/
BOWLING FOR FASCISM:  SOCIAL CAPITAL AND THE RISE OF THE NAZI PARTY IN WEIMAR GERMANY, BOWLING FOR FASCISM:  SOCIAL CAPITAL AND THE RISE OF THE NAZI PARTY IN WEIMAR GERMANY,

BOWLING FOR FASCISM: SOCIAL CAPITAL AND THE RISE OF THE NAZI PARTY IN WEIMAR GERMANY, - PowerPoint Presentation

fanny
fanny . @fanny
Follow
343 views
Uploaded On 2021-01-27

BOWLING FOR FASCISM: SOCIAL CAPITAL AND THE RISE OF THE NAZI PARTY IN WEIMAR GERMANY, - PPT Presentation

Shanker Satyanath Nico Voigtländer HansJoachim Voth NYU UCLA and NBER UZH and CEPR 26 May 2015 Background Social capital ID: 830204

social party capital entry party social entry capital nazi members association associations density nsdap 000 club government baseline towns

Share:

Link:

Embed:

Download Presentation from below link

Download The PPT/PDF document "BOWLING FOR FASCISM: SOCIAL CAPITAL AND..." is the property of its rightful owner. Permission is granted to download and print the materials on this web site for personal, non-commercial use only, and to display it on your personal computer provided you do not modify the materials and that you retain all copyright notices contained in the materials. By downloading content from our website, you accept the terms of this agreement.


Presentation Transcript

Slide1

BOWLING FOR FASCISM: SOCIAL CAPITAL AND THE RISE OF THE NAZI PARTY IN WEIMAR GERMANY, 1919-33

Shanker Satyanath Nico Voigtländer Hans-Joachim Voth (NYU) (UCLA and NBER) (UZH and CEPR)

26

May 2015

Slide2

Background: Social capital

Social capital = a dense network of civic associations “[t]he study of social capital is that of network-based processes that generate beneficial outcomes through norms and trust” (Durlauf and Fafchamps, 2004) Social capital typically associated with benign outcomes: Vigorous democracy (Tocqueville, 1835 and Putnam, 1994,1995)Economic development (Knack and Keefer, 1997) Pro-social behavior (Guiso, Sapienza and Zingales, 2008, 2010)Also acknowledged that social capital can have negative effects, such as social polarization (Durlauf and

Fafchamps

, 2004); crime (Field, 2003)

Autocratic rulers can use social capital as a means of control

 entrench elites  persistence of “bad” institutions

(

Acemoglu

, Reed, and Robinson, 2013)

This paper: Can social capital also contribute to the fall of existing democracies and the

emergence

of autocracies?

Slide3

3

Slide4

Origins of Totalitarianism:

Mass-society, decline of traditional ties  susceptibility for totalitarian doctrineLarge-scale, impersonal, social institutions: Individuals cut off from traditional and communal ties (Ortega y Gasset)Social isolation is key: Appeal to marginal loners on the fringes of society (Arendt, 1958). Stern

(1972): Germany lacked “the kind of voluntary, civic activity that attracted their English and American counterparts.”

Mass

movements – NS, Communists – offer an alternative

identity

weakness of German civic society facilitated rise of the NazisContrast

: Berman

(1997): Weimar Germany

had comparatively high social capital, successfully exploited by NSDAP

4

Slide5

This paperConstruct novel dataset for association density in more than 225 towns and cities in the 1920s

Show that there is a robust, strong relationship between density of associations and Nazi Party entry Results equally strong for bowling, singing, and animal breeding clubs etc. Address concerns over endogeneityShow that “dark side” of social capital was particularly strong where regional institutions were weak

5

Slide6

Background: Rise of the NSDAPFounded 1919

1923 – attempt to overthrow the government (“Beerhall Putsch”)Party banned in 1924Returns to the polls in 1928, receives 2.6% of the voteIn the late 20s, party organization growing rapidly100,000 members1,400 local chaptersBy 1933, 850,00 members; “Storm Troopers” (SA) strong enough to challenge the government militarily First major electoral success in 1930 (after the party had already built substantial membership base)

Slide7

Why party entry mattersMembership expansion via local party cells was a critical pre-condition for subsequent electoral success and the collapse of democracy (Brustein, 1998)

Membership dues key source of financingMembers important for major modes of mobilization (rallies, leafleting, etc.)NS entry rates predict (later) electoral success

Slide8

How did the NSDAP exploit local associations? Town chapters (Ortsgruppen

) were responsible for recruiting members, collecting dues, coordinating activities, etc.Koshar (1986) uses the example of Emil Wissner, a salesman in Marburg: Member of a white-collar employee association (from 1921), and active in two gymnastics clubs (from 1904). Joined the party in 1929, and actively used his position to proselytize for the party, and to win new members.

Slide9

Social Networks and Party Entry

Fellow association members more trusted than randomly matched acquaintances: makes it easier for Nazi party ‘political entrepreneurs’ to spread the message

One Nazi Party member recounts how he…

“…became acquainted with a colleague of my own age with whom I had frequent conversations. He was a calm, quiet person whom I esteemed very highly. When I found out that he was one of the local leaders of the National Socialist party, my opinion of it as a group of criminals changed completely…”

Slide10

NSDAP members were mostly members of ‘ordinary’ associations

From Koshar (1987):

Slide11

Data

Collected data on associations from 229 town and city directories, altogether 22,127 associations2.61 associations per 1,000 inhabitants on averageConditions to be in the sample:Contacted all towns larger than 10,000 in 1925 (~550)Surviving directories listing associations in the 1920sFor many towns and cities, this information was lost, destroyed during the war, or it did not exist in the first placeCore measure: “Association density” number of associations per 1,000 inhabitants (Unfortunately, no systematic

data on number of members

)

Matched with sample

Falter-

Brustein

computerized sample

of

38,752 Nazi Party members for 1925-33 (Schneider-Haase, 1991). Identify 9,169 members in the 229 towns and cities

11

Slide12

12

12

12

12

Association density

Nazi Party entry

Towns and cities in the sample, by association density and party entry

Note: Full dots = above median; empty dots = below median.

Slide13

Slide14

Balancedness

Omnibus test:

Test if predicted NSDAP entry (by all controls) is correlated with club density

p-value 0.19 for baseline controls

p-value 0.80 for all controls, conditional on baseline controls

Slide15

Baseline results:Nazi Party entry and association density

15

Baseline

Slide16

Partial scatter plot, NSDAP entry rate and association density (baseline)

Slide17

Baseline results – some robustness

17

Slide18

More robustness…

Subsamples by high/low Catholic, blue-collar, city sizeBonding and bridging social capitalMatching estimation (also by location)

18

Slide19

NSDAP Party Membership and Success at the Polls

19

Slide20

Mediation test: Club density

 Party entry  Electoral success

Slide21

Towards an Interpretation

When do associations matter most?Early vs. late party entry: Stronger results for early entryRole of `Nazi potential’: Associations matter more in towns with lower right-wing votes in early 1920sPanel results: Existing members most ‘useful’ for fostering party growth in locations with high club densityInterpretation:

Local networks particularly useful for new parties that cannot rely on existing members for local recruitment efforts

Further suggestive evidence:

Elections – Counterfactuals

: Weak negative relationship with KPD (communists), none with DNVP (right-wing party) in 1928-33

21

Slide22

Understanding the effects of social capital:The role of institutions

A lot of evidence – social capital positive for democracyIn Weimar – contributes to decline and fall of democracyHow do we make sense of the difference?One answer – institutionsStrong, stable institutions align expectationsProvide a positive prior for democracyCan crack down on anti-democratic movements while they’re still small

Slide23

Example: Prussia 1919-32 = “The Weimar that works”

Stable Social Democrat coalition (narrow majority)Vigorous defenders of democracy (against right and left)Police stops paramilitary groupsBans political marches (e.g., police shoots on Communist demonstrators on May 1, 1929)Increasing pressure from central government starting 1930. Prussian government deposed in a putsch in July 1932

Slide24

Proxy for government stability (state-level):

Three indicators over the period 1918-July 32 (ending with the Prussian coup d’etat)the percentage of time that the longest-serving government was in officethe percentage of time that the longest-serving party was in office (possibly in different coalitions)the percentage of time that a state was governed by at least one party from the “Weimar coalition” (SPD, DDP,

Zentrum

)

Compute first

principal

component

Prussia in the upper third, but some states equally or more stable

Slide25

The role of stable government – preview

Low stability, outside Prussia

(N=58)

Prussia

(N=119)

High stability, outside Prussia (N=48)

Slide26

Slide27

The net effect of club density on NSDAP entry

Slide28

Towards causalityIV

Additional checks“Plausibly exogenous”Selection on unobservables Altonji et al.

28

Slide29

IV strategy

1860s membership in gymnast associations1861 participation in the Nuremberg Singing Festival283 singing associations6,000-20,000 participants[Friedrich Nietzsche among them]Exclusion restriction19C nationalism vs. national socialism (“spirit of 1848”)Turn towards the apolitical after 1850Evidence from Democratic congress in Berlin, 1848

Slide30

IV results

Slide31

ConclusionsSocial capital associated with many beneficial outcomes

We showed: dense networks of clubs associated with rise of the Nazi party, and thus contributing to the collapse of Weimar Germany’s democracyDoes not depend on the type of associationImportant interaction with institutions: Social capital can be exploited to undermine democracy when institutions are weak

Slide32

Tocqueville knew it all along… “The most natural privilege of man… is that of combining his exertions with those of his fellow creatures and of acting in common with them. The right of association therefore appears to me almost as inalienable in its nature as the right of personal liberty. … Nevertheless, if

the liberty of association is only a source of advantage and prosperity to some nations, it may be perverted or carried to excess by others, and from an element of life may be changed into a cause of destruction.” [italics added]

Slide33

BACKUP

33

Slide34

The basic result

Cumulative NSDAP membership, by association densityNote: Each data point reflects the cumulative NSDAP entry rate (per 1,000 inhabitants), starting in 1925 and averaged across the cities with above- and below- median association density. The data are described in Section 3. NSDAP entries are from the Berlin-Minneapolis sample (Schneider-Haase 1991); starting in 1930, we correct aggregate entry rates for a change in sampling methodology, as described in Appendix C.

Total entries per 1,000

Below-median club

denisty

: 27.7

Above-median club density: 35.2

Slide35

Partial scatter – exclude 90pctile of club density

35

Slide36

Historians’ judgment

“…the movement may have ‘fed’ on preexisting membership structures and clusters which the single members helped channel into the reestablished Nazi party. Ties with other ‘bourgeois’ associations of Germany’s civil society may well have enhanced this process by extending the reach of single members for recruitment purposes.” (Anheier 2003) “Weimar's rich associational life provided a critical training ground for eventual Nazi cadres and a base from which the NSDAP could launch its Machtergreifung (seizure of power).” (Berman 2007)

Slide37

Example: Coburg

Slide38

Veterans of

5

th

infantry

Regiment

Bamberg

Soccer

And athletics

Slide39

Bad Langensalza[member count not listed]

Slide40

Associations in the sample

40

Slide41

Members per capita vs. Clubs p.c.

41

Membership data for sports and gymnastics clubs members available for Prussian towns in 1927

Slide42

Elections – Counterfactuals

42

Slide43

Early and late Nazi Party entries, by locality

Note: The x-axis plots average rates of Nazi Party entry (per 1,000 inhabitants) in each city over the period 1925-28, and the y-axis over the period 1929-33. Data are described in Section 3.

Slide44

Slide45

Slide46

Slide47

Location-specific ‘sociability’? Worker associations as counterfactual

Evidence for “general sociability”, but not for an effect on Nazi party entryWorking class associations did not act as gateways to the Nazi movement – "infection" apparently required a minimum degree of ideological compatibility

Slide48

Slide49

Slide50

Civic vs. Military clubs

Slide51

“Bridging” vs. “Bonding” social capital

Slide52

Bonding and bridging social capital

Slide53

Matching estimation and geographic location

Slide54

Quantile regressions

Slide55

Quantile regression – graph

Quantile regression graph

Note: The figure shows the effect of a unit increase in association density on Nazi Party entry rates, by quantile of the dependent variable. The shaded area reflects the 95% confidence interval of the quantile regressions. The figure is derived for our main specification, with the three baseline controls: share of Catholics, ln(population), and the of share blue collar workers, all measured in 1925. Absolute coefficient sizes are plotted. For standardized beta coefficients, see Table 13 in the paper.

Slide56

Annually standardized entry rates

56

Slide57

Plausible exogeneity – Results following Conley, Hansen, and Rossi (2012)

Comparison: Reduced-form coefficient on IV is 0.227.

Slide58

Selection on unobservables - Altonji ratios

Slide59

Association delegates to Democratic Congress in Berlin, 1848