewsmallprecinctsinthecountrysidethatcouldnotbespreadacrossallgroups.Removingtheseprecinctsfromtheanalysis,however,doesnotaltertheresults.Inordertoincreasethee ectivenessofthecampaignmessages,wedrewusefulinsightsfromtheU.S.experimentalevidencesummarizedbyGreenandGerber(2004).First,weactedintheweekbeforeelectionday,soastoensurethemessagesticksinvoters'minds.Second,wehadourmail yersdesignedbyprofessionalsanddirectlysenttoindividualswiththeirnameandaddressontheenvelope.15Third,wedidnotuseautomatedrobocalls.Weinsteadtrainedvolunteerstomakethecampaignphonecalls.Speci cally,fromthecandidate'sheadquarters,volunteerscalledallselectedhouseholdswiththefollowingprotocol: rst,theywereinstructedtotalkwiththevotersandaskfortheiropinionforabouttwominutes.Then,theywouldaskthevotertolistentoarecordedmessagefromthecandidate.Attheendofthecall,therecordedvoiceofthecandidatereada30-secondscriptwiththeabovevalenceandideologymessages(oracombinationofthetwo).16Ourrandomizedcampaignusedtheabovetools|mailersandphonecalls|onalargescale.Allhouseholdsinthecityreceivedanenvelopefromtheincumbentcampaign.Theenvelopecontainedtheocialplatformofthepoliticalpartiessupportingthecandidateplusoneofour yers(orbothofthem)accordingtotheassignedtreatmentgroup.Votersinthecontrolgroupreceivedjustthe 14Aswewerealreadypushingtheboundariesintermsofsamplesize,wedecidedthattheaccuracylosscouldnotjustifyanadditionalsubgrouptreatedbyphonecallsonly.15Toavoidsendingmultipleenvelopestothesamehousehold,werandomizedthenameofthereceiverwithineachhousehold,becausewedidnotwanttotargetonlyhouseholdheads.16IntheAppendix,wereporttheEnglishtranslationofthetextofthethreerecordedmessages.Originalaudio lesareavailableonthewebsite:www.igier.unibocconi.it/randomized-campaign.16 platform,butnotthe yerwithourinformationaltreatment.Thisprocedureallowedustokeepthecandidateunawareoftherandomizationoutcome.Ofcourse,thecandidateapprovedallmessagesandpaidforthecostsofthecampaign,butwegavehimclosedenvelopessothathecouldnotinferwhichprecinctswerereceivingone yerasopposedtotheother.Insummary,allhouseholdswithatleastonememberenlistedasaneligiblevoterreceivedourmailers.Ontopofthis,about25percentofthehouseholdsinthetreatmentgroupsalsoreceivedacampaignphonecall.173.3DataToelicitbeliefsaboutthevalenceandideologyofthetwomaincandidatesalongthelinesdescribedinSection2,werantwosurveysof2,042eligiblevotersdistributedacrossalltreatmentgroups.Weranthe rstsurveytendaysbeforetheelectionand,mostimportantly,beforevotersreceivedtheinformationaltreatments,soastomeasurepriorsanddemographiccharacteristics.Thesecondsurveywasconductedthedayaftertheelectionandwasmeanttomeasureposteriorsand(self-declared)votechoices.Toimplementoursurveys,wecontractedacompanyfromanotherItalianregion,soastohaveinterviewerswithdi erentaccentsfromthecampaignvolunteersandtoremoveanylinkbetweenthecampaignandthesurveyphonecalls.About71percentoftherespondentsinthe rstsurveyalsorepliedtothequestionaboutwhethertheyvotedornotinthesecondsurvey.Therefore,oursampleismadeupof1,455voters,1,306ofwhomactuallyvotedforoneofthecandidates.However,231ofthe1,306votersdidnotspecifyforwhichcandidatetheyvotedandforthisreasonweaccommodateforpotentiallynon-randomnon-responsesinthemodelestimation.Tofurthervalidateourrandomizationdesignexpost,wecheckedforbalancingofthecharac-teristicsofvotersacrosstreatmentgroups.Surveyvariablesincludedemographiccharacteristics,educationalattainment,politicalorientation,homeownership,andhowoftenvotersreadnewspa-persorwatchTV.TheresultsarereportedinAppendixTableA2.Noneofthese(self-declared)individualcharacteristicsisstatisticallydi erentacrosstreatmentgroups.18Table1summarizeselectionresultsattheprecinctlevel.Theincumbentmayorwonhisbidforreelectionwithavoteshare51.3percent,enoughtoavoidaruno .Table2showsthe(self- 17Becauseofbudgetandtimeconstraints,wecouldnotreachallhouseholdsbyphone.18Asanadditionalex-postvalidationoftherandomizationdesign,webuiltproxiesofCensuscharacteristicsattheprecinctlevel.Thisexercisehastwolimitations,however.First,datafromthelastavailableCensusreferto2001.Second,precinctsarenoteasilymatchablewithCensuscells.Toovercomethesecondlimitation,weimplementedthefollowinggeocodingprocedure:1)foreachstreet(i.e.,line)belongingtoaprecinctwecalculatedtheweightedaverageofthecharacteristicsoftheCensuscells(i.e.,polygons)overlappingwiththatstreet(withweightsequaltotheoverlappingsegments);2)foreachprecinct,wecalculatedtheweightedaverageofthecharacteristicsoftheassociatedstreets(withweightsequaltothepopulationlivingineachstreet).AppendixTableA3reportsthebalancingtestsoftheseCensuscharacteristicsacrosstreatmentgroups.Althoughtheestimatesarelikelytosu erfromattenuationbiasduetomeasurementerror,noneofthemisstatisticallydi erentfromzero.17 declared)votechoicesofsurveyedindividuals.Asoftenhappensinpost-electoralpolls,thereisaslightbandwagone ectinvotedeclarationsfavoringthewinningcandidate(57.1percent).Thebandwagonisnotaconcernforestimationunderthe(plausible)assumptionthatthise ectisorthogonaltoourtreatmentgroups.Inanycase,recallthatastrengthofourapproachisthatwecancross-validatetheconsistencyoftreatmente ectsinthesurveydata(attheindividuallevel)withthoseintheaggregateactualvotingdata(attheprecinctlevel).4EvidenceonChoicesInthissection,weevaluatewhetherourinformationaltreatmentshadanye ectonvotingchoicesatboththeprecinctandindividuallevel.Basedontheexperimentaldesigndescribedintheprevioussection,the(reduced-form)causale ectsofcampaigningonvalenceversusideologycanbeestimatedthroughtheOLSmodel:Yi=6Xk=1 kDki+i(3)whereYiistheelectoraloutcomeofinterest,Dkiarebinaryindicatorscapturingtreatmentgroupstatus,andiistheerrorterm.19Thesixtreatmentgroups,Dk;include:valencemessagebyphone(andmail);valencemessagebymailonly;ideologymessagebyphone(andmail);ideologymessagebymailonly;doublemessagebyphone(andmail);anddoublemessagebymailonly.Observationsreceivingnoinformationaltreatmentaretheexcludedreferencegroup.Table3summarizestheresultsintheaggregatesample,whoseunitsofobservationarethe95electoralprecincts.Atthemargin,partisanadshavenoimpactonturnout.Thereisevidence,however,thatcampaigningonvalencebringsmorevotestotheincumbentwhenphonecallsareusedasacampaigntool.Phonecallsdeliveringthevalencemessageincreasetheincumbent'svoteshareby4.1percentagepoints(i.e.,byabout8.4percentwithrespecttotheaverageshareinthecontrolgroup).Thisestimatede ectissizable,becauseitmustbeinterpretedasanintention-to-treate ect:infact,only25percentofthehouseholdsinthetreatedprecinctsreceivedacampaignphonecallandnotallofthemacceptedourinvitationtolistentothemessagerecordedbythecandidate.Becauseofthesmallsamplesize,however,coecientsarenotpreciselyestimatedandwecannotrejectthenullhypothesisthattheyarestatisticallyequaltoeachother. 19Toaccountforpotentialintra-classcorrelationbetweenneighboringprecinctsweclusterstandarderrorsatthepollingplacelevel,whiletoaccountforcorrelatedtimeshocksinsurveydataweinclude xede ectsfortheinterviewdate;resultsarenotsensitivetothesemodelingchoices.Empiricalresultsarequalitativelysimilarwhenweincludepredeterminedvariablesasadditionalcovariates,althoughthespeci cationbecomesdemandingintermsofdegreesoffreedomintheaggregatedata(resultsavailableuponrequest).18 Whatwecanrejectintheaggregatedataisthenullthatthetwocampaigntools|mailersversusphonebanks|areequallye ective.Ifwemergetogetherallgroupsthatreceivedaninformationaltreatmentwiththesamecampaigntool,we ndthat|withrespecttothecontrolgroup|phonecallsincreasetheincumbentvoteshareby2.7percentagepoints(p-value:0.019),while,statistically,thee ectofmailersisbothdi erentfrom2.7andnotdi erentfromzero.ThisresultisinlinewithU.S.experimentalevidenceshowingthatmailersareusuallyine ectiveinpoliticalcampaigns(seeGreenandGerber,2004).Inourcase,however,mailersarealsoadministeredtovoterswhoreceiveaphonecall.Therefore,wecannotruleoutthepossibilitythatmailersaloneareine ective,buttheybecomee ectivewheninteractedwithothercampaigntoolsdeliveringthesamemessage.Basedontheaboveevidenceontheine ectivenessofmailersalone,Table4estimatesequation(3)imposingthisrestriction:includingboth\mail"and\nomessage"inthecontrolgroup.Stan-darderrorsareslightlylower,andthepointestimatesandthestatisticalsigni canceoftheincludedregressorsarealmostidenticalwithrespecttothefullmodel.Inordertovalidatetheaggregateevidenceandtogainstatisticalaccuracy,weestimateequation(3)usingtheindividual-levelsurveydata,wheresamplesizeislessofanissue.Theunitsofobservationarethe1,455eligiblevotersforturnoutorthe1,306actualvotersforthevoteshares.Asalloutcomesarebinary,estimationisbyprobit.Thepricewepayisthathereoutcomesareself-reported,thatis,basedonvotedeclarationsandnotonactualchoices.Theunderlyingassumptionisthatself-reportingbiasisthesameacrosstreatmentgroups.20Table5reportstheestimatesforalltreatmentgroups.Resultsareconsistentwiththeaggregateevidence.Phonecallsdeliveringthevalencemessageincreasetheincumbent'svoteshareby9.5percentagepoints(i.e.,byabout16percentwithrespecttothecontrolgroup).Thise ectislargerthanintheaggregatedata,buttreatmentintensityisalsohigherinthiscontext,becauseallsurveyedhouseholdsreceivedthecampaignphonecall,asopposedtoonly25percentintheaggregatedata.Phonecallsarestillthemoree ectivecampaigntool,withadi erencesigni cantatthe1percentlevel.Moreimportantly,conditionaloncampaigntool,thevalencemessageisnowstatisticallymoree ectivethantheideologymessageatthe10percentlevel.21Table6furtheremphasizesthispointby 20Aswedocumentinthenextsection,non-responseinvotedeclarationsislikelytobenon-random,i.e.,tobeassociatedwithindividualcharacteristicssuchasideologyorpriorbeliefs.Thisdoesnotimply,however,that(non-random)non-responseshouldnotbeorthogonalto(random)treatmentassignment.21Althoughourexperimentaldesign|basedonrandomizationattheprecinctlevel|didnotallowforstrati cationonindividualcharacteristics,wenonethelessinvestigatedpotentiallyheterogeneousresponsesbyrepeatingthebaselineestimationinsplitsamplesalongmanyobservabledimensions.Thepositiveimpactofvalencephonecallsontheincumbent'svoteshareturnsouttobestatisticallylargerforfemales,individualsolderthan65years,individualswithoutacollegedegree,andless-informedvoters.Instead,thereisnosigni cantheterogeneityalongpreviouspoliticalorientation,homeownership,ortypeofoccupation(resultsavailableuponrequest).19 focusingoninformationaltreatmentsadministeredbyphone:campaigningonvalencebringsmorevotestotheincumbentandtothepartyliststhatsupporthim,andthesepointestimatesarestatisticallylargerthanthoseofcampaigningonideologyalone.Finally,inAppendixTableA4,weevaluatethepotentialimpactofspilloversacrossneighboringprecincts.AsacounterparttoTable5,weestimatethee ectsonvotingchoicesoftheaveragetreatmentintensityforindividualsvotinginthesamepollingplace,althoughtheymaybelongtodi erentprecinctsandthereforetreatmentgroups.IfAssumption1(SUTVA)ismet,weexpectthesemeasurestohavenoimpactonchoicesfortreatmentsdetectedasine ectiveinTable5,andtohavealesssigni cantimpactfortreatmentsdetectedase ectiveinTable5.Itisthusreassuringthatnoneofthesespilloverestimatesisstatisticallydi erentfromzero.225ModelEstimationWenowreporttheresultsfromthemaximumlikelihood(ML)estimationofourvotingmodel.Theestimationprocedureisstraightforwardandrelieson ttingindividualvotedeclarations,which|inSection4|wehaveshowntocloselymatchactualvoteoutcomes.23Thespeci cationselectionwarrantssomediscussion,however.Section2discussednon-responseparameters[ A; B],preferenceparameters[ ;;],beliefpa-rameters[P;2;V;2;P;3;V;3; P; V;A;B],andthechoiceofacopulafamily[Independent;Frank;FGM].Concerningthepreferenceparameters,alargeliteratureinpoliticaleconomicsandpoliticalsciencehasemphasizedpreferenceheterogeneity,forinstanceinthecaseofdistasteforspeci cpolicyoutcomes,suchasin ationorunemployment.24Wecaneasilyaccommodatethisfeaturebyallowingadi erent[ ;;]vectorforleft-wing(L),centrist(C),andright-wing(R)vot-ers.Wecanaswellaccommodateheterogeneityinthedependencestructureofthebeliefs[A;B]byallowingthemtodi erforL,C,andRvoters.Concerningtheskewnessofthemarginalbeliefs,onecanexperimentwithrelaxingthesimple[ P; V]toamore exible[ P;2; V;2; P;3; V;3],thus 22NoticethatpointestimatesarenotdirectlycomparablewiththoseinTable5becausetheregressorsarenolongerdummiesbutshares.Comparedtotheaveragevaluesandstandarddeviationsofthespillovershares,however,pointestimatesaregenerallysmall,and|asexpected|theyarelargerfortheadministrationofthevalencemessagebyphone,becauseinthosecasesthesharesalsoincludetreatedvotersforwhomthereexistsanon-zeroe ect.23Theidenti cationofthemodelisassessedthroughseveralroundsofMonteCarlosimulations.Forgivenparametervalueswesimulatedindividualvotesandensuredthattheestimationbasedonthesimulateddataconvergedtotheoriginalstructuralvalues.Ourlikelihoodfunctiondependsonarelativelysmallnumberofparameters.Thisallowsforafairlyextensivesearchforglobaloptimaovertheparametricspace.WeusethepatternsearchalgorithmofMatlabwithdi eringinitialvalues.Repeatingtheoptimizationprocedureconsistentlydeliversidenticalglobaloptima.Wealsoemployedageneticalgorithm(GA)globaloptimizerwithalargeinitialpopulationof10;000valuesfollowedbyasimplexsearchmethodusingtheGAvaluesasinitialvaluesforthelocaloptimizer.Bothmethodsresultedinthesameestimatesbutthepatternsearchalgorithmconvergesfasterinourenvironment.24Amongothers,seeDiTella,MacCulloch,andOswald(2001);GerberandLewis(2004).20 allowingtheextentoftheskewtochangewiththevariance.Allthesearetestableparametricconstraintsthatcanbeassessedbasedonlikelihoodratiotests.Ontheotherhand,thechoiceofthecopulafamilyrequiresageneralizedlikelihoodratiotestapproach,asthecopulafamiliesweconsiderarenon-nested.TheVuong(1989)modelselectiontestisappropriateforthispurpose.InAppendixTablesA5andA6wereportthefullsetofmodelestimatesforalltherelevantcombinationsofparametricandcopulaassumptions,whicharepairwisetestedinAppendixTablesA7,A8,andA9throughlikelihoodratiotestsandVuongtests(forthecopula).Accordingtothetests,thepreferredspeci cationallowsforheterogeneityinpreferenceparametersalongthevoter'sself-declaredideologicalstance,forindependencebetweentheideologicalandvalencedimensionsofbothcandidates,andforcommon[ P; V].Thus,thepreferredmodelspeci cationestimates=[ A; B;f z;z;zgz=L;C;R;P;2;V;2;P;3;V;3; P; V].WereporttheMLestimatesforthismodelinTable7.We rstnotethattheestimatesoftheprobabilityofresponse(i.e.,theprobabilityofdisclosingone'svote)are0:76and0:99forpredictedvotesforA( A)andB( B),respectively,andareverypreciselyestimated.WhilewecannotrejectthenullthattheprobabilityofresponseisoneforvotersthatvotedforB,wecanstronglyrejectthenullforvotersthatvotedforA;whichjusti esourchoiceofmodelingnon-randomnon-response.25Interestingly,voterswhoarepredictedtohavevotedBaremorelikelytodisclosetheirvote,contrarytothepossiblehypothesisthatthosewhovotedforthewinner(A)shouldbemorewillingtodisclosetheirpreferenceforthewinner.ThisresultsquareswiththeintuitionofconservativevotersinTuscanybeingparticularlyassertive.Generally,thepreferenceparametersareestimatedwithprecision.Theparametergoverningtheinteractionbetweenvalenceandideologyvaluesforthevoter,,isestimatedtobeafairlyprecisezero.Imposing=0clari estheinterpretationof astherelativeweightinpreferencesofvalence(x0)totheweightofideology(1�x0).Hence, =x0 1�x0=1impliesequalweightsalongbothdimensionsandthisiswhatwe ndforLandCvoters.TheweightonvalenceforRvotersis,however,muchlower,around27percent,versusa73percentweightonideology.Concerningthecurvatureoftheideologicallossfunctionu(:),surprisingly,we nd1forallthreetypesofvoters,indicatingincreasinglossesbutatdiminishingratesfrompoliciesfurtherawayfromthevoter'sblisspoint.Thisisincontrastwiththestandardassumptionof=2,quadratic 25Asfurtherevidenceinsupportoftheprobabilityofdisclosingone'svotebeingnon-random,weranaprobitregressionofadummyindicatingwhetherornotavotewasdisclosedontheelicitedposteriorbeliefsandvoter'sideology.AnFteststronglyrejectsthenullhypothesisofnoexplanatorypowerandhencerandomnon-response(p-value=0.000).Interestingly,thestrongervoters'beliefsaboutthevalenceofeithercandidate,themorelikelyvotersaretodisclosetheirvote.21 losses,forexample.Forcentristvoters,isactuallyestimatedtobezero,althoughtheestimateisratherimprecise.With=0,thelossduetodeviationsfromthevoter'sblisspointisconstantandindependentofthecandidate'spolicy.Thebeliefparametersarealsopreciselyestimatedforthemostpart.Interestingly,thespeci -cationfeedsbackinformationwhichallowsustoassesscertainfeaturesofthesurveydesign.Themodelclearlycapturesanintermediatelevelofuncertaintybetween at(s=1)anddegeneratepri-ors(s=4)forbothvalenceandideology.Theon-the-modeprobabilitymass,V;3;isestimatedataround0:40forvalenceandthecorrespondingparameterforideology,P;3;isestimatedataround0:58.Hence,votersanswering2to5toQ2aremorecertainthanhaving atpriors,butde nitelynotsureaboutthecandidatebeingatthemode(i.e.,answer1toQ2).Alongthevalencedimen-sion,votersdonotperceivethedistinctionbetween\veryuncertain"(s=2)and\ratheruncertain"(s=3)giventhat,attheestimatedvalues,V;3=V;2.However,alongtheideologydimension,\ratheruncertain"doesresultinlessdispersioninthemarginaldistribution.Inaddition,thean-swersgiventotheskewnessdimensionseemtobeimportantonlyalongtheideologicaldimension,where P�1=2,butnotonthevalencedimensionwhere Visnotsigni cantlydi erentfrom1=2,indicatingasymmetricpartitioningoftheo -modeprobabilitymass.Finally,concerningthechoiceofthecopulaandtheestimatesofthedependenceparameters,wenotethat,althoughboththeFGMandFrankcopulamodelshavetypicallyhigherlikelihoodvaluesthanunderindependence,thelossofparsimonyofthemodeldoesnotjustifytheadditionalparametersaccordingtotheVuongtests(seeAppendixTableA9).Thisresultoccursbecausewecanonlyestimate[A;B]veryimprecisely,whichcanbeeasilyrationalized.Theparameters[A;B]areessentiallyidenti edbyvotersthatare:i)closetoachangeintheirvotechoicebetweenAandB;andii)characterizedbynon-degenerateandnon- atbeliefsalongboththeideologyandvalencedimensions.Thesejointrestrictionssubstantiallyreducethenumberofobservationsprovidingusefulidentifyingvariationforestimating[A;B].Notwithstandingthelackofprecision,lookingatthesignsoftheestimateddependenceparametersinAppendixTablesA5andA6isintriguing.Wegenerally ndevidenceofapositiveassociationbetweenleftpositionandvalenceperceptionsforAdrivenbyleft-wingvoters,andapositiveassociationbetweenrightpositionandvalenceperceptionsforBdrivenbyright-wingvoters.Moreextremepositionsappeartobecorrelatedwithhighervalence,inaccordancewiththetheoreticalresultsinBernhardtetal.(2011).TheFrankcopulaispreferredovertheFGMcopula,althoughwecannotrejectthenullofequal t.Thestructuralestimationhasallowedustofullyrecoveralloftheparametersnecessarytocharacterizetheindividualbeliefdistributions.Weproceedtotheanalysisofvoters'beliefsnext.22 6EvidenceonBeliefsThee ectofpartisanadsonbeliefsisinterestingperse,anditcanshedlightontherobustnessoftheimpactofthesameadsonvotingchoices,basedontheirmutualconsistency.Toincreaseaccuracy,werestrictourattentiontoinformationaltreatmentsdeliveredbyphone,thatis,bymeansofthee ectivecampaigntool.InTables8and10,theoutcomesaretheaverageandthestandarddeviationoftheindividualbeliefdistributions|frommodelestimation|ofbothvalenceandideologyoftheincumbentandoftheopponent,respectively.InTables9and11,welookatthesamemomentsoftheindividualbeliefdistributions,butweinsteadusesurveyresponsesasopposedtoestimatesfromthestructuralmodel.Speci cally,theoutcomesarethe(self-reported)modeandabinarymeasureof\uncertainty"(namely,adummycapturing atpriorsinsurveyresponses).EstimationisbyOLSformultivaluedorcontinuousoutcomesandbyprobitforbinaryoutcomes.26Fortheincumbent,boththevalenceandideologymessageshavetheexpecteddirecte ects.Informationonvalenceincreasesperceivedcompetencebyabout5percentwithrespecttotheaverageperception.Thesameholdsforinformationonideology,asperceivedideologydecreases(i.e.,movestotheleft)byabout5percent.Interestingly,secondmomentsarealsoa ectedbythetwotreatments:uncertaintyabouttheincumbent'svalenceorideologyisreducedbyadditionalcampaigninformationalongthecorrespondingdimension.Decreaseduncertaintyisarelevantchannelofthee ectofcampaigninformationonchoices.Asamatteroffact,thepositivee ectofvalencephonecallsontheincumbent'svoteshareisstrongerinthesubsampleofvoterswhosepriorsare at.Inthetreatedgroup,weobserveasharptighteningofthebeliefdistribution,whichcontributestotheoveralle ect.Thenegativeimpactofideologymessagephonecallsonthecandidate'sideologydoesnottrans-lateintomore(orless)votesforA.Notwithstandingthelargeutilityweightvotersplaceonthisdimension,theshiftinthebeliefdistributionscausedbytheideologyphonecallsisnotstrongenoughtoa ectvotingchoices.27Withrespecttoideology,informationontheincumbent'spositionhasinterestingcross-e ectsontheperceptionoftheopponent'sposition.VoterswhoreceivedtheideologyphonecallfromtheincumbentcampaignmovetheirsubjectiveevaluationoftheopponentBtotherightby3percent.Thetreatmentalsoreducesuncertaintyalongthisdimension.Thismightbeduetotheincreased 26Forthesakeofintuition,weuseOLSalsofortheideologymode,whichcanonlytake ve(ordinal)values.ResultsfromorderedProbitarequalitativelyidentical(availableuponrequest).27Analternativeexplanationmightbethattheideologymessagea ectsright-wingandleft-wingintheoppositeway,butthisisnotwhatwe ndinoursample.Ideologyphonecallshadnegligiblee ectsonvotingbehaviorforbothtypesofvoters,whiletheirimpactonbeliefswasalmostequivalent.23 salienceoftheleft/rightdistinctionortoitsrelativenature,anditiscausalevidenceofcross-learningbetweenpoliticalcampaigns.This ndingisconsistentwithasophisticatedsubjectiveupdatingbehavioronthepartofthevoters.Forexample,thistypeofevidencewouldbeconsistent(albeitnotproofof)Bayesianupdatinginatwo-candidatesignalinggame.7ModelFitandCounterfactualElectoralCampaignsToconcludeouranalysiswediscussmodel tresultsandcounterfactualelectoralsimulationsbasedonourstructuralestimates.Overall,thestructuralmodelunderthebaselinespeci cationpredictstheactualvotecorrectly88:7percentofthetime.Inparticular,wepredictcorrectly95:9percentofthevotesforcandidateAand70:7percentofthevotesforB.Here,thesampleunderconsiderationisrestrictedtothevoterswhodisclosedtheirvoteonly,sincewedonotknowtheactualvoteofthosewhochosenottodiscloseit.Turningtocounterfactuals,nostandardprotocolexistsintheliteratureforrunningthesetypesofexercises,sowehavedevisedone.SupposeonewishestoassesswhatwouldhavehappenedtotheaggregatevoteshareofAifeverybodyinthecityhadreceivedthevalencemessage(i.e.,hadgottentreatmentH=1).Wesimulatethiscounterfactualcampaignusinga vestepprocedure.UnderourstabilityAssumption6,foreachvoteri;itispossibletogeneratepriorbeliefdis-tributionsaboutAandBbasedupontheirpriorsurveyanswersand0,thestructuralparametervectorestimatedfromvotesandposteriorbeliefs.Thisisthe rststep.Secondly,foreachvoteri2T(h)withh6=1(i.e.,nottreatedwiththevalencemessagetobeginwith),itisalwayspossibleto ndthenearestneighbortreatedmatchinthegrouph=1,i02T(1),basedontheMahalanobisdistancemetricderivedfromcovariates(suchasage,gender,maritalstatus,education,priors,andideology).Voteri0istheclosestmatchtovoteriforwhichthecausale ectofvalenceonbeliefsisactuallyobserved.Essentially,thisisthesameintuitiononewouldfollowinpropensityscoreestimation.Oncetheclosestmatchi0hasbeenidenti ed,asthirdstepwecomputethedi erencebetweeni0'smarginalposteriorandpriorbeliefsateverypointofthesupportofeachofthevalenceandideologydimensions.Fourth,weapplyi0'spointwisechangesinbeliefstoi'spriorstocalculatethecounterfactualposteriormarginalbeliefsofi,undertheassumptionthat,hadigottenthesametreatmentasi0,shewouldhaveupdatedherbeliefsinthesamewayasi0.Fifth,wecomputejointposteriorbeliefsusingtheappropriatecopulafamilyandtheestimated's.Giventheposteriorsforeachvoteri,weobtainasimulatedelectoraloutcome,bycalculatingtheexpectedutilityofeachcandidateforiandthenpredictingtheirvoteforthecandidatewiththehighestexpectedutility.24 Importantly,thissimulationproceduredoesnotrequirethesimulatedelectoralcampaigntoonlyfocusonasingletreatment,butitcanbetweakedtotargetingspeci csubgroupswithdi erenttreatments.Forinstance,wecansimulateacampaigninwhichvalencemessagesaresenttoknowncentristandright-wingvoterswhileideologicalmessagesaresenttoleft-wingvoters.Thisisofparticularrelevanceatapointintimewhenpoliticalcampaigns,especiallyintheUS,haveincreasinglyturnedtospecializedcompanies,suchasAristotle,formicrodataacquisitionandselectivecampaignadvertising,atrendwellunderwayalsoincommercialandonlinemarketing.WeexploresomeofthepossibleelectoralcounterfactualsinTable12.Foreachcounterfactual,weincludeallvoters,eventhosewhodidnotdisclosetheiractualvote.Table12reportscounterfactualelectoraloutcomesfor vetypesofcampaignsbyA:(1)ablanketvalencecampaign;(2)ablanketideologicalcampaign;(3)ablanketdoublevalence-ideologycampaign;(4)atargetedcampaignofvalencemessagestocenterandright-wingvotersanddoublemessagestoleft-wingvoters;(5)atargetedcampaignofideologicalmessagestocenterandright-wingvotersanddoublemessagestoleft-wingvoters.Allresultsarebenchmarkedtothesimulatedelectoraloutcomethatwouldhaverealizedintheabsenceofanycampaignmessageonourpart.Thecounterfactualsarealsoassessedintheirprecisionbyconstructing95percentasymptoticcon denceintervalsbasedonbootstrappingfromtheasymptoticdistributionoftheparameters.Allourcounterfactualestimatesappearstatisticallyprecise.Themoste ectivepossiblecampaignistheelectoralcampaigninwhichvalencemessagesalonearesenttoallvoters.AblanketvalencecampaignincreasesthevoteshareofAby2:2percentagepointsrelativetonocampaign,whichismorethanenoughtomakethedi erenceinaclosely-contestedelection.Interestingly,ablanketcampaignofideologymessagesactuallyreducesthevoteshareofAsubstantially,infactbythesame2:2percentagepointsthatablanketvalencecampaignwouldinsteadbringtoA.Infact,the95percentcon denceintervalsforthetwosimulatedcampaignsdonotoverlap,sowecanbereasonablycertainthatablanketvalencecampaignwouldhaveoutperformedablanketideologycampaign.Tounderstandwhytheideologycampaignreducesvoteshares,recallthattheideologicalmessageinourexperimenthasaleftistbent,reducingtheexpectedutilityfromAforR,CandpossiblythemostmoderateoftheLvoters.Overall,thelossofsupportfromCandRinoursampleturnsouttomorethansucienttoo setthegaininLvoters.Forthesamereason,adoublecampaignofbothideologyandvalencemessagesincreasesthevoteshareofAby0:5percentagepoints,which,whilee ective,isnotase ectiveastheblanketvalence-onlycampaign.Finally,themixedcampaigninwhichLvotersgetbothtypesofmessageswhileCandRvotersgetvalencemessagesonlyisalmostase ectiveasthevalencecampaign,25 whilethecampaigninwhichLvotersgetbothtypesofmessageswhileCandRvotersgetideologymessagessubstantiallydecreasesA'svoteshare.Insummary,consistentlywithouroverallresults,campaigningonvalenceappearedthemoste ectivetooltopersuadevoters.8ConclusionThispaperpresentsnovelevidenceonthee ectsofcampaigninformationonvoters'decisionsinalarge-scale eldexperiment.Importantly,oure ectsareobservedbothinvotedeclarationsofsurveyedvotersandinactualvoteoutcomesattheprecinctlevel.Tothebestofourknowledge,thisisthe rstempiricalrandomizationexerciseintheliteraturethatoperatesatthescaleofanentireelectionandcoverstheentirevotingpopulationinamaturedemocracy.Bothourreduced-formandstructuralestimationresultsuncoverlargeelectoralgainsfromvalence-basedinformationalcampaigning,possiblyduetotherelativelyhigherlackofpriorinformationaboutthecandidatesalongthisdimension.Anadditionalcontributionofourpaperistopresentabeliefelicitationprotocolthatallowsus,whencombinedwithinformationontheelectoralchoicesofvoters,tocompletelycharacterizevoters'beliefsaboutcandidatesalongboththeideologicalandvalencedimensions.Ourmethodologyallowsusto exiblyincorporatemultivariatebeliefdistributionswithinastructuralrandomutilityvotingmodel.Wethenemploythisempiricalmodeltostructurallyestimatebothbeliefdistributionsandvoters'preferenceparameters.Fromamethodologicalviewpoint,weincorporateageneralstructureofbeliefsupdatingthatgoeswellbeyondwhatnormallyachievablewithstandardassumptionsinthepoliticalandcom-mercialadvertisingliterature.Forinstance,letusconsiderconjugatepriorsoftheGaussianfamily.Withnormalbeliefsnewsignalscannotreducetheprecisionofthesubjectivedistributions,theyalwaysreducethevarianceofthesedistributions.Butrelyingonsuchbeliefsisveryrestrictive.Toseethisconsideranotherintuitivebeliefdistribution:abinomial.Whentherearetwo(ormoregenerally nite)states,theprobabilityofthe\good"statecangoupordowndependingonthesignalvalue.Asaresult,thevarianceofthebeliefscanactuallyincreaseordecreaseafterreceivingadditionalinformation.Hence,theimportanceofleavingthebeliefsfamilyunrestrictediscrucialinnotforcingerroneousassumptionsontothedata.Ourestimatesshowthattheutilityweightplacedbyvotersonacandidate'spolicypositionisofapproximatelyequalmagnitudetothatplacedonacandidate'svalenceandthatthecommonassumptionofconvexityofthelossesfromideologicaldistanceisnotsupportedbythedata.We26 alsoshowhowtheinformationaltreatmentswedesignedsystematicallyin uenceboththe rstandsecondmomentsofvoters'marginalbeliefsaboutbothcandidatesintheelectoralrace,notonlythebeliefsaboutthecandidateoriginatingthemessage.Webelievethiscausalevidenceofcross-campaignlearningcanproveusefulforunderstandingthelevelofsophisticationinsubjectiveupdatingbyvoters.Potentialapplicationsofourelicitationmethodologyandestimationappeartobequitewide,in-cluding,inadditiontopoliticalcampaigning,commercialadvertisingandmarketing.Ourapproachcouldbeofusefortheassessmentofanytypeofinformationaltreatmentforrandomizedcontrolledtrials,mostofthemcurrentlyperformedindevelopingcountries.Finally,ourincorporationoftheprobabilityofnon-responsemaybeappliedinmanyothercontextsinwhichnon-randomnon-responsetosurveyquestionsseemsplausible(e.g.,reportsofincomeorotherlabor-relatedquestionsforwhichthosesurveyedmaybeuncomfortabledisclosinginformation).27 References[1]Ansolabehere,Stephen,andShantoIyengar.1995.GoingNegative:HowPoliticalAdvertise-mentsShrinkandPolarizetheElectorate.NewYork:TheFreePress.[2]Ansolabehere,Stephen,ShantoIyengar,AdamSimon,andNicholasValentino.1994.\DoesAttackAdvertisingDemobilizetheElectorate?"AmericanPoliticalScienceReview,88,829{838.[3]Ansolabehere,StephenandJamesM.Snyder.2000.\ValencePoliticsandEquilibriuminSpa-tialElectionModels,"PublicChoice,103,327{336.[4]Ansolabehere,Stephen,JamesM.Snyder,andCharlesStewart,III.2001.\CandidatePosi-tioninginU.S.HouseElections,"AmericanJournalofPoliticalScience,45,136{159.[5]Aragones,EnriquetaandThomasR.Palfrey.2002.\MixedEquilibriuminaDownsianModelwithaFavoredCandidate,"JournalofEconomicTheory,103,131{161.[6]Ashworth,ScottandEthanBuenodeMesquita.2009.\ElectionswithPlatformandValenceCompetition,"GamesandEconomicBehavior,67,191{216.[7]Banerjee,Abhijit,SelvanKumar,RohiniPande,andFelixSu.2011.\DoInformedVotersMakeBetterChoices?ExperimentalEvidencefromUrbanIndia,"MITmanuscript.[8]Banerjee,Abhijit,DonaldGreen,andRohiniPande.2012.\CanVotersbePrimedtoChooseBetterLegislators?EvidencefromVoterCampaignsinIndia,"MITmanuscript.[9]Bernhardt,Dan,OdilonCamara,andFrancescoSquintani.2011.\CompetenceandIdeology,"ReviewofEconomicStudies,78,487{522.[10]Blass,AsherA.,SaulLach,andCharlesF.Manski.2010.\UsingElicitedChoiceProbabili-tiestoEstimateRandomUtilityModels:PreferencesforElectricityReliability,"InternationalEconomicReview,51,421{440.[11]Chappell,HenryW.Jr.1994.\CampaignAdvertisingandPoliticalAmbiguity,"PublicChoice,79,281{303.[12]Cox,DavidR.1958.PlanningofExperiments.NewYork:Wiley.[13]Dewan,Torun,MacartanHumphreys,andDanielRubenson.2010.\TheImpactofLeadersandtheMessagesTheyConvey,"LSEmanuscript.[14]DiTella,Rafael,RobertJ.MacCulloch,andAndrewJ.Oswald.2001.\PreferencesoverIn a-tionandUnemployment:EvidencefromSurveysofHappiness,"AmericanEconomicReview,91,335{341.[15]Dominitz,Je andCharlesManski.1996.\ElicitingStudentExpectationsoftheReturnstoSchooling,"JournalofHumanResources,31,1{26.[16]Du y,JohnandMargitTavits.2008.\BeliefsandVotingDecisions:ATestofthePivotalVoterModel,"AmericanJournalofPoliticalScience,52,603{618.28 [17]Enelow,JamesM.andMelvinJ.Hinich.1982.\NonspatialCandidateCharacteristicsandElectoralCompetition,"JournalofPolitics,44,115{130.[18]Farlie,DennisJ.1960.\ThePerformanceofSomeCorrelationCoecientsforaGeneralBi-variateDistribution,"Biometrika47,307{323.[19]Fujiwara,ThomasandLeonardWantchekon.2013.\CanInformedPublicDeliberationOver-comeClientelism?ExperimentalEvidencefromBenin,"AmericanEconomicJournal:AppliedEconomics,forthcoming.[20]Galasso,VincenzoandTommasoNannicini.2011.\CompetingonGoodPoliticians,"AmericanPoliticalScienceReview,105,79{99.[21]Garthwaite,PaulH.,JosephB.Kadane,andAnthonyO'Hagan.2005.\StatisticalMethodsforElicitingProbabilityDistributions,"JournaloftheAmericanStatisticalAssociation,100,680{700.[22]Gerber,AlanS.,JamesG.Gimpel,DonaldP.Green,andDaronShaw.2011.\HowLargeandLong-lastingArethePersuasiveE ectsofTelevisedCampaignAds?ResultsfromaRandomizedFieldExperiment,"AmericanPoliticalScienceReview,105,135{150.[23]Gerber,AlanS.,andDonaldP.Green.2000.\TheE ectsofCanvassing,TelephoneCalls,andDirectMailonVoterTurnout:AFieldExperiment,"AmericanPoliticalScienceReview,94,653{63.[24]Gerber,AlanS.,DonaldP.Green,andRonShachar.2003.\VotingMayBeHabit-Forming:EvidencefromaRandomizedFieldExperiment,"AmericanJournalofPoliticalScience,47,540{50.[25]GerberElisabethR.andJe reyB.Lewis.2004.\BeyondtheMedian:VoterPreferences,DistrictHeterogeneity,andPoliticalRepresentation,"JournalofPoliticalEconomy,112,1364{1383.[26]Gill,Je andLeeD.Walker.2005.\ElicitedPriorsforBayesianModelSpeci cationsinPoliticalScienceResearch,"JournalofPolitics,67,841{872.[27]Green,DonaldP.,andAlanS.Gerber.2004.GetOuttheVote:HowtoIncreaseVoterTurnout.Washington,D.C.:BrookingsInstitutionPress.[28]Groseclose,Timothy.2001.\AModelofCandidateLocationWhenOneCandidateHasaValenceAdvantage,"AmericanJournalofPoliticalScience,45,862{886.[29]Kadane,JosephandLaraJ.Wolfson.1998.\ExperiencesinElicitation,"JournaloftheRoyalStatisticalSociety,47,3{19.[30]Kartik,NavinandR.PrestonMcAfee.2007.\SignalingCharacterinElectoralCompeti-tion,"AmericanEconomicReview,97,852{870.[31]Lee,David,EnricoMorettiandMatthewJ.Butler.2004.\DoVotersA ectorElectPolicies?EvidencefromtheU.S.House,"QuarterlyJournalofEconomics,119,807{859.[32]Liu,ScottandPatriciaStout.1987.\E ectsofMessageModalityandAppealonAdvertisingAcceptance,"PsychologyandMarketing,4,167{87.29 [33]Manski,CharlesF.2004\MeasuringExpectations,"Econometrica,72,1329{1376.[34]Manski,CharlesF.andFrancescaMolinari.2010.\RoundingProbabilisticExpectationsinSurveys,"JournalofBusinessandEconomicStatistics,28,219{231.[35]Miller,GeorgeA.1956.\TheMagicalNumberSeven,PlusorMinusTwo:SomeLimitsonOurCapacityforProcessingInformation,"PsychologicalReview63,81{97.[36]Nickerson,DavidW.2008.\IsVotingContagious?EvidencefromTwoFieldExperiments,"AmericanPoliticalScienceReview,102,49{57.[37]Ramalho,EsmeraldaA.andRichardJ.Smith.2012.\DiscreteChoiceNonresponse,"ReviewofEconomicStudies,7,34{58.[38]Rubin,DonaldB.1978.\BayesianInferenceforCausalE ects:TheRoleofRandomization,"TheAnnalsofStatistics,79,1{20.[39]Savage,Leonard.1971.\ElicitationofPersonalProbabilitiesandExpectations,"JournaloftheAmericanStatisticalAssociation,66,783{801.[40]Scho eld,Norman.2003.\ValenceCompetitionintheSpatialStochasticModel,"JournalofTheoreticalPolitics,15,371{383.[41]SklarAbe.1959.\Fonctionsder�1 2partition�1 2ndimensionsetleursmarges,"Publicationsdel'InstitutdeStatistiquedel'Universit�1 2deParis,8,229{231.[42]Stokes,DonaldE.1963.\SpatialModelsofPartyCompetition,"AmericanPoliticalScienceReview,57,368{377.[43]Vicente,PedroC.2013.\IsVote-buyingE ective?EvidencefromaFieldExperimentinWestAfrica,"EconomicJournal,forthcoming.[44]Vuong,QuangH.1989.\LikelihoodRatioTestsforModelSelectionandNon-NestedHypothe-ses,"Econometrica,2,307{333.[45]Wantchekon,Leonard.2003.\ClientelismandVotingBehavior:EvidencefromaFieldExper-imentinBenin,"WorldPolitics,55,399{422.[46]Wattenberg,MartinP.andCraigL.Brians.1999.\NegativeCampaignAdvertising:Demobi-lizerorMobilizer?"AmericanPoliticalScienceReview,93,891{899.[47]Zafar,Basit.2009.\CollegeMajorChoiceandtheGenderGap,"FederalReserveBankofNewYorkSta ReportNo.364.30 TablesandFiguresTable1{ElectionResultsataGlance MeanMedianS.d.MinMaxObs. Turnout0.7080.7140.0500.3890.78895Incumbentshareovervalidvotes0.5130.5080.0610.3540.66795Incumbentpartiesovervalidvotes0.5410.5420.0650.3580.67995 Notes.Descriptivestatisticsattheprecinctlevelofthevariablesspeci edinthe rstcolumn.\In-cumbentparties"refertothevotesharesofthepartylistssupportingtheincumbent.Table2{VoteDeclarationsattheIndividualLevel MeanMedianS.d.MinMaxObs. Declaredturnout0.8981.0000.3030.0001.0001,455Declaredvotefortheincumbent0.5711.0000.4950.0001.0001,306Declaredvoteforincumbentparties0.4930.0000.5000.0001.0001,306 Notes.Descriptivestatisticsattheindividuallevelofthevariablesspeci edinthe rstcolumn.\Incumbentparties"refertothe(self-declared)voteinfavorofthepartylistssupportingtheincumbent.31 Table3{Reduced-FormAggregateEstimates,AllGroups Referencegroup:nomessage ValenceValenceIdeologyIdeologyDoubleDoublebyphonebymailbyphonebymailbyphonebymail Turnout-0.011-0.0000.0130.010-0.006-0.006[0.031][0.015][0.011][0.013][0.009][0.013]Incumbent0.041**0.0040.0130.0210.027*-0.023share[0.019][0.025][0.016][0.025][0.015][0.015]Incumbent0.032*0.0180.0150.0290.021-0.015parties[0.018][0.023][0.016][0.026][0.014][0.015] Notes.Observations:95precincts.OLScoecientsreported;dependentvariablesinrowheadingsandtreatmentgroupsincolumnheadings.Robuststandarderrorsclusteredatthepollingplacelevelinbrackets.Signi canceatthe10%levelisrepresentedby*,atthe5%levelby**,andatthe1%levelby***.Table4{Reduced-FormAggregateEstimates,PhoneCalls Referencegroup:mailornomessage ValenceIdeologyDoublebyphonebyphonebyphone Turnout-0.0120.012-0.006[0.030][0.011][0.010]Incumbent0.040**0.0120.026*share[0.019][0.015][0.013]Incumbent0.0260.0080.014parties[0.020][0.016][0.012] Notes.Observations:95precincts.OLScoecientsreported;dependentvariablesinrowheadingsandtreatmentgroupsincolumnheadings.Robuststandarderrorsclusteredatthepollingplacelevelinbrackets.Signi canceatthe10%levelisrepresentedby*,atthe5%levelby**,andatthe1%levelby***.32 Table5{Reduced-FormIndividualEstimates,AllGroups Referencegroup:nomessage ValenceValenceIdeologyIdeologyDoubleDoublebyphonebymailbyphonebymailbyphonebymail Turnout-0.024-0.0190.0060.033-0.019-0.003[0.027][0.034][0.026][0.022][0.028][0.029]Incumbent0.095**-0.0610.018-0.0280.0350.004share[0.039][0.049][0.049][0.043][0.050][0.050]Incumbent0.109***-0.007-0.008-0.0440.009-0.014parties[0.040][0.060][0.061][0.046][0.051][0.049] Notes.Observations:1,455eligiblevoters(turnout);1,306actualvoters(voteshares).Probitmarginale ectsreported;dependentvariablesinrowheadingsandtreatmentgroupsincolumnheadings.Fixede ectsforsurveydateincluded.Robuststandarderrorsclusteredattheprecinctlevelinbrackets.Signi canceatthe10%levelisrepresentedby*,atthe5%levelby**,andatthe1%levelby***.Table6{Reduced-FormIndividualEstimates,PhoneCalls Referencegroup:mailornomessage ValenceIdeologyDoublebyphonebyphonebyphone Turnout-0.0260.005-0.021[0.023][0.023][0.023]Incumbent0.110***0.0350.051share[0.033][0.043][0.045]Incumbent0.123***0.0050.022parties[0.032][0.053][0.044] Notes.Observations:1,455eligiblevoters(turnout);1,306actualvoters(voteshares).Probitmarginale ectsreported;dependentvariablesinrowheadingsandtreatmentgroupsincolumnheadings.Fixede ectsforsurveydateincluded.Robuststandarderrorsclusteredattheprecinctlevelinbrackets.Signi canceatthe10%levelisrepresentedby*,atthe5%levelby**,andatthe1%levelby***.33 Table7{ModelEstimates,BaselineSpeci cation Model'sEstimateparameters[s.e.] A=Pr(responsejA)0.76[0.01] B=Pr(responsejB)0.99[0.01] L1.08[0.21] C1.10[0.14] R0.37[0.13]L0.34[0.21]C0.00[0.49]R0.98[0.32]L0.18[0.14]C0.02[0.09]R-0.03[0.05]V;30.40[0.15]V;20.40[0.28] V0.56[0.05]P;30.58[0.16]P;20.38[0.19] P0.71[0.19] Loglikelihood-1,043.60Observations1,306 Notes.Asymptoticstandarderrorsinbrackets.Theselectedspeci- cationassumesindependenceofmarginals,heterogeneouspreferenceparameters,andforcessameskewofmarginaldistributionofbeliefsfordi erentstatedlevelsofuncertainty.34 Table8{BeliefsaboutIncumbentfromModelEstimates Referencegroup:mailornomessage ValenceIdeologyDoublebyphonebyphonebyphone Average0.310**-0.022-0.100valence[0.148][0.142][0.098]Valence0.0050.0630.025std.dev.[0.082][0.095][0.093]Average0.015-0.121**-0.102*ideology[0.063][0.056][0.055]Ideology-0.036-0.090**-0.127***std.dev.[0.060][0.039][0.044] Notes.Observations:1,306actualvoters.OLScoecientsreported;dependentvariablesinrowheadingsandtreatmentgroupsincolumnheadings.Fixede ectsforsurveydateincluded.Robuststandarderrorsclusteredattheprecinctlevelinbrackets.Signi canceatthe10%levelisrepresentedby*,atthe5%levelby**,andatthe1%levelby***.Table9{BeliefsaboutIncumbentfromSurveyResponses Referencegroup:mailornomessage ValenceIdeologyDoublebyphonebyphonebyphone Valence0.326**-0.039-0.092mode[0.157][0.144][0.096]Valence-0.052***0.002-0.003uncertainty[0.013][0.018][0.018]Ideology-0.049-0.104**-0.052mode[0.052][0.052][0.059]Ideology-0.052*-0.046**-0.032uncertainty[0.023][0.019][0.019] Notes.Observations:1,455eligiblevoters.OLScoecients(mode)orProbitmarginale ects(uncertainty)reported;dependentvariablesinrowheadingsandtreatmentgroupsincolumnheadings.Fixede ectsforsurveydateincluded.Robuststandarderrorsclusteredattheprecinctlevelinbrackets.Signi canceatthe10%levelisrepresentedby*,atthe5%levelby**,andatthe1%levelby***.35 Table10{BeliefsaboutOpponentfromModelEstimates Referencegroup:mailornomessage ValenceIdeologyDoublebyphonebyphonebyphone Average-0.127-0.045-0.071valence[0.081][0.133][0.094]Valence-0.077-0.096-0.048std.dev.[0.110][0.107][0.132]Average-0.0750.189**-0.032ideology[0.067][0.075][0.070]Ideology0.041-0.177***-0.091std.dev.[0.075][0.064][0.057] Notes.Observations:1,306actualvoters.OLScoecientsreported;dependentvariablesinrowheadingsandtreatmentgroupsincolumnheadings.Fixede ectsforsurveydateincluded.Robuststandarderrorsclusteredattheprecinctlevelinbrackets.Signi canceatthe10%levelisrepresentedby*,atthe5%levelby**,andatthe1%levelby***.Table11{BeliefsaboutOpponentfromSurveyResponses Referencegroup:mailornomessage ValenceIdeologyDoublebyphonebyphonebyphone Valence-0.094-0.043-0.051mode[0.106][0.133][0.088]Valence-0.028-0.0290.008uncertainty[0.047][0.045][0.054]Ideology0.0230.141**-0.016mode[0.048][0.062][0.063]Ideology-0.044-0.089***0.001uncertainty[0.028][0.030][0.032] Notes.Observations:1,455eligiblevoters.OLScoecients(mode)orProbitmarginale ects(uncertainty)reported;dependentvariablesinrowheadingsandtreatmentgroupsincolumnheadings.Fixede ectsforsurveydateincluded.Robuststandarderrorsclusteredattheprecinctlevelinbrackets.Signi canceatthe10%levelisrepresentedby*,atthe5%levelby**,andatthe1%levelby***.36 Table12{PredictedVoteDi erencesunderCounterfactualElectoralCampaigns CounterfactualtreatmentPredictedvotedi erenceinpercentagepoints Blanketvalence2.2treatment[0.77,3.33]Blanketideology-2.2treatment[-3.37,-0.27]Blanketvalence&ideology0.5treatment[-0.73,1.84]Valencetreatmenttocenter&right1.3valence&ideologytoleftvoters[-0.19,2.37]Ideologytreatmenttocenter&right-2.4valence&ideologytoleftvoters[-3.87,-0.92]Actualelectoral1.8campaigne ect[1.23,3.14] Notes.Counterfactualadditionalvotes(inpercentagepoints)thatcandidateAwouldhaveobtainedwiththesimulatedcampaignsdescribedinthe rstcolumnrelativetonoelectoraltreatmentbeingadministered.Bootstrapped95percentcon denceintervalsinbrackets.Con denceintervalsarebasedon1,000drawsfromtheasymptoticdistributionoftheMLparametervectors.37 Figure1{PriorValenceMarginalDistributionforVoter#371 Figure2{PriorJointProbabilityDistributionforVoter#369 38 Figure3{PosteriorJointProbabilityDistributionforVoter#369 39 AppendixForallmaterialsrelatedtothedesignofourrandomizedcontrolledtrial(includingsurveyquestion-naires;coloredtreatment yers;audio lesofthetreatmentphonecalls;andmapsofthetreatmentgroups)pleaserefertothewebsite:www.igier.unibocconi.it/randomized-campaign.Inthenexttwosubsections,wereporttheEnglishtranslationsofthetextofthemail yers(whicharethenshowedinFigureA1andFigureA2)andofthetextofthecandidate'srecordedmessagesforthecampaignphonecalls.Inthesubsectiondevotedtotablesand gures,wereport:balancingtestsofprecinctcharacteristicsacrosstreatmentgroups(TableA1);balancingtestsofindividualcharacteristicsacrosstreatmentgroups(TableA2);balancingtestsof2001Censuscharacteristicsacrosstreatmentgroups(TableA3);estimatesofpotentialspillovere ects(TableA4);completesummaryofthestructuralmodelestimations(TablesA5andA6);LRandVoungtestsofmodelselection(TablesA7,A8,andA9); yersforboththevalenceandideologymessage(FiguresA1andA2).A1MailFlyers:EnglishTranslationsValence yer.COMPETENCEANDEFFORT.100millionworthofinvestments:SpentinpartontheFortress,squares,streets,andparkinglots.PIUSS,theintegratedplanforthedevelopmentofthecity:ThecityofArezzowasranked rstinTuscany;thisisanimportantaccomplishment.Inno-vation:Thedigitalcenter,thehydrogenpipeline,andtheenergyhouse.FANFANIFORMAYOR.Ideology yer.AWARENESSANDSOLIDARITY.Children:Createdanintegratedsystemtocatertheneedsofall,opened3newpublicnurseryschools.Elderly:In-homeassistance,newpublicservicestohelpfamilies.Anetworkofsolidarityfortheneediest:Housing,mealcenters,workintegrationservices.FANFANIFORMAYOR.A2PhoneCallRecordedMessages:EnglishTranslationsValencemessage.DearVoter,the15thand16thofMay,thecitizensofArezzowillvotetoelectthemayorandcitycouncilmen.WeallthereforehavetheopportunitytomakeaninformedchoiceforthefutureofArezzo.Overthelastyears,myadministrationinvested100millionEurostodevelopandimproveourcity.ResultsareundertheeyesofeveryoneandcanbeobservedbysimplylookingattheFortress,thesquares,thestreets,andtheparkinglots.Thankstothequalityofour40 work,thePIUSS|theplanforthedevelopmentofthecityofArezzo|wasranked rstamongthoseinTuscany.Thiswasanimportantaccomplishmentthatalsoenabledustogainaccesstoimportant nancialresourcestoimprovetheprominenceofourcity.However,wedidmuchmorethanthis,westrivedtoboostinnovationwiththedigitalcenter,thehydrogenpipeline,andtheenergyhouse.Givenalsoallthesereasons,Itakethelibertytoaskforyourvoteintheelectionofthe15thand16thofMay.RewardourCOMPETENCEandourEFFORT.BestregardsfromGiuseppeFanfani.Ideologymessage.DearVoter,the15thand16thofMay,thecitizensofArezzowillvotetoelectthemayorandcitycouncilmen.WeallwillhavetheopportunitytomakeaninformedchoiceforthefutureofArezzo.Forus,futurestandsforSOLIDARITY.Inthese veyearsofcitygovernment,wedealtwithissuesregardingchildhoodcreatinganintegratedsystemofservicesabletoprovideanswerstoallfamiliesandopeningthreenewpublicnurseryschools.Wealsotookcareofourelderlypeople,providingnewservicestohelpfamiliesassistthemandincreasingin-homeassistance.Atthesametime,wede nitelydidnotforgetaboutthosethatfoundthemselveslivingindicultcircumstancesalsobecausetheywerea ectedbytheinternationalcrisisthatseverelystruckourregion.Infact,weincreasedhousing,mealcenters,andprofessionalintegrationservicesforallthoseinneed.Givenalsoallthesereasons,Itakethelibertytoaskforyourvoteintheelectionofthe15thand16thofMay.MakeSOLIDARITYwin!Foran\Arezzo"carefulandopentothehardshipsofthoseinneed.BestregardsfromGiuseppeFanfani.Valenceplusideologymessage.DearVoter,the15thand16thofMay,thecitizensofArezzowillvotetoelectthemayorandcitycouncilmen.WeallthereforehavetheopportunitytomakeaninformedchoiceforthefutureofArezzo.Overthelastyears,myadministrationinvested100millionEurostodevelopandimproveourcity.ResultsareundertheeyesofeveryoneandcanobservedbysimplylookingattheFortress,thesquares,thestreets,andtheparkinglots.Thankstothequalityofourwork,thePIUSS|theplanforthedevelopmentofthecityofArezzo|wasranked rstamongthoseinTuscany.Atthesametime,wede nitelydidnotforgetaboutthosethatfoundthemselveslivingindicultcircumstancesalsobecausetheywerea ectedbytheinternationalcrisisthatseverelystruckourregion.Infact,weincreasedhousing,mealcenters,andprofessionalintegrationservicesforallthoseinneed.Givenalsoallthesereasons,Itakethelibertytoaskforyourvoteintheelectionofthe15thand16thofMay.RewardourCOMPETENCEandourEFFORT.MakeSOLIDARITYwin!ForanArezzocarefulandopentothehardshipsofthoseinneed.BestregardsfromGiuseppeFanfani.41 AppendixTablesandFiguresTableA1{Ex-AnteBalancingTestsatthePrecinctLevel Referencegroup:nomessage ValenceValenceIdeologyIdeologyDoubleDoublebyphonebymailbyphonebymailbyphonebymail Eligiblevoters-66.083-101.58319.250-63.667*-65.500-6.083[96.591][70.235][57.771][36.922][66.886][56.033]Firstneighborhood0.0360.0360.203-0.0470.203-0.047[0.136][0.112][0.178][0.112][0.123][0.109]Secondneighborhood0.116-0.051-0.051-0.051-0.0510.033[0.188][0.140][0.151][0.154][0.086][0.128]Thirdneighborhood-0.0140.236-0.0980.152-0.014-0.098[0.190][0.172][0.134][0.199][0.169][0.134]Fourthneighborhood-0.138-0.221-0.054-0.054-0.1380.112[0.149][0.141][0.146][0.164][0.139][0.129]Regional'10turnout-0.005-0.0030.0160.0120.000-0.002[0.025][0.016][0.010][0.010][0.010][0.014]Regional'10left0.0110.0130.0130.0120.004-0.021[0.015][0.019][0.013][0.017][0.013][0.013]Regional'10right-0.015-0.0170.0110.007-0.0060.019[0.015][0.014][0.012][0.018][0.011][0.018]European'09turnout-0.0040.0080.0190.0130.0020.007[0.026][0.012][0.012][0.013][0.011][0.012]European'09left-0.0120.015-0.016-0.0140.018-0.028[0.030][0.026][0.016][0.025][0.019][0.021]European'09right0.009-0.0150.0180.009-0.0140.026[0.022][0.021][0.015][0.024][0.020][0.020]National'08turnout-0.0140.0120.0020.0020.0050.000[0.025][0.008][0.006][0.007][0.007][0.009]National'08left0.0160.026-0.015-0.0040.020-0.019[0.019][0.019][0.019][0.028][0.020][0.017]National'08right-0.018-0.0230.0130.004-0.0240.023[0.020][0.017][0.017][0.028][0.021][0.018]City'06turnout-0.0020.0080.0120.0090.011-0.006[0.020][0.011][0.009][0.013][0.011][0.013]City'06left0.0160.035-0.029-0.0170.009-0.029[0.029][0.024][0.023][0.034][0.021][0.022]City'06right-0.014-0.0370.0280.014-0.0080.022[0.029][0.024][0.022][0.033][0.021][0.024] Notes.Observations:95precincts,86(European),84(National),83(City).OLScoecientsreported;dependentvariablesinrowheadingsandtreatmentgroupsincolumnheadings.Eligiblevotersisthenumberofeligiblevotersintheprecinct(average820.168).Theneighborhooddummiescapturethecity-wideneighborhoodtheprecinctbelongsto.Theothervariablesaretheelectoraloutcomesinpastelectionsandareexpressedasvoteshares.Robuststandarderrorsclusteredatthepollingplacelevelinbrackets.Signi canceatthe10%levelisrepresentedby*,atthe5%levelby**,andatthe1%levelby***.42 TableA2{Ex-PostBalancingTestsattheIndividualLevel Referencegroup:nomessage ValenceValenceIdeologyIdeologyDoubleDoublebyphonebymailbyphonebymailbyphonebymail Male0.0080.0140.0340.0040.0060.042[0.039][0.050][0.038][0.038][0.047][0.039]Over65-0.0350.004-0.0120.086-0.0460.056[0.053][0.048][0.048][0.053][0.042][0.048]College-0.004-0.0270.0100.0080.035-0.016graduate[0.035][0.041][0.041][0.047][0.045][0.040]Outof-0.0190.010-0.0370.048-0.0410.050laborforce[0.052][0.054][0.058][0.059][0.050][0.053]White0.029-0.0050.032-0.0130.008-0.013collar[0.045][0.043][0.038][0.041][0.039][0.038]Other-0.010-0.0050.006-0.0350.033-0.037occupation[0.049][0.041][0.040][0.039][0.042][0.051]Center-left0.0450.058-0.009-0.033-0.0590.014[0.044][0.055][0.048][0.040][0.042][0.059]Homeowner-0.017-0.007-0.0450.0270.007-0.037[0.040][0.030][0.039][0.036][0.033][0.028]Read0.037-0.0070.025-0.0240.0320.048thepress[0.036][0.038][0.042][0.052][0.049][0.047]WatchTV0.034-0.0160.0380.068-0.0330.055[0.042][0.055][0.039][0.046][0.042][0.038] Notes.Observations:1,455eligiblevoters.OLScoecientsreported;dependentvariablesinrowheadingsandtreatmentgroupsincolumnheadings.Allvariablesaredummies.ReadthepressandWatchTVcapturewhetherthevoterdeclarestodothis\veryoften"or\often."Fixede ectsforsurveydateincluded.Robuststandarderrorsclusteredattheprecinctlevelinbrackets.Signi canceatthe10%levelisrepresentedby*,atthe5%levelby**,andatthe1%levelby***.43 TableA3{Ex-PostBalancingTestsof2001CensusCharacteristics Referencegroup:nomessage ValenceValenceIdeologyIdeologyDoubleDoublebyphonebymailbyphonebymailbyphonebymail Males-5.112-1.318-8.103-1.957-2.5871.187[7.450][6.922][6.353][7.245][5.220][8.773]Marriedpeople-5.780-1.608-8.986-2.040-2.8631.256[8.041][7.496][6.905][7.955][5.697][9.541]Collegegraduates-0.5070.093-0.7120.473-0.1770.748[0.661][0.568][0.492][0.725][0.499][1.058]Foreigners-0.400-0.178-0.311-0.255-0.395-0.129[0.339][0.339][0.330][0.339][0.310][0.395]Employmentrate0.002-0.003-0.000-0.0020.005-0.001[0.006][0.006][0.005][0.004][0.005][0.004]Unemploymentrate-0.0010.0040.0010.000-0.0010.003[0.005][0.004][0.004][0.004][0.005][0.004]Homeownership0.011-0.028-0.012-0.023-0.012-0.003[0.025][0.038][0.030][0.025][0.027][0.025] Notes.Observations:95precincts.OLScoecientsreported;dependentvariablesinrowheadingsandtreatmentgroupsincolumnheadings.Allvariablesareimputedattheprecinctlevelfrominformationonthe2001Censuscells.Males,Marriedpeople,Collegegraduates,andForeignerscapturetheaveragenumberofindividualswiththatattributeattheprecinctlevel.Employmentrate,Unemploymentrate,andHomeownershipareexpressedasshares.Inparticular,homeownershipistheshareofhousesoccupiedbytheowner.Robuststandarderrorsclusteredatthepollingplacelevelinbrackets.Signi canceatthe10%levelisrepresentedby*,atthe5%levelby**,andatthe1%levelby***.44 TableA4{EvaluatingPotentialSpillovers,AllGroups Referencegroup:nomessage ValenceValenceIdeologyIdeologyDoubleDoublebyphonebymailbyphonebymailbyphonebymailspilloversspilloversspilloversspilloversspilloversspillovers Turnout0.032-0.0340.0100.0470.0030.028[0.048][0.055][0.044][0.060][0.042][0.054]Incumbent0.099-0.1130.064-0.0200.1240.005share[0.077][0.082][0.080][0.100][0.076][0.099]Incumbent0.081-0.147-0.035-0.1180.0380.006parties[0.079][0.098][0.096][0.104][0.089][0.115] Notes.Observations:1,455eligiblevoters(turnout);1,306actualvoters(voteshares).OLScoecientsreported;dependentvariablesinrowheadingsandtreatmentgroupsincolumnheadings.Eachspilloversvariablecapturestheshareofobservationswhoreceivedthecorrespondingtreatmentinthesamepollingplaceofeveryobservation.Averagevaluesare:0.135(valencebyphone);0.099(valencebymail);0.151(ideologybyphone);0.106(ideologybymail);0.135(doublebyphone);0.113(doublebymail).Fixede ectsforsurveydateincluded.Robuststandarderrorsclusteredattheprecinctlevelinbrackets.Signi canceatthe10%levelisrepresentedby*,atthe5%levelby**,andatthe1%levelby***.45 TableA5{ModelEstimateswithHeterogeneousPreferenceParameters ModeldescriptionCopulafamily:FGMFrankIndpFGMFGMFGMFrankFrankFrankIndpSamealpha:NoNoNoYesYesYesYesYesYesYesRhospeci cation:StandardStandard-StandardHeteroRestrictedStandardHeteroRestricted-Parameter A=Pr(responsejA)0.760.760.760.760.760.760.760.760.760.76(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01) B=Pr(responsejB)0.990.990.990.990.990.990.990.990.990.99(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01) = L1.081.081.071.091.091.091.101.101.081.08(0.23)(0.23)(0.21)(0.23)(0.23)(0.22)(0.23)(0.23)(0.22)(0.21) C1.111.111.111.101.111.111.101.121.111.10(0.14)(0.14)(0.14)(0.14)(0.14)(0.14)(0.14)(0.15)(0.15)(0.14) R0.360.370.360.360.350.350.350.330.370.37(0.13)(0.13)(0.13)(0.13)(0.13)(0.13)(0.13)(0.14)(0.13)(0.13)=L0.340.340.340.340.340.340.330.330.340.34(0.22)(0.22)(0.21)(0.22)(0.22)(0.22)(0.21)(0.21)(0.22)(0.21)C0.000.000.000.000.000.000.000.000.000.00(0.49)(0.49)(0.48)(0.48)(0.47)(0.47)(0.49)(0.45)(0.45)(0.49)R1.031.031.001.021.041.021.031.100.980.98(0.33)(0.32)(0.32)(0.32)(0.33)(0.32)(0.32)(0.33)(0.31)(0.32)=L0.180.180.180.190.190.180.190.200.190.18(0.15)(0.15)(0.14)(0.15)(0.15)(0.15)(0.15)(0.15)(0.15)(0.14)C0.020.020.020.030.030.030.020.040.040.02(0.09)(0.09)(0.09)(0.09)(0.09)(0.09)(0.09)(0.10)(0.09)(0.09)R-0.04-0.04-0.04-0.04-0.04-0.04-0.04-0.05-0.03-0.03(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)(0.04)(0.04)(0.05)(0.05)V;30.380.370.400.370.370.360.360.360.400.40(0.15)(0.15)(0.15)(0.15)(0.16)(0.16)(0.15)(0.16)(0.16)(0.15)V;20.380.370.400.370.370.360.360.360.400.40(0.32)(0.32)(0.31)(0.29)(0.30)(0.29)(0.28)(0.28)(0.30)(0.28) V= V;30.590.580.590.560.560.560.560.560.560.56(0.06)(0.06)(0.07)(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)(0.06)(0.05) V;20.510.510.51-------(0.10)(0.10)(0.10)-------P;30.580.580.590.570.570.570.570.550.560.58(0.17)(0.16)(0.16)(0.16)(0.16)(0.16)(0.16)(0.15)(0.15)(0.16)P;20.380.380.380.370.360.370.370.330.370.38(0.20)(0.20)(0.20)(0.20)(0.20)(0.20)(0.19)(0.19)(0.19)(0.19) P= P;30.710.710.720.700.690.700.690.680.700.71(0.23)(0.23)(0.24)(0.18)(0.18)(0.18)(0.18)(0.17)(0.18)(0.19) P;20.690.690.69-------(0.30)(0.30)(0.30)-------A=LA-1.00-13.67--1.00-1.00-1.00-8.24-30.00-30.00-(10.62)(261.31)-(10.37)(11.69)(11.58)(90.46)(1703.1)(1717.1)-CA----1.001.00-14.1713.22-----(134.16)(136.54)-(4054.00)(4003.60)-RA----1.00--30.00------(15.42)--(786.89)--B=LB-1.00-30.00--1.00-1.00-1.00-30.00-30.00-29.99-(18.42)(2035.20)-(17.90)(18.95)(13.53)(1952.30)(1969.40)(1796.20)-CB----1.001.00-8.438.23-----(190.48)(195.53)-(2618.30)(3160.70)-RB-----1.00---30.00------(42.58)--(5325.70)--Loglikelihood-1043.20-1042.90-1043.30-1043.40-1043.30-1043.40-1043.10-1042.60-1043.10-1043.60Observations1,3061,3061,3061,3061,3061,3061,3061,3061,3061,306 Notes.Asymptoticstandarderrorsinbrackets.Preferenceparametersareallowedtovarywithvoter'sideology(L,C,R);basedonLRtests,ourpreferredspeci cationiswithindependentcopulaandsamealpha.Copulafamily:\FGM"standsforFarlie-Gumbel-Morgensen;\Frank"standsforFrankfamily;\Indp"for.Samealpha:\yes"forcesskewofmarginalstobethesameforeachlevelofstateduncertainty;\no"allowstheskewtodi er.Rhospeci cation:\standard"meansbaselineAandB;\hetero"allowsAandBtovarywithvoter'sideology;\restricted"forcesLA=RBandRA=LB. TableA6{ModelEstimateswithoutHeterogeneousPreferenceParameters ModeldescriptionCopulafamily:FGMFrankIndpFGMFGMFGMFrankFrankFrankIndpSamealpha:NoNoNoYesYesYesYesYesYesYesRhospeci cation:StandardStandard-StandardHeteroRestrictedStandardHeteroRestricted-Parameter A=Pr(responsejA)0.770.770.770.770.770.770.770.770.770.77(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01) B=Pr(responsejB)0.980.980.980.980.980.980.980.980.980.98(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01)(0.01) = L0.890.910.900.880.880.900.910.910.910.89(0.09)(0.09)(0.09)(0.09)(0.09)(0.09)(0.09)(0.09)(0.09)(0.09) C-------------------- R--------------------=L0.650.680.690.690.680.650.660.660.68(0.14)(0.14)(0.14)(0.14)(0.14)(0.14)(0.14)(0.14)(0.14)(0.14)C--------------------R--------------------=L0.050.060.050.040.040.050.060.060.060.05(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)C--------------------R--------------------V;30.400.350.350.340.400.340.340.340.340.34(0.17)(0.16)(0.15)(0.15)(0.17)(0.17)(0.16)(0.16)(0.16)(0.16)V;20.400.350.350.340.400.340.340.340.340.34(0.30)(0.29)(0.29)(0.24)(0.30)(0.25)(0.28)(0.29)(0.29)(0.28) V= V;30.540.540.540.510.520.520.520.520.520.52(0.07)(0.06)(0.06)(0.05)(0.06)(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)(0.05)(0.05) V;20.500.500.50-------(0.11)(0.10)(0.10)-------P;30.600.580.610.650.650.600.610.580.620.65(0.17)(0.15)(0.15)(0.17)(0.17)(0.15)(0.16)(0.15)(0.15)(0.15)P;20.600.550.610.650.650.600.610.580.610.65(0.33)(0.32)(0.32)(0.27)(0.28)(0.26)(0.26)(0.27)(0.26)(0.26) P= P;30.800.770.810.810.820.770.770.740.770.81(0.26)(0.23)(0.27)(0.28)(0.28)(0.22)(0.23)(0.20)(0.23)(0.27) P;20.690.650.70-------(0.42)(0.35)(0.44)-------A=LA-1.00-30.00--1.00-1.001.00-30.00-30.0029.99-(18.09)(1993.00)-(22.79)(38.48)(24.90)(2120.70)(3038.50)(2786.20)-CA----1.001.00-30.0029.60-----(53.29)(41.32)-(1849.70)(7268.40)-RA-----1.00---30.00------(41.50)--(2997.90)--B=LB1.0029.99-1.00-1.00-1.0029.99-30.00-30.00-(29.21)(1633.70)-(37.36)(51.93)(22.23)(3674.60)(4066.60)(2467.70)-CB----1.001.00-22.4227.94-----(86.81)(63.35)-(6915.90)(11627.00)-RB-----1.00---30.00------(81.43)--(7895.00)--Loglikelihood-1057.70-1057.40-1057.70-1057.90-1057.94-1057.70-1057.50-1057.50-1057.40-1057.90Observations1,3061,3061,3061,3061,3061,3061,3061,3061,3061,306 Notes.Asymptoticstandarderrorsinbrackets.UnlikeTableA3,preferenceparametersarenotallowedtovarywithvoter'sideology(L,C,R);basedonLRtests,thesearenotourpreferredspeci cationsbutwereportthemforcompleteness.Copulafamily:\FGM"standsforFarlie-Gumbel-Morgensen;\Frank"standsforFrankfamily;\Indp"for.Samealpha:\yes"forcesskewofmarginalstobethesameforeachlevelofstateduncertainty;\no"allowstheskewtodi er.Rhospeci cation:\standard"meansbaselineAandB;\hetero"allowsAandBtovarywithvoter'sideology;\restricted"forcesLA=RBandRA=LB. TableA7{LRTests:RestrictionofPreferenceParametersToBetheSameacrossVoter'sIdeology CopulaTeststatisticP-value FGM28.940.00Frank28.860.00Independent28.620.00 Notes.Skewrestrictedtobethesameacrosslevelsofstateduncertainty.Standardspeci cation.TableA8{LRTests:RestrictionofSkewToBetheSameacrossLevelsofUncertainty PreferencesCopulaTeststatisticP-value HomogeneousFGM0.290.86HomogeneousFrank0.370.83HomogeneousIndp0.380.83HeterogeneousFGM0.490.78HeterogeneousFrank0.390.82HeterogeneousIndp0.540.76 Notes.Standardspeci cation.TableA9{VuongTests:CopulaComparisons PreferencesCopulaRhoTestP-valuePreferredcomparisonspeci cationstatisticcopula HomogeneousFrankvs.FGMStandard0.760.45FrankHomogeneousIndependentvs.FGMStandard39.480.00IndependentHomogeneousIndependentvs.FrankStandard17.930.00IndependentHeterogeneousFrankvs.FGMStandard1.050.29FrankHeterogeneousIndependentvs.FGMStandard22.670.00IndependentHeterogeneousIndependentvs.FrankStandard12.610.00IndependentHeterogeneousIndependentvs.FGMHeterogeneous52.080.00IndependentHeterogeneousIndependentvs.FrankHeterogeneous26.590.00IndependentHomogeneousIndependentvs.FGMHeterogeneous12.90.00IndependentHomogeneousIndependentvs.FrankHeterogeneous35.930.00IndependentHeterogeneousIndependentvs.FGMRestricted37.190.00IndependentHeterogeneousIndependentvs.FrankRestricted30.780.00IndependentHomogeneousIndependentvs.FGMRestricted40.570.00IndependentHomogeneousIndependentvs.FrankRestricted34.770.00Independent Notes.Skewrestrictedtobethesameacrosslevelofstateduncertainty.48 FigureA1{CampaignFlyerwiththeValenceMessage FigureA2{CampaignFlyerwiththeIdeologyMessage 49