/
Optimal illiquidity Optimal illiquidity

Optimal illiquidity - PowerPoint Presentation

kittie-lecroy
kittie-lecroy . @kittie-lecroy
Follow
379 views
Uploaded On 2017-12-16

Optimal illiquidity - PPT Presentation

John Beshears James J Choi Christopher Clayton Christopher Harris David Laibson Brigitte C Madrian US is an outlier on DC account liquidity US 10 penalty for most early withdrawals ID: 615846

system account completely optimal account system optimal completely illiquid penalty planner early liquid period leakage retirement withdrawal social accounts

Share:

Link:

Embed:

Download Presentation from below link

Download Presentation The PPT/PDF document "Optimal illiquidity" is the property of its rightful owner. Permission is granted to download and print the materials on this web site for personal, non-commercial use only, and to display it on your personal computer provided you do not modify the materials and that you retain all copyright notices contained in the materials. By downloading content from our website, you accept the terms of this agreement.


Presentation Transcript

Slide1

Optimal illiquidity

John BeshearsJames J. ChoiChristopher ClaytonChristopher HarrisDavid LaibsonBrigitte C. MadrianSlide2

U.S. is an outlier on DC account liquidityU.S.10% penalty for most early withdrawals0% penalty for loans and certain withdrawals

Canada, AustraliaNo liquidity unless long-term unemployedGermany, Singapore, UKNo liquiditySource: Beshears et al. (2015)Slide3

U.S. retirement savings leakage

Households < 55 withdraw $0.40 (not counting loans) from retirement accounts for every $1 contributed Source: Argento, Bryant, and Sabelhaus (2014)Slide4

QuestionsIs this too much leakage?Is 10% the right penalty?

1970s Senate wanted 30% penalty1970s House wanted 10% penaltySlide5

Why do we need to make savings illiquid?Limited self-controlCreates need for illiquidity

But unpredictable, uninsurable legitimate spending needs existCreates need for flexibilitySlide6

Model setup

Households live for 2 periodsPeriod 1 = working lifePeriod 2 = retirementConsumption in period 1, , produces utility

is random variable representing how valuable pre-retirement spending is

Lies between positive numbers

and

Consumption in period

2,

,

produces utility

 Slide7

Benevolent social planner

Social planner’s preference over household’s consumption given by

is discount factor representing how much less valuable future utility is

Lies between 0 and 1

can’t be observed by

planner, but planner knows population-wide distribution of

 Slide8

Household preferencesHousehold’s preference over

consumption given by

Present bias term

is between 0 and 1

Represents excessive impatience

Lower value = more excessive impatience

 Slide9

distribution

 Normal distribution with mean 1, standard deviation 0.25, truncated at 1/3 and 5/3Slide10

Savings accountsPlanner chooses for N accounts

How much to put in each account at period 1Early withdrawal penaltySlide11

Optimal system with autarky and homogeneous

 Planner can’t redistribute early-withdrawal penalties collectedPenalties are “burned”Everybody has same degree of self-controlTheorem: Optimal system has only 2 accounts: one completely liquid account and one completely illiquid account (Angeletos, Werning, and Amador, 2006)Illiquid account like Social Security or DB pensionSlide12

Optimal system with transfers and homogeneous

 Planner can redistribute early-withdrawal penalties collectedEverybody has same degree of self-controlTheorem: A system with one completely liquid account and one completely illiquid account is not optimalSlide13

Optimal penalty in illiquid account in two-account system

Empirical estimate ≈ 0.7Optimal penalty ≈ 30% Slide14

Optimal system with transfers and heterogeneous

 Planner knows frequency of values but not each person’s Theorem: If all agents have or

, then the optimal system

has only 2 accounts: one completely liquid account and one completely illiquid account

Intuition:

Completely liquid system is a disaster for impatient types, who consume everything in period 1 and have nothing in period 2

Partially illiquid system increases period 2 inequality relative to completely illiquid system

 Slide15

Less extreme distribution

 Average = 0.7Modal agent has no self-control problemSlide16

Results from numerical simulationsOptimal 2-account system1 completely liquid account

1 completely illiquid accountWelfare gain of 3.4% of income relative to system with only one completely liquid accountOptimal 3-account system1 completely liquid account1 completely illiquid account1 account with early withdrawal penalty = 9%Welfare gain from third account is only 0.018% of incomeSlide17

LeakagePlanner puts 14% of partially and fully illiquid assets in partially illiquid accountPercent of

personal retirement accounts + DB pension + Social Security in personal retirement accountMedian married household in 2008: 12% Median single household in 2008: 0%74% of dollars in partially illiquid account leaks in period 1Slide18

Robustness to other parameterizationsVary

Risk aversionShape of taste shocks Distribution of self-control parameter Optimal early withdrawal penalty: 6% to 13%Leakage rate: 65% to 90% Slide19

How I Learned to Stop Worrying and Love LeakageSlide20

TakeawaysU.S. retirement savings system

might be close to optimalWithin highly simplified modelCompletely illiquid layer like Social Security is optimal and achieves almost all possible welfare gains from policy401(k)/IRA system adds only a little to welfare10% withdrawal penalty from 401(k)/IRA system is about optimalHigh leakage from 401(k)/IRA system is optimalSome of that leakage is for legitimate purposesPenalties paid by early withdrawers benefit the rest of usSlide21

CaveatAssumes that the optimal amount is deposited in each account

If current level of Social Security + DB benefits is inadequate, then system is not optimalWould want to add an additional completely illiquid account to bring completely illiquid assets up to right level